![]() ![]() |
![]() |
UFDC Home | Search all Groups | World Studies | Federal Depository Libraries of Florida & the Caribbean | UF Government Documents Collection | Vendor Digitized Files | | Help |
Material Information
Subjects
Notes
Record Information
|
Full Text |
4E *aA nc -41 ly Vim ol 'R k UU1 CV tjo Xv 00 4 T1 VB SOO" semion BOOK ew P-10SAO lk "y A ` iirv, 41 r 4 4- Co4limiftee On uwxftp, ir/ !014 till 4 I Ii Alli All 4 v #m m1 [COMMITTEE PRINT] FINE FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND THE NATION'S ECONOMY COMPENDIUM OF PAPERS PREPARED FOR THE FINE STUDY COMMITTEE ON BANKING, CURRENCY AND HOUSING HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES 94th Congress, Second Session BOOK I PART 1-DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS AND HOUSING PART 2-REGULATION OF DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS JUNE 1976 Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing The report has not been officially adopted by the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing and may not therefore necessarily reflect the views of its members. U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 42-7480 WASHINGTON : 1976 COMMITTEE ON BANKING, CURRENCY AND HOUSING HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin, Chairman LEONOR K. (MRS. JOHN B.) SULLIVAN, Missouri THOMAS L. ASHLEY, Ohio WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania ROBERT G. STEPHENS, JR., Georgia FERNAND J. ST GERMAIN. Rhode Island HENRY B. GONZALEZ. Texas JOSEPH G. MINISH, New Jersey FRANK ANNUNZIO, Illinois THOMAS M. REES, California JAMES 31. HANLEY. New York WARREN J. MITCHELL, Maryland WALTER E. FAUNTROY, District of Columbia LINDY (MRS. HALE) BOGGS, Louisiana STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina JERRY M. PATTERSON, California JAMES J. BLANCHARD, Michigan CARROLL HUBBARD, JR., Kentucky JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York GLADYS NOON SPELLMAN, Maryland LES Ai'COIN, Oregon PAUL E. TSONGAS, Massachusetts BUTLER DERRICK. South Carolina PHILIP H. HAYES, Indiana MARK WV. HANNAFORD, California DAVID W. EVANS, Indiana CLIFFORD ALLEN, Tennessee NORMAN E. D'AMOURS, New Hampshire STANLEY N. LUNDINE, New York ALBERT W. JOHNSON, Pennsylvania J. WILLIAM STANTON, Ohio GARRY BROWN, Michigan CHALMERS P. WYLIE, Ohio JOHN H. ROUSSELOT, California STEWART B. McKINNEY, Connecticut JOHN B. CONLAN, Arizona GEORGE HANSEN, Idaho RICHARD T. SCHULZE, Pennsylvania WILLIS D. GRADISON, JR., Ohio HENRY J. HYDE, Illinois RICHARD KELLY, Florida CHARLES E. GRASSLEY, Iowa MILLICENT FENWICK, New Jersey RON PAUL, Texas (I) PREFACE The House Banking, Currency and Housing Committee together with the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regu- lation and Insurance announced on April 24, 1975 the undertaking of a major review of the nation's financial institutions and their regulation by the Federal Government. A project was launched, called the Financial Institutions in the Nation's Economy (FINE) Study, encompassing five areas: The relationship between banks and thrift institutions, and what changes may be desirable in their borrowing, lending, investment and customer service activities; the adequacy of federal regulation, as now divided among three government agencies for banks alone; the structure and operations of the Federal Reserve System; the operation of U.S. banks abroad, of foreign banks in the U.S., and of the Eurodollar market; and the operation of bank holding companies. A team of consultants and Committee staff, under the supervision of Dr. James L. Pierce, principal consultant to the Committee on the FINE Study, began an analysis of the major issues affecting our financial institutions. Working with staff and expert consultants, the Committee published in November 1975 a set of Discussion Prin- ciples which contained proposals for the restructuring of our financial institutions. Extensive hearings followed and ultimately legislation was proposed. As a first step in this process, the Committee commissioned for FINE a number of studies that were conducted by respected scholars who had published extensively and had experience in advising the government on policy matters in their respective fields. These studies provided an independent perspective on financial reform. The papers present a focused evaluation of important issues which touch on the many facets of financial reform and are the result of careful study by individuals who have thought deeply in their chosen area. The papers contained in this volume represent all of the studies that have been commissioned for the FINE Study. Four studies that were completed and in publishable form before the hearings began were published in a November 1975 volume. The present volume con- tains those four studies as well as new ones relating to international banking, bank holding companies, credit unions and additional papers on regulatory reform. Besides the studies, an extensive and detailed questionnaire dealing with the current practices and attitudes of the Federal banking regu- latory agencies was prepared by the FINE Study Staff and several consultants. This questionnaire was published in the earlier volume; in the present volume the questionnaire is reprinted as well as the replies from the Federal Reserve Board and the Comptroller of the Currency. HENRY S. REUSS, Chairman, Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing. FERNAND J. ST GERMAIN, Chairman, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Superviion, Regulation and Insurance. (M) Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2013 http://archive.org/details/financiali00unit CONTENTS (The same table or contents appears in Books I and II) Page Preface ---------------------------------------------------------- II FINE Study Discussion Principles--------------------------- --------VII Part 1-Depository Institutions and Housing--------------------------- 25 1. "Housing and Financial Reorganization," by Dr. Craig Swan, Associate Professor of Economics, University of Minnesota----- 27 2. "A Program to Protect Mortgage Lenders Against Interest Rate Increases," by Dr. James L. Pierce, Consultant and Director of the FINE Study-------------------------------------------- 93 3. "Evaluations of Selected Subsidized Housing Programs," by Rich- ard L. Wellons, Economic Analyst, Congressional Research Serv- ice, The Library of Congress-------------------------------- 101 4. "Credit Unions as Viable Financial Intermediaries," by Dr. David I. Fand, Professor of Economics, Wayne State University-------- 117 Part 2-Regulation of Depository Institutions------------------------- 143 1. "The Structure of Federal Regulation of Depository Institutions," by Dr. Samuel B. Chase, Jr., Consultant, Washington, D.C ------ 145 2. "Opportunity and Responsibility in a Financial Institution," by Dr. Donald D. Hester, Professor of Economics, University of Wisconsin ------------------------------------------------173 3. "Financial Innovation and EFTS: Implication for Regulation," by Dr. William L. Silber, Professor of Economics and Finance, and Dr. Kenneth D. Garbade, Assistant Professor of Finance, New York University------------------------------------------- 193 4. "Bank Trust Departments and Public Policy Today," by Roy A. Schotland, Professor of Law, Georgetown University Law School ----------------------------------------------------211 5. "Bank Holding Companies and Public Policy Today," by Roy A. Schotland. Professor of Law. Georgetown University Law School- 233 6. Questionnaire: Questions on Regulation and Supervision of Banks, submitted to the Federal Banking Agencies by the Banking, Cur- rency and Housing Committee and the Subcommittee on Finan- cial Institutions Supervision, Regulation and Insurance, U.S. House of Representatives----------------------------------- 285 Answer: Comptroller of the Currency-------------------------- 301 Answer: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System------ 463 Part 3-Structure and Operations of the Federal Reserve System-------- 667 1. "The Structure and Operations of the Federal Reserve System: Some Needed Reforms," by Dr. Thomas Mayer, Professor of Economics, University of California, Davis------------------- 66 Part 4-International Banking-------------------------------------- 727 1. "Foreign Bank Activities in the United States," by Jane D'Arista. Professional Staff Member, Banking, Currency and Housing Com- mittee, U.S. House of Representatives----------------------- 731 2. "U.S. Banks Abroad," by Jane D'Arista. Professional Staff Mem- ber, Banking, Currency and Housing Committee, U.S. House of Representatives -------------------------------------------801 [COMMITTEE PRINT] FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND THE NATION'S ECONOMY (FINE) DISCUSSION PRINCIPLES [COMMITTEE PRINT] FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND THE NATION'S ECONOMY (FINE) DISCUSSION PRINCIPLES COMMITTEE ON BANKING, CURRENCY AND HOUSING HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES 94th Congress, First Session NOVEMBER 1975 Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing The report has not been officially adopted by the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing and may not therefore necessarily reflect the views of its members. U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE WASHINGTON : 1975 (1) 62-748 0 76 bk. 1- 2 COMMITTEE ON BANKING, CURRENCY, AND HOUSING HENRYS. REUSS, Wisconsin, Chairman WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas WILLIAM A. BARRETT, Pennsylvania LEONOR K. (MRS. JOHN B.) SULLIVAN, Missouri THOMAS L. ASHLEY, Ohio WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania ROBERT G. STEPHENS, JR., Georgia FERNAND J. ST GERMAIN, Rhode Island HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas JOSEPH G. FINISH, New Jersey FRANK AN NUNZIO, Illinois THOMAS M. RE ES, California JAMES M. HANLEY, New York PARREN J. MIT C HELL, Maryland WALTER E. FAUNTROY, District of Columbia LINDY (MRS. HALE) BOG G S, Louisiana STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina JERRY M. PATTERSON, California JAMES J. BLANCHARD, Michigan CARROLL HUBBARD, JR., Kentucky JOHN J. LAFALCE, N?w York GLADYS NOON SPELLMAN, Maryland LES AL'COIN, Oregon PAUL E. TSONGAS, Massachusetts BUTLER DERRICK, South Carolina PHILIP H. HAYES, Indiana MARK W. HANNAFORD, California DAVID W. EVANS, Indiana ALBERT W. JOHNSON, Pennsylvania J. WILLIAM STANTON, Ohio GARRY BROWN, Michigan CHALMERS P. WYLIE, Ohio JOHN H. ROUSSELOT, California STEWART B. McKlNNEY, Connecticut JOHN B. CONLAN, Arizona GEORGE HANSEN, Idaho RICHARD T. SCIIULZE, Pennsylvania WILLIS D. GRADISON, JR., Ohio HENRY J. HYDE, Illinois RICHARD KELLY, Florida CHARLES E. GRASSLEY, Iowa MILLICENT FENWICK, New Jeisey (lIlI PREFACE As a means of insuring the widest possible participation, including that of consumer, citizen and financial groups, the following set of Discussion Principles, a result of preliminary discussions with staff and expert consultants, is submitted as a part of the FINE (Financial Institutions and the Nation's Economy) Study process. The broad approach embodied in these Discussion Principles is deemed essential to insure that proposals for the restructuring of our Nation's financial institutions clearly promote efficiency of financial markets through increased competition among financial institutions. Artificial and outmoded constraints which have served to inhibit capital formation required of a flourishing economy must be dealt with comprehensively if the credit needs of this Nation- private individuals, government, and business-are to be met. Hearings will now be held on these principles, leading to the con- sideration of implementing legislation. The Committee encourages the fullest possible participation, by the submission of suggestions, criticisms, and supplemental proposals. HENRY S. REuSS, Chairman, Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing. FERNAND J. ST GERMAIN, Chairman, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regulation and Insurance. (In) 5 CONTENTS Page I. Deposity institutions----------------------------------------- 1 II. Housing----------------------------------------------------- 5 III. Depository institutions holding companies ----------------------- 9 IV. Regulatory agencies ----------------------------------------- 11 V. The Federal Reserve System -----------------------------------15 VI. Foreign banks in the United States ---------------------------- 19 VII. U.S. banks abroad-------------------------------------------- 21 (V) FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND THE NATION'S ECONOMY (FINE) DISCUSSION PRINCIPLES TITLE I: DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS A coordinated approach is needed to strengthen our depository in- stitutions. Artificial ceilings on interest rates paid to depositors re- duce the incentive for Americans to save, discriminate against small savers, and have not succeeded in preventing disintermediation. All forms of depository institutions need broader and clearer powers with respect to both sources and uses of funds. More competition, and better informed depositors, borrowers, and investors, could provide an appropriate bicentennial for Adam Smith. Regulation, examina- tion and supervision of depository institutions must be coordinated to protect depositor and stockholder interests; to provide equitable treatment of prospective borrowers; and to prevent laxity and waste of government personnel. The reformed depository institutions should be treated equally from the standpoint of taxation. All this requires that the reform of depository institutions be viewed as a totality, and not a set of disparate actions. 1. Chartering and Conversion Any federally-chartered savings and loan association that wishes to convert to a national bank charter would be permitted to do so, pro- vided capital and other requirements are met. Any mutual savings and loan association would be permitted to convert to a stock savings and loan chartered under regulations similar to those adopted by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board pursuant to the legislation enacted by Congress in 1974. Mutual savings banks would be permitted to convert to a national bank, savings and loan, or be permitted to obtain original chartering from the federal government. Each of these permitted conversions would be supervised by the Federal Depository Institutions Commission (See Title IV-Regulatory Agencies) to assure that there would be no special advantages to insiders or other abuses arising from the conversion. In order to en- courage competition, any new depository institutions would be chartered if capital and other requirements are met. 2. Sources of Funds All Regulation Q ceiling rates and the prohibition against paying interest on demand deposits would be removed by the direction of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission, according to a schedule which would avoid injury to the depository institutions affected and to the flow of capital necessary for housing, and accom- panied by a method of continuing to attract deposits in a period of (1) (7) 2 rising interest rates. In no event would these ceilings and prohibitions exist later than five years after the date of enactment of this proposed legislation. There should be no promise of final review of this action before the ceilings are eliminated, because unless institutions are sure of the demise of ceiling rates, they will not engage in the portfolio adjust- ments necessary to allow them to survive in a world without ceilings on deposit rates. The Federal Depository Institutions Commission, in consultation with the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Home Loan Bank Board, would have standby authority to reimpose interest rate ceilings, subject to Congressional review, should this be required by any financial emergency. Savings and loan associations, credit unions and mutual savings banks would also be permitted to issue demand deposits and other third party transfer arrangements. In the case of credit unions, such demand deposits and third party arrangements will be available to the general public only in the case of a community credit union in a low-income area. 3. Uses of Funds Savings and loan associations, mutual savings banks, and credit unions would retain their present investment powers, and be permitted to engage in expanded consumer lending, including the issuance of credit cards and the establishment of revolving lines of credit. They would also be permitted to invest in commercial paper, corporate debt and bankers acceptance. Savings and loan associations would be allowed to make interim construction loans not tied to permanent financing. 4. Disclosure To promote competition, the depositors, borrowers, and investors of depository institutions are entitled to more information than they now receive. The Federal Depository Institutions Commission would be required to obtain from depository institutions, and make avail- able by market area to the public, information respecting the amount of interest paid on deposits and charged on loans as well as informa- tion relating to capital provisions, foreign activities, loan losses, and the impact of holding company operations on a depository institution. 5. Relationship to Federal Reserve System All federally insured depository institutions would be required to meet, reserve requirements on their deposit liabilities, and on their liabilities to other depository institutions. All reserves would be held at the Federal Reserve. All institutions of a given size would be treated alike in their required reserves for a given type of deposit, except that any institutions that did not formerly have required reserves at the Federal Reserve would have reserve requirements imposed initially only on the increase in their deposits over and above their level at the time of introduction of the legislation. Reserve requirements on this initial level of deposits would be phased in over a five-year period. 3 All institutions that are required to meet reserve requirements would have direct, full and equitable access to Federal Reserve services, including the discount window and wire transfer system. Branches of foreign banks would have access to the discount window, but they could not use loans to foreign borrowers as collateral. The designation of a Federal Reserve "member bank" would cease to exist, because all federally insured depository institutions would hold required reserves with the Federal Reserve, thus, "membership" is automatic and meaningless. The Federal Reserve would continue to administer the discount window and the discount rate, and to set reserve require- ments, in accordance with general monetary policy considerations. (See Title V-The Federal Reserve System.) 6. Regulatory Agencies All federally insured depository institutions and their holding companies would be supervised and regulated by the new Federal Depository Institutions Commission. (See Title IV-Regulatory Agencies.) 7. Housing Incentives Incentives to depository institutions to encourage an adequate supply of funds at reasonable rates for low- and moderate-income housing are explained in Title II-Housing. 8. Taxation Banks, savings and loan associations, mutual savings banks, and credit unions would each receive the same treatment under federal tax laws. 9. Branching Interstate branching of all federally insured depository institutions would be allowed if branching did not conflict with state laws. In those states where there is a conflict, out-of-state federally insured depository institutions and within-state federally chartered institu- tions, would be allowed a branch in all Standard Metropolitan Statis- tical Areas (SMSA's) with populations of two million persons or above. All branching across state lines would be subject to the approval of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission, which would be responsible for assuring that competition would not be reduced by such branching. Mergers with existing depository institutions to form branches across'state lines would not be allowed. 10. Trust Activities At the present time only commercial banks are permitted to engage in trust activities. In order to increase competition and decrease the possibility of conflicts of interest, this power would be extended to savings and loan associations, credit unions, and mutual savings banks. The Federal Depository Institutions Commission would supervise and regulate trust activities, and only permit them upon a finding that the institution was sufficiently large and strong to support a trust de- partment. Such non-bank depository institutions would, however, 10 4 have to avoid business loans and business investments, which continue to present a conflict of interest problem for banks which engage in trust activities. 11. Securities Underwriting Banks would be permitted to engage in the underwriting of state and municipal securities, including revenue bonds. The present prohi- bitions on underwriting of corporate securities by depository institu- tions would be retained. 12. Electronic Funds Transfer Systems The Congress would await the receipt of reports from the National Commission on Electronic Funds Transfers before legislating further in this important area of new payment mechanisms. Existing regula- tory authority for new payment mechanisms would be transferred to the Federal Depository Institutions Commission. TITLE II. HOUSING It is not possible to consider meaningful reform of depository insti- tutions without confronting the problem of housing. Existing housing programs are clearly deficient, as evidenced by the wild swings in housing starts that continue to plague the economy and by the large quantity of remaining substandard and deteriorating housing. A keystone to housing policies has been the existence of specialized depository institutions that were created to devote most of their resources to granting and servicing mortgage loans. These institutions have been protected from inter-depository institutional competition for funds by interest rate ceilings on their deposit accounts. These interest rate ceilings prevent small investors from receiving a fair return on their savings. And they have not succeeded in insuring a stable flow of funds into thrift institutions. Because savings and loan associations hold almost exclusively mortgages which yield a fixed interest income, it has not been possible for them to afford to pay high enough interest rates on their thrift accounts to maintain a steady inflow of funds. Yet if thrift institutions are to be allowed to invest a significant proportion of their resources in assets other than mortgage loans, there is the danger that the mortgage market and hence housing would suffer in the process. While thrift institutions could afford to pay a higher interest rate on their liabilities if they could hold more diversi- fied portfolios, there is no assurance that housing would be any better off in the process. The Hunt Commission and the supporters of the Financial Institutions Act have gone to great lengths to demonstrate that if thrift institutions were allowed greater investment powers, and if ceiling rates on their deposits were removed, a miracle would occur- housing and the mortgage market would be better off. But the sole basis for this rosy conclusion is a questionable series of simulations of sophisticated econometric models. Stronger measures than wishful thinking are required to assure an adequate flow of funds into housing. The proposals that follow are designed to aid low- and moderate- income housing without using the depository institutions as the whip- ping boys of a housing program. While the depository institutions would continue to play a key role in financing housing, they would receive incentives to participate rather than be coerced. The incentives would be applied in such a way that broader uses of funds would be possible, and interest ceilings on thrift accounts would no longer be needed. 1. Alortgage-interest tax credit.-Any financial institution would be eligible for a mortgage-interest tax credit, along the lines proposed in the Financial Institutions Act of 1975 with one important exception. Eligible mortgages would be restricted to those on property destined for dwellings for low- and moderate-income owners and renters. This restriction will reduce the estimated $725 million annual cost (5) 6 significantly w-hen the program is fully operative. There is no reason to subsidize housing for upper income people, as the Financial In- stitutions Act of 1975 proposes. 2. Federal Home Loan Bank Board.-The Federal Home Loan Bank Board would be empowered to lend directly to any depository in- stitution, provided that the proceeds were used for purposes of grant- ing mortgage loans for low- and moderate-income housing. Con- struction loans for rental units to house low- and moderate-income families would be included as well as mortgage loans on these struc- tures. The maturity of the loans from the FHLBB would be determined at the discretion of that institution and could be up to the maturity of the mortgage loans granted by the depository institution. The interest rate charged to the mortgagor by the mortgage lender would have to reflect the lower interest rate the mortgage lender obtains from the FHLBB. The FHLBB as reorganized under Title IV would raise its funds through the capital markets under the auspices of the Treasury. In this lending program two factors would have to be determined: the amount of lending that would be made to depository institutions and the interest rate they would be charged. During periods in which it is desirable to stimulate mortgage granting activities of depository institutions, a relatively large volume of funds would be lent at a subsidized rate, i.e., the FHLBB would charge depository institutions a rate below what it must pay to borrow in the open market. The lower rate would be passed on to eligible mortgage borrowers because of the requirement that mortgage lenders add only a fixed charge to their borrowing costs from the FHLBB. The cost of this subsidy (the difference between borrowing and lending rates) would be met from general revenues, and would have to be the subject of prior Congres- sional budget and appropriation procedures. The FHLBB would be guided in its lending program by a co- ordinating committee comprised of the Chairman of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board, the Secretary of the Department of Housing and Urban Development, the Secretary of the Treasury and the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. The Chairman of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board would be required to issue an annual report de- scribing the planned lending program for the coming year and describ- ing how the execution of the program over the previous year accorded with the program that was planned. 3. Mortgage Reserve Credit.-The Federal Reserve Board would be given authority to provide reserve credits to all depository institutions on new and outstanding low- and moderate-income housing and construction loans for all depository institutions. All depository institutions that are required to hold reserves at the Federal Reserve would be eligible for the credit. .Thus for each dollar of reserves held at the Federal Reserve, each institution would receive a reserve credit against these reserves equal to a fixed percentage of its new and outstanding dollar volume of mortgage and icsidential construction loans. The reserve credit would enhance the attractiveness of mortgage and construction loans relative to other assets because the act of granting these loans would free re- serves that could be used for investment purposes. The credit would also ease the burden on those depository institutions that would ex- perience large reserve requirements for the first time. 7 The Federal Reserve Board would set the percentages for the credits at a percentage of qualifying loans that would, generally speaking, allow an institution truly specializing in low- and moderate- housing loans to substantially escape the new reserve requirements on time deposits. The only restriction would be that net required reserves (required reserves less the reserve credit) would have to be positive for all institutions. Because of the obvious influence that the reserve credits would have on the nation's housing program, the Federal Reserve would have to be guided by the coordinating committee described in Title II, 2. 14 TITLE III: DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS HOLDING COMPANIES The general statutory framework that provides for depository institutions holding companies' regulation and places limits on their activities should be retained. Both statutory amendments and im- proved regulation are needed to reduce the possibility that relation- ships between and among depository institutions and their non- financial affiliates can impair the soundness of the depository in- stitutions. 1. Federal Depository Institutions Commission.-The Federal De- pository Institutions Commission would have authority for supervis- ing, regulating and examining bank holding companies and holding companies involving savings and loan associations. 2. Competition.-In order to promote healthy competition among depository institutions, holding companies would be subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission so as to prevent the acquisition of bank or savings and loan subsidiaries which would tend to lessen competition in a financial market. 3. Avoiding Confusion.-Naming of holding companies, other sub- sidiaries of the same holding companies, and their affiliates in a way sufficiently close to that of a financial institution so as to cause public confusion would be prohibited. Any liability issued by a non-financial subsidiary would clearly state that the liability carries no guarantee by any depository institution in the holding company system, or by the U.S. government. 4. Prohibited Transactions.-The Federal Depository Institutions Commission would determine, before permitting any action by a depository institution with a holding company, a subsidiary, or an affiliated non-financial institution, that such action would not weaken the depository institution in question. Present limitations on the amount of loans between and among affiliated depository institutions and the requirement that they be secured, would be removed, thus treating these transactions as similar to inter-branch bank transac- tions. Transactions, other than routine deposit transactions, would be prohibited between a depository institution which is a subsidiary of a depository institution holding company and any investment company (including real estate investment trusts) which it manages or advises. 5. Public Information.-The Federal Depository Institutions Com- mission would obtain, and make publicly available by market area on a periodic basis, information concerning loans and other financial transactions between and among depository institutions, their holding companies, their non-financial affiliates, and institutions such as real estate investment trusts which obtain advice from a non-financial affiliate. 6. Independent Directors.-The Board of Directors of each financial institution in a holding company system, as well as the important committees thereof, would be required to have at least one-third their members independent-having no affiliation with the holding com- pany or any of its nonfinancial affiliates or subsidiaries. (9) TITLE IV: REGULATORY AGENCIES In a speech to the American Bankers Association Convention in October, 1974, Chairman Arthur Burns of the Federal Reserve Board characterized the present bank regulatory system as "a jurisdictional tangle that boggles the mind." This tangle of confusing, overlapping, and sometimes conflicting jurisdictions and policies, Chairman Burns noted, has resulted in a "competition in laxity" among the regulators that poses a grave danger to the public interest. The alarm sounded by Chairman Burns echoed past admonitions by knowledgeable officials. As far back as May, 1962, the former Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Governor J. L. Robert- son, warned that the tripartite bank regulatory system tends to reduce the standards of supervision "to the level of the lowest or most lenient." Hearings by committees of the Congress have disclosed a wide- spread increase in dubious bank practices approved by regulators who are supposed- to be guided by principles of soundness. These questionable practices include excessive foreign currency speculation, extensive bank involvement in unsound loans to real estate invest- ment trusts, and enormous expansion of banks through bank holding companies and in operations overseas. The collapse of three major U.S. banks, suggests that the quality of bank regulation may be inadequate. In part, the deficiencies in the present regulatory apparatus can be attributed to the jerrybuilt nature of its construction. Until the National Bank Act of 1863,. all banks were regulated solely by the states, which continue to play an important supervisory role. A superstructure of federal regulation has developed on top of state regulation. The Comptroller of the Currency supervises nationally- chartered banks; the Federal Reserve Board supervises state-chartered member banks, all bank holding companies, and so-called Edge Act Corporations (international banking subsidiaries of U.S. Banks); the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (which insures nearly all banks) supervises state-chartered banks that are not members of the Federal Reserve system. Within this three-headed structure, anomalies abound. The Federal Reserve, for instance, regulates bank holding companies, but usually does not regulate the bank involved. The Federal Reserve has sole authority over Edge Act corporations, but often does not regulate the bank with which the Edge Act corporation is associated. The Federal Reserve has sole authority to supervise the overseas operations of U.S. banks, but in many cases does not regulate the domestic opera- tions of the same bank. As early as 1937, the Brookings Institution called for consolidation of regulatory and supervisory responsibility. Since then, the Hoover Commission in 1949, the Commission on Money and Credit in 1961, and the Hunt Commission in 1971 all have made extensive recom- mendations for reform. (11) 16 12 Clearly today's complicated financial world cannot afford to run the risk of recurrent crises before adopting safeguards. The present system must give way to a single, strong Federal Depository Institutions Commission that will better serve both the public interest and the interest of the financial community here and abroad. 1. Creation of a Single Agency A single Federal Depository Institutions Commission would be created, which would draw together the activities of the Comptroller of the Currency, and the regulatory and supervisory functions of the Federal Reserve System, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the Federal Home Loan Bank System, and the National Credit Union Administration. The Commission would be phased in over a three- year period. Under this proposal the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and the National Credit Union Administration would cease to exist. The agencies that presently provide federal insurance to depository institutions would be combined into a single agency under the aegis of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission. The Federal Reserve Board would be responsible only for the conduct of monetary policy, as described in Title V-The Federal Reserve System. The Federal Home Loan Bank System would receive a new charter which would include the authority to administer the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation and to administer a program of housing finance that would utilize all depository institu- tions as a source of mortgage funds for low- and moderate-income housing, as described in Title II-Housing. Creation of a single agency would make it easier to upgrade the quality of bank examination, supervision, and regulation by enhancing he prestige of the agency and by concentrating resources on better training and recruitment of personnel. It would also result in sub- stantial savings through elimination of duplication. 2. Composition of Commission The Federal Depository Institutions Commission would be com- prised of five commissioners including the Deputy Attorney General, a commissioner of the Securities and Exchange Commission (selected by the Chairman of the SEC), the Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, and two representatives of the public interest, one of whom would be Chairman. The representative of the public interest and the Chairman would be appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate. They would serve six year terms, except that the initial term of the non-chairman public Interest representative would be for four years. 3. Duties of Commission The Commission would be responsible for the chartering, conversion, mergers, examination, supervision and regulation of foreign banks as well as all federally chartered depository institutions (including Edge Act corporations) and their holding companies. The Commission would also be responsible for the examination, supervision and regula- tion of state chartered banks, savings and loan associations, credit unions, mutual savings banks and the overseas branches of U.S. banks. This responsibility could be delegated by the Commission to state 13 supervisory authorities upon a finding that the state authority was doing an adequate job. Depository institutions not insured by the federal government would be omitted from the jurisdiction of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission. The Commission would also respect and observe the elements of the dual banking system in its examination, supervision and regulation of state chartered depository institutions. 4. Structure of Commission The Federal Depository Institutions Commission would have a dual charge: to encourage the soundness of depository institutions, and to encourage competition among them. To accomplish this, the Commission would be composed of two units: (a) One unit would pursue the examination, supervision and regulation functions relating to the soundness of depository institutions. (b) The second unit would be responsible for promoting competition. It would do this through analysis and recommenda- tions with respect to mergers, new charters, holding company activities, and disclosures of relevant information. The Commission would be required to submit a public report and testify at least once a year before the appropriate committees of Congress with respect to its efforts to improve the competitive performance of depository institutions and its efforts to promote soundness. TITLE V. THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM The impact of the Federal Reserve System's conduct of monetary policy on economic growth, jobs and inflation has grown enormously since the system was established in 1914. Yet the structure of the Fed has never basically changed. It remains, in important ways, essentially a "banker's bank," its control largely in the hands of American financial and industrial interests. Member banks own the stock of the 12 Reserve Banks. Two-thirds of the directors of each Federal Reserve Bank are elected by member banks, the remaining one-third by the Board of Governors. The Boards of Directors then elect the presidents of the Reserve Banks, who in turn wield important influence on the Federal Open Market Committee, which sets monetary policy. Congressional and public involvement in monetary decisions which affect all Americans has been peripheral, and easily ignored. In con- trast with fiscal policy, which is hammered out on the forge of public debate and in give and take between the executive and legislative branches, monetary policy is shaped largely in secret. In its virtually complete control over monetary policy the Fed can largely offset the effects of fiscal policies determined by democratic process. The Fed can-by either intent or by error-precipitate inflation or recession. The experiences of 1966, 1969, 1973, and 1974 bear witness to this power. The removal of monetary policy from public pressure is both a virtue and a vice. It allows monetary policy to be flexible in a way that is virtually impossible for spending and taxation policy. It exempts monetary policy from narrow political considerations. But the balance between independence and public accountability is tipped too far in one direction. The Federal Reserve has become almost a fourth branch of government, exempt from the system of checks and balances written into the Constitution for other areas of public policy. The recommendations that follow are designed to bring the Federal Reserve more into the public realm, more responsive to the needs of all major constituencies of American society. At the same time, the Federal Reserve would retain the scope for flexibility in policy, and a measureof independence great enough to insulate policy from transi- tory political considerations. 1. THE FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Due to the transfer of certain responsibilities now vested in the Federal Reserve Board to the Federal Depository Institutions Com- mission, the present Board of Governors consisting of seven governors, would be replaced over time by a five member Board which would continue to be appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate. The governors would serve staggered terms of ten years, with a new term available every two years. This is the same turnover rate that currently exists with seven governors and fourteen year terms. In (15) 19 16 order to effect an orderly transition from a seven member board to a five member Board, the first two terms to expire after the enactment of this legislation would not be filled. The President would select a Chairman of the Board from among the five Governors, subject to confirmation by the Senate. The Chairman's term would be for four years, and would be co-terminous with that of the President. The operations of the Federal Reserve System, except for monetary policy and for transactions on behalf of foreign central banks, would be subject to audit by the General Accounting Office. 2. REGIONAL RESERVE BANKS A. Responsibilities Regional Federal Reserve Banks would have no regulatory respon- sibilities, because the responsibilities would be transferred to the new Federal Depository Institutions Commission. The stock of the Reserve Banks would be retired, and the banks would become purely a govern- ment institution. Reserve banks would continue to perform their current functions of discount facilities, check clearing, funds transfers, coin and currency distribution, research, and public distribution of data and special analyses. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York would continue to conduct open market operations and foreign exchange activities on instruction from the Board of Governors. B. Presidents The presidents of the reserve banks would be appointed by the President of the United States, subject to confirmation by the Senate. They would have a term of five years and would receive salaries equal to those of Governors. Reserve bank presidents would be phased in as existing presidents reach the end of their present five year terms- of office. They would be required to be highly qualified to advise the Board of Governors on monetary policy, as well as to conduct the functions of the banks. The present Boards of Directors of the Reserve Banks would cease to exist, and the present function of the Boards in bringing diversity to monetary policy making (in terms of geography, business sectors, and other constituencies) would be met through the changes proposed in this Title. Each Reserve Bank president would present written reports of the Advisory Committees mentioned below, as well as reports of their own views, to the Board of Governors. All such reports would be promptly distributed by the Board to the general public. The Reserve Bank presidents would not vote on monetary policy actions, but would advise the Board of Governors on policy and would be present at meetings dealing with policy. The Board of Governors would promptly inform them of all policy actions. C. Depository Institutions Advisory Committee Each Federal Reserve District would have a Depository Institutions Advisory Committee appointed by the Federal Reserve Bank president comprised of representatives of those institutions-banks, savings and loan associations, mutual savings banks and credit unions-holding required reserves at that Reserve Bank. Members of the Depository Institutions.Advisory Committee would make their views known con- cerning Federal Reserve regulations that directly affect them, such as 20 17 the levels of reserve requirements for different kinds of liabilities and for different size institutions, the discount rate and administration of the discount window, operations of the Federal Reserve's funds transfer system and other functions of the Fed. The Committee would be comprised of twenty to thirty members, as determined by the Reserve Bank president, selected from large, medium-sized and small institutions, and giving fair representation to each type of institution. The Committee would advise the Reserve Bank president in open meetings, and would present appropriate reports and comments to the Reserve Bank president. D. Monetary Policy Advisory Committee Each Federal Reserve District would have a Monetary Policy Advisory Committee appointed by the Federal Reserve Bank presi- dent comprised of individuals residing in the Reserve District. The Committee would have twenty to thirty members, as determined by the Reserve Bank president, giving fair representation to finance, industry, farming, labor, and education, and the general public. All reasonable efforts should be made to appoint a Committee that is representative of the population characteristics of the Federal Reserve District. The Committee would serve as the eyes and ears of the community and would evaluate local conditions in the district. It would present to the Reserve Bank president in open meetings its views on how monetary policy actions are affecting the local communities and the nation. 3. MONETARY POLICY A. Responsibility At present, the three tools of monetary policy-open market operations, reserve requirements, and the discount rate (the rate which the Federal Reserve charges banks who borrow from them)- are wielded by three different authorities. The Federal Open Market Committee decides the extent of purchase or sale of government securi- ties, which influences interest rates and the availability of money and credit in the economy. The Board of Governors establishes reserve requirements, which influences the money, credit and interest rates in different ways. Applications for changes in the discount rate are approved by the Board, but the recommendation for such changes comes from the boards of Directors of the 12 reserve banks. This "system" is not only incoherent, but it also fails to pinpoint responsibility for monetary policy. The regulation of financial institutions would be removed from the Federal Reserve System and placed in the hands of the Federal Depository Institutions Commission, as described in Title IV. This would make monetary policy the full-time responsibility of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Monetary policy would be centered in this one responsible group, operating with the advice of Federal Reserve Bank presidents and the Two Advisory Committees described above. 21 18 B. Employment Objectives The Federal Reserve Act would be amended to explicitly make the Federal Reserve responsible for helping achieve the objectives of the Employment Act of 1946: to' "promote maximum employment, production and purchasing power." C. Economic Reports The Board would be required to issue an annual economic report similar to that required of the President. It should be issued following consultation with the President and review of the Administration's fiscal policies and at the same time, or shortly after, issuance of the President's report. The report would explain in detail basic monetary policy plans for the coming year, and how the Board has conditioned its plans to the relevant fiscal proposals of the President. The Board would provide its economic forecast for the coming year and explain how its policies would help achieve the results forecast. The report would also describe how its policies have been chosen in light of the Board's obligations under the Employment Act of 1946. D. Congressional Testimony The Board would be required to present annually its report to the Congress in order to present Congress with the formalized opportunity to express its views on the monetary policies contained therein. The Board would continue to report to the Banking Committees of the Congress every three months on the progress of monetary policy, as set forth in House Concurrent Resolution 133. 22 TITLE VI. FOREIGN BANKS IN THE UNITED STATES The growth in foreign bank operations in the U.S. has been one of the more significant developments in banking activity in the last decade. U.S. assets of the 78 foreign banks (with 180 U.S. offices) exceed $57 billion, up from $7 billion ten years ago. Foreign banks now hold 6.5 percent of total U.S. commercial bank assets, and 9 percent of all business loans. Foreign banking here is conducted by very large banks. Forty- seven-or approximately three-fifths-of the foreign banks engaged in banking operations in the United States are among the top 100 banks world-wide. Only 18 U.S. banks are among the top 100 in size of deposits. Foreign banks here have five major advantages over U.S. banks. These advantages result from the absence of any federal regulatory controls over foreign banks, which leaves jurisdiction to the states. First, they can engage in full-service banking operations in more than one State, a privilege denied domestic banks under the McFadden Act of 1927. Second, through subsidiaries and affiliates, they may underwrite and deal in corporate securities in addition to their banking business. These activities are prohibited to domestic banks under the Glass- Steagall Act. Third, foreign banks can hold equity investments in U.S. com- mercial companies or U.S. subsidiaries of foreign commercial compa- nies, while U.S. banks and bank holding companies are barred from such equity investments in commercial companies. Fourth, foreign banks are not subject to the "closely related to banking" restriction of the Bank Holding Company Act of 1970. Fifth, foreign bank branches and agencies escape the restrictions of member bank reserve requirements. The branches and agencies, which control some 80 percent of total foreign bank assets here, have been able to tap the Eurodollar market for purposes of lending in the U.S. without posting reserves. Domestic banks, on the other hand, have reserve requirements imposed on their identical Euro- dollar borrowing. In the period July-October, 1974, when money was tight and domestic banks had a reserve requirement of 8 percent on the use of Eurodollais for domestic )purposes, foreign agencies and branches brought $1.8 billion of Eurodollars into the United States, and lent $1.4 billion to credit-starved U.S. corporations and $.4 billion to banks willing to pay as much as 13 percent for short-term funds. As the Federal Reserve Board has recognized, this freedom from reserve requirements for foreign banks doing business in the United States seriously hampers the Board's monetary policies. Because the recommendations which follow, together with the other Titles, treat foreign banks generally like domestic banks, "grandfathering" would not be permitted, subject to a phasing out period. (19) 23 20 1. Interstate Branching would be allowed for foreign banking sub- sidiaries and branches, subject to the approval of the Federal Deposi- tory Institutions Commission, and subject to the same conditions which would apply to interstate branching by domestic banks. 2. Underwriting.-Foreign banks chartered in the U.S. would be permitted to engage in the underwriting of state and municipal securities including revenue bonds. The present prohibitions on underwriting of corporate securities by depository institutions would be extended to foreign banks, which would have an appropriate in- terim period to phase out existing operations. 3. Corporate Equity Investment.-Foreign banks, branches and holding companies (chartered in the U.S.) would, like domestic banks, be prohibited from holding equity investments in commercial companies. 4. Bank Related Activities.-Foreign banks would be subject to the "closely related to banking" restrictions of the Bank Holding Company Act of 1970. 5. Reserve Requirements and Deposits.-Foreign bank subsidiaries (chartered in the U.S.) could engage in all activities allowed domestic banks and would be subject to the same reserve requirements as are domestic banks, including reserve requirements on Eurodollar bor- rowings from their parent banks and other foreign deposits. Foreign bank branches (whose parents are not chartered in the U.S.) could not accept deposits in the U.S. from individuals, partnerships, corpora- tions, states and municipalities, because deposit insurance is not now legally available, and would be difficult to supervise if it were. These branches would have reserve requirements imposed upon their bor- rowings from other depository institutions in the U.S. and upon their Eurodollar borrowings. 6. The Federal Depository Institutions Commission.-The Commis- sion would be responsible for the chartering, conversion, mergers, examination, supervision and regulation of foreign banks operating in the United States. 24 TITLE VII: UNITED STATES BANKS ABROAD Overseas networks of branches and subsidiaries have been a major factor in the expansion of U.S. banks over the last decade. In 1964 there were only 11 U.S. banks with 181 overseas branches. Now there are 125 banks and 732 branches overseas, and branch assets have. grown from $6.9 billion in 1964 to $155 billion currently. At year end 1974, assets held by U.S. banks in their foreign branches were 14 per cent of total domestic and foreign assets of all U.S. commercial banks. An additional volume of assets is held overseas in subsidiaries and affiliates. This extraordinary expansion has created a reserve-free and largely unregulated international banking market. 1. Capital Adequacy.-The Federal Depository Institutions Com- mission would be authorized to impose such capital requirements, in addition to the present capital requirements, on banks currently engaged in foreign activities upon a finding that their capital is not sufficient to support such activities. 2. Overseas Departments in U.S. Banks.-To promote competition among banks of different sizes in international financial markets, U.S. banks would be authorized to establish overseas departments in their domestic offices. These departments would be allowed to engage in the same activities as foreign branches of U.S. banks. They could raise funds from abroad and lend to foreign residents without being subject to the restrictions placed on the bank's domestic activities. 3. Examination.-United States banks would only be permitted to establish branches in those countries which permit periodic examina- tion of the branch, and complete access to its records, by the Federal Depository Institutions Commission. The Federal Depository Institu- tions Commission would determine the degree of examination of subsidiaries and joint banking ventures which would be required to insure that the parent bank's capital would not be endangered, and would only permit these activities in countries where such examination was allowed. 4. Branches, Subsidiaries and Joint Foreign Banking Ventures.-U.S. banks would be prohibited from investing in joint foreign banking ventures, from acquiring a financial interest in a bank operating overseas, or from establishing a foreign subsidiary without advance approval by the Federal Depository Institutions Commission. Subsid- iaries and joint banking ventures would be allowed to the extent that the Federal Depository Institutions Commission determined that such activities would not endanger the bank's capital. Joint ventures overseas between U.S. banks would be governed, as now, by U.S. anti-trust law. Federal Depository Institutions Commission approval of joint ventures between foreign banks operating in the United States and U.S. banks would also be governed by U.S. anti-tiust law. 5. Federal Reserve Privileges.-Federal Reserve discount and borrow- ing privileges would be extended to U.S. banks only on domestic paper. (21) PART 1 DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS AND HOUSING 62-748-76--bk. I---3 HOUSING AND FINANCIAL REORGANIZATION (By Dr. Craig Swan*) INTRODUCTION This paper tries to make some simple points. Unfortunately to understand the interactions between housing and financial markets often involves rather complex interrelationships. The basic thesis of the paper should not be lost sight of and should be emphlia.ized from the beginning. The case for financial reorganization is very strong and compelling. It is only natural, because of the importance of mortgage financing, that concerns about housing get involved with questions about financial reorganization. Looking at the way housing has been: financed only strengthens the general case for financial reorganiza- tion. There is some uncertainty about how specific plans for financial reorganization will affect housing markets. The appropriate response to this inherent uncertainty is not to oppose financial reorganization, but rather to consider complementary policy responses that will work to mitigate any adverse impact on housing and mortgage markets. The traditional ways of financing housing have worked well in nor- mal times but not so well in periods of large movements in interest rates. This volatility in interest rates has characterized the last ten years and there is no good reason to believe it will not continue to be a major factor in financial markets into the future. Further, the develop- ment of new technology, related to the widespread use of computers, is giving rise to new ways of managing money that tend to blur and erase the traditional distinctions between financial institutions. Fin- ally, some of the past responses of public policy to these two develop- ments are not without their serious and unfortunate side effects. These public policy responses, primarily the regulation of deposit rates, have in some measure been designed to preserve existing institutional dis- tinctions. While they might have had their intended effect in the short run, their long run impacts have been much less beneficial, if not per- verse. Changing the financial structure would allow one to eliminate these artificial restrictions as well as providing the resulting financial institutions with the means to cope with volatile interest rates and new technology. There have, of course, been other policy responses that have been valuable additions to the working of mortgage markets. Their further development should be continued following financial reorganization. Examples of these sorts of responses are the elimination of the Federal National Mortgage Association from the federal budget, the develop- ment of GNMA guaranteed mortgage backed securities and a whole host of initiatives by the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Company to broaden and stabilize the sources of mortgage financing. *.AqQnesiate Profesor of Eeonomie.. University of 3Minnesota. A paper prepnrad for the- FINE Study, October 1975, revised February 1976. (27) 28 IMPACT OF FINANCIAL REORGANIZATION ON HOUSING What does financial reorganization mean for housing? Unfortu- nately, no one can forecast the impact of financial reorganization on housing and mortgage markets with certainty. There are at least three aspects of housing markets one might be concerned about: the long run size of the housing stock, cycles in homebuilding, and the distribu- tion of the housing stock. S'Ce of the HIo.sm.;n, Stork Co0,'ern about the long run size of the housing stock usually trans- lates into a coni-ern about, the impact financial reorganization will have on nmotitgage rates. The concern is not so much with what will haippvn to m,'-'rt-age rates next. year or the year after that, but rather w-ith what w\ll hl.prn to the average of mortgage r-.tes over a longer period of time. VWill mortgage rates, and hence the cost of housing, Ie ] ili,,,r or Iower ? We simply do not know. There are several econometric simulations that attempt to ascertain the impact of financial reorganization on the mort.g8ge rate and the stock of houses. These models are discussed below. By and large these simulation results suggest that financial reorganization will have little or no adverse impact on the size of the housing stock or the mortgage rate. There are, however, still questions, not only about the specific simulations and models but also about the basic methodology that sug- gest one should not accept these findings uncritically. In particular, I would conclude that the simulations do not offer convincing evidence of a beni ,'n impact and that one should, instead, conclude that the impact of financial reorganization on the housing stock and on mort- gage rates is still unklmown. HouIns'g Cycers With reward to the question of housing cycles, neither of the two simulations reviewed below looks at the question of cycles in home- building and what impact financial reorganization would have on themi. One point should be made cle:r from the beginning. Given dramatic increases in interest rates, cycles in homebuilding are to a large extent ilnherent in the nature of lHoium Houses are the epitome of long-li(ved, dIrab)le goods. The purchase of such goods is eCsily postponed temporarily when interest rates rise. If inflation continues to fluctuate and if monetary policy continues to bear a major burden for stabilization Ipolicy, then one would have to expect that we would continue to see periods of dramatic increases in interest rates and associated declines in homiebuilding with or without financial reorganization. There is the further question of whether, with financial reorganiza- tion, these declines will be as severe as they have been in the past. There is a large body of work that suggests that ait times of tight credit markets swings in the availability of mortgage credit have exacerbated tlie swing(rs iin obilding. A Aiajor element in this view is related to households reallocating their savings away from thrift institutions fnd toward the direct purchases of market securities at times when short-term interest rates rise. Thrift institutions in turn have fewer funds to lend as mortgages. At tlhe same time, yields on mortgages do not look as attractive as the yields on alternative assets, as the increase 29 in mortgage rates usually lags the increase in other interest rates. Institutions with portfolio flexibility slow down their accumulation of mortgages preferring instead to acquire other, higher yielding securities. How will financial reorganization affect this process? Under most plans for financial reorganization there are two potentially offsetting effects. Which effect will be stronger is unclear a priori. A major feature of most plans for financial reorganization is the elimination of ceilings on rates paid on savings deposits and an expansion of invest- ment powers for thrift institutions. Thus, in periods when interest rates rise, thrifts will be able to raise their deposit rates and continue to compete for savings. Expanded investment powers work to shorten the effective maturity of assets held by thrifts. Thus their earnings will respond more quickly to an increase in interest rates, enabling them to pay higher deposit rates. To the extent that thrifts can main- tain deposit inflows in periods of high interest rates, they may be able to soften the decline in mortgage lending. On the other hand, to the extent that they have portfolio flexibility, it may be at precisely these same times that other assets, offering more attractive yields than mortgages, induce thrifts, as well as other instituttion.z to make fewer mortgage loans. It should be clear that this shift out of mortgages. is to some extent self limiting. The allocation of funds away from mort- gages would be expected to re.sult in higher mortgage rates and lower yields on the favored assets. Thus at some point the portfolio shifts do not continue to look so profitable. However, at what point the shift out of mortgages would stop is not at all clear. The magnitude, and, thus the net impact of these two effects, the competition for deposits and the subsequent portfolio allocation decisions. is difficult to meas- ure. As a result there is a great uncertainty about the impact of financial reorganization or cyclical patterns of mortgage lending. Dhi.tNbution of the Housing Stock- The final area of concern has to do with the distribution of the housing stock, in particular the cost and availability of housing for low and moderate income families. I do not see that financial reorgani- zation has any special implications for the distribution of the hous;jing stock other than its impact on mortgage rates. To the extent that financial reorganization raises or lowers mortgage rates, there will be effects on the cost of housing for everyone, including low and moderate income families. To the extent that housing expenditures form an especially large fraction of expenditures for low and moderate income families, these families will be affected more than most fami- lies by a rise or fall in the mortgage rate. As regards the prospects of homeownership, to the extent that moderate income families are the marginal mortgage borrowers who gret loans when interest :rates are low and who do not get loans when rates rise. either because they choose not to buy at times of high rates or are simply rationedl out of the market on non-price terms, then financial reorganization will have large impacts on them as it raises or lowers the average mortgage rate and through its impacts on cycles in mortgage lending. To briefly summarize, there are several aspects of houtsin" markets that may well be affected by financial reorganization, but the specific impacts of financial reorganization are unclear. One can make plausi- 30 ble a case for different impacts. The appropriate response in this sit- uation is not to oppose financial reorganization-the other gains from reorganization are too great-but rather to consider the design and implementation of alternative public policy measures that will work to complement the aims of financial reorganization and at the same time guard against untoward impacts on housing markets or specific income groups. The paper also includes a discussion of some possible policy re- sponses: (1) do nothing more, (2) mandatory credit allocation, (3) mortgage income tax credit, (4) interest rate insurance, (5) an ex- panded role for the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Company, (6) variable rate mortgages. THE CASE FOR FINANCIAL REORGANIZATION The Congress has a long standing concern about the housing condi- tions of American citizens. This concern is hardly surprising and led in 1949 to a declaration of national housing policy: The Congress hereby declares that the general welfare and security of the Nation and the health and living standards of its people require housing pro- duction and related community development sufficient to remedy the serious housing shortage, the elimination of substandard and other inadequate housing through the clearance of slumnis and blighted areas, and thle realization as soon as feasible of the goal of a decent home and a suitable living environment for every American family, thus contributing to the development and redevelop- ment of communities and to the advancement of the growth, wealth, and security of the Nation. Congressional concern with housing predates the 1949 declaration and is reflected in forms of direct aid-public housing programs estab- lished in the thirties and other forms of subsidized housing in the sixties-as well as policies designed to influence the provisions of mort- gage credit-FI[A mortgage insurance. VA mortgage guarantees, the Federal Home Loan Bank System, and a host of other specialized mortgage n market institutions. The close connection between housing decisions and mortgage fi- -nancing is ablo not surprising. Buyinm a home is the larg-est financial decision most families make. For most families their ability to buy a home is strongly affected by their ability to secure mortgage financing. The importance of financiing to individual homebuyers, as well as to the development of rental property, is the reason why concerns about lhousing- enter into any discussion of changes in the. structure of finan- cial instit ut ionls. Tie development of financial institutions and their regulation, in part icular tie development of savings and loan associations and the Federal Home Loan Bank System, have reflected a concern on the part of the Congress to insure that an adequate supply of mortgage ,Iedit be available. In the last ten years there have been three dramatic dle,-lines in tle amount of new lhonwebuildin,(, 1966. 1969-1970, and 1974-1975. All of these (declines have been associated with a decline in s:,vi,,,gs flows tl, tlirift institiittions and a consequent reduction in mort- r;,,re lendin by these institutions. It is not surprising then that pro- posals to 111ange, thle structure of thrift institutions, specifically to weaken their relianceo on mortgage lending by broadening their invest- ment. opportunities, should give rise to a concern about the implications of .-,uIh a change for housi.ngr markets. The general case for restructuring of financial institutions receives overwhelming support among academic economists. The professional training of academic economists teaches them that competition is good. In a search for higher profits, firms are led to adopt lower cost tech- nology and the forces of competition pass these lower costs on to con- sumers in terms of lower prices. A major thrust of the proposals for restructuring financial markets, the Hunt Commission and the Fi- nancial Institutions Act, is to introduce more competition into finan- cial markets primarily by eliminating interest rate ceilings on savings accounts, allowing thrift institutions to offer checking accounts of one form or another, and allowing thrift institutions wider investment powers. These proposals would find support among academic econo- mists on general grounds of competition leading to increased efficiency. Beyond the general case for more competition, events of the last ten years strongly suggest that the traditional forms of organization may run serious risks in what appears to be a new environment for financial markets. These changes in the environment reflect the com- plex interaction of high and variable rates of inflation, a more vigorous role for monetary policy and the development of new technologies for handling money. There is good reason to believe that this new environ- ment calls for a reorganization of financial institutions, especially thrift institutions. High and variable rates of inflation and the more vigorous use of monetary policy in the last ten years have had dramatic impacts on interest rates. These factors have had an especially dramatic impact on the normal relation between short term and long term interest rates. The technical term for the relationship between short- and long-term interest rates is the term structure of interest rates. The discussion below is organized as follows: first the impact of the term structure, particularly changes in the term structure, on thrift institutions is examined. Then the relationship between the term structure of interest rates, on the one hand, and inflation and monetary policy, on the other, is discussed. THRIFT INSTITUTIONS AND THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES As mentioned above the development and regulation of thrift insti- tutions has reflected a concern to provide adequate sources of mortgage financing. By tradition savings and loan associations have been special- ists in mortgage lending. These tendencies to specialize in mortgage lending have been strengthened by regulation and tax advantages, so that currently the assets of savings and loan associations are almost exclusively mortgages. At the end of 1974, savings and loan associa- tions held almost $250 billion of mortgages, over 84 percent of their total assets.' Holdings of savings and loan associations were over 44 percent of total residential mortgages outstanding at the end of 1974. From 1970 to 1974 savings and loan associations placed almost 83 per- cent of the increase in their assets in mortgages and accounted for over 51 percent of the net increase in residential mortgages. Considering mutual savings banks as well as savings and loan associations shows 1 These numbers understate to some de ree the attachment of savings and loan associa- tions to the mortgage market. Savings and loan associations hold mortgages indirectly by holding GNMA. -guaranteed, mortgage backed securities and FHLMC participation certifi- cates. These holdings are not reflected in the figures above. 32 that at the end of 1974 the two thrift institutions held 56.6 percent of the residential mortgage debt outstanding. The two thrifts provided 58.3 percent of the net increase in residential mortgage debt from 1970 to 1974. For a long time the provision of long term mortgage credit by thrift institutions worked smoothly but recent developments, especially since 1965, have exposed some fundamental weaknesses. Thrift institutions have basically borrowed short-savings deposits that are for all prac- tical purposes withdrawable on demand-and lent long-home mort- gages with initial contract maturities of 25 to 30 years and effective maturities of perhaps 10 to 15 years. This sort of business was profit- able and not very risky as long as (1) short term rates in general were lower than long term rates and (2) rates on short term assets that com- peted for household funds were not significantly above rates paid by thrift institutions. . Sinec late 1965 the relationship between short and long term interest rates has changed dramatically. Table 1 illustrates the behavior of the spread between long term and short term rates since 1950. From 1950 to 1964 long term rates were consistently above short term rafe.s. In 1966 and 1969 the traditional positions of short and long term interest rates was reversed as short term rates exceeded long term rates. TABLE 1.-SELECTED ASPECTS OF DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN YIELDS ON LONG- AND SHORT-TERM SECURITIES MEAN STANDARD DEVIATION (long-short) of differential TIME Private b Public Private Public 1950-1954.......................................... --------------------------------------- 90 113 29 24 1955-1959 ---------------------------------------- 55 79 49 50 1960-1964 ....--------------------------------------- 83 104 35 31 1965-1970.......-------------------------------------...... ..... -81 -2 45 38 1970-1974....... --------------------------------------- 62 29 154 103 SYield on corporate bonds (Moody's Aaa) minus yield on 4-6 month, prime commercial paper. b Yield on taxable government bonds minus yield on 3-month treasury bills. Standard deviation=(l ,'5(S,-S))1" where S;=yield spread for particular year S=5 year average of S,. Source: 1975 Economic Report of the President, Table C-58. The period 1970-1974 may appear to have. reestablished traditional yield differentials. IHowev'er looking at the differentials on a year by y(.ir ,bs.isi ole '(ees t'relliildoiis variation in thle yield spreads. In 1970 yield spreads were low by historical standards. 1971 and 1972 yield spreads were ainonA tlhe highest, of the period. Finally in 1973 :tild 1971 yieldl spreads retistored their largest negative dif'erentials of 1i1w' )Priod. This trelllendotls roller coaster variation in yield spi,'::,1 I .- -,' 'u In i 1, stand;i'rd deviations of the yield spreads that are also pre-.tiifed iI 'T;i1ade 1. For the period 1970-1974 the variation i, yield sprle1ids, as nieIsu re('l by the standard deviations, is two to t ', tim largee ,as anv of the ("!Irlier periods. The yield spre:d( is of tremendous importance to thrift institutions l,(,:1,se t]Iyv are 1)0or1owimi ng short and lending long. When short term market int, r'evt rates rise above riat(s paid( on deposits, hotiuseliolds find that market securities offer more attractive yields than savings ac- 33 counts at thrift institutions. It is not surprising that many households then reallocate their savings away from thrift institutions and toward the purchase of direct market securities. This interest sensitivity of savings flows is well documented. See for example Hamburger, Modi- gliani, Gramrnlich and Hulett, and W. Gibson (Gibson suggests that savers may be becoming even more sensitive to interest rate differentials.) The problems of thrift institutions are compounded when short term rates rise above long term rates. Not only do deposits at thrift institutions look unattractive but also thrift institutions find them- selves hard pressed to remain competitive by offering higher deposit rates. Their earnings come from long term assets and do respond quickly to movements in short term rates. One might argue that when short term interest rates rise. above long term interest rates that thrift institutions should be expected to raise their deposit rates to remain competitive, even if it means that thrifts are paying out more than they are currently earning on their mortgages. Such a situation is part of the natural risk of intermedi- ating between long and short term rates. If thrift institutions are efficient at predicting future interest rates then over the long run their earnings from long term assets, mortgages, should be sufficient to cover expenses based on a sequence of short term interest rates. High deposit costs relative to mortgage earnings in one year would be expected to be off-set by lower deposit costs in another year.2 However three things appear to work against this outcome. One, the competitive effects of inter-institutional competition may work to put a floor under deposit rates and hinder any reduction in deposit rates when market rates decline. Two, thrifts may simply be bad forecasters. Three, the historical sequence of interest rates in the re- cent past suggests that the last ten years have been exceedingly diffi- cult times to forecast. In particular, recent fluctuations in the yield spread between long and short term interest rates have not been around an unchanged level of interest rates. Over the past 25 years the general structure of interest rates has risen. This rise has been particularly dramatic in the last ten years. A plausible argument can be made that these increases in the structure of interest rates, especi- ally since 1965, have to a large extent been unexpected by almost everyone. INTEREST RATES: INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY What explains the change in the behavior of interest rates over the last ten years, in particular the increase in the level of rates and the increase in the variability of the yield spread between short and long term rates? Economic theory suggests three major causes: (1) high and variable rates of inflation, (2) strong aggregate demand, and (3) a more vigorous use of monetary policy. My subjective weihting puts most emphasis on (1) and (3), inflation and monetary policy. Inflation Before discussing these factors in more detail a distinction should be made between what economists call real and nominal interest rates. 2 This is essentially the position argued by both Tobin and Kaufman. 34 Nominal interest rates are what most people think of when they think of interest rates. They are agreements to pay back so many dollars tomorrow for the use of money today. If, before these dollars are paid back inflation occurs, then the dollars that are paid back will have less purchasing power than the original dollars that. are lent. Economic theory suggests that lenders should be concerned with their real returns, that is the purchasing power they will get in the future in return for lending, and hence not purchasing, today. Thus if lenders expect inflation they will want to charge a higher nominal interest rate in order to compensate themselves for the expected loss in pur- chasing power from inflation. If borrowers also expect inflation then they will agree to the higher nominal interest rates. Their higher future nominal incomes will enable them to pay the higher nominal in- terest rate without affecting their real returns. Thus when borrowers and lenders expect inflation, an economist expects that nominal interest rates will increase in their expectation of inflation. Real interest rates are then a construct to take out the effects of inflation on interest rates. Measured after the fact, by subtracting the actual rate of inflation from the nominal interest rate, they tell one what the real return to the lender, and hence the real cost to the borrower, was. Measuring real interest rates before the fact is exceedingly difficult as one needs to know the expectations of borrowers and lenders about future inflation. With a distinction between real and nominal interest rates, let us turn now to a brief discussion of the change in the behavior of interest rates over the last ten years. Economists expect. that nominal interest rates will reflect inflationary expectations. While we do not measu-re inflationary expectations directly, we do know that. actual rates of in- flation have been high and variable in the last ten years. Comparing the period 1965-1974 with 1955-1964, one finds that the average rate of inflation as measured by the implicit GNP price deflator rose from 1.96 percent per year to 4.58 percent per year. The variation of the rate of inflation, as measured by the standard deviation, also increased dra- matically from .87 to 2.19 percent. To repeat, these figures measure actual inflation, not necessarily expectations of inflation. However, if market expectations of inflation were very accurate then these figures would also be good proxies for movements in expectations of inflation. Indeed, Eugene Fama in a recent, paper concludes that ". . one . . cannot reject the hypothesis that all variation through time [r1953-1971] in one- to six-month nominal rates of interest mirrors variation in correctly assessed one- to six-month expected rates of change in p)urtchllasing power. (Faiia, p. 282.) While there is not yet a consensus among academic economists as to Fanmia.s conclusion that changes in expectations of inflation explainll all the variation in short teril interest rates, there i" lln(loubt(lly a con.sentl.,is that expectations of inflation are responsible for a large slhare of the variation. Aggqregate Demand Shifts in basic demand and supply factors can lead to changes. in interest rates. As aggregate (ldenand in real terms rises economists would expect that real interest rates would also rise. (The increase in aggregate demannd may also give rise to inflation inducing yet a further rise in nominal interest rates.) The period 1966-1969 was a period of extremely high levels of aggregate demand relative to potential or full employment output. It would not be at all surprising that the expan- 35 sion of aggregate demand would be accompanied by higher real rates of interest. Monetary Policy The final important influence on interest rates has to do with the actions of the Federal Reserve System. Whether measured by changes in the growth rate of the money supply or interest rates, the last ten years have seen a much more vigorous use of monetary policy.4 This more active role for monetary policy reflects to some degree the fail- ure to implement countercyclical fiscal policy. This more vigorous use of monetary policy in place of fiscal policy has interesting implications for interest rates. Conventional macro- economic theory suggests that temporary restraint on aggregate de- mand can be achieved by the use of either monetary or fiscal policy. Even if both policies are successful in restricting the level of output, they will have different implications as regards interest rates. The use of monetary policy means that restraint is accompained by in- creases in interest rates. The use of fiscal policy means that restraint is accompanied by a reduction in interest rates. Thus the primary use of monetary policy instead of fiscal policy for stabilization goals over the last ten years has contributed to the recurring episodes of dramatic increases in interest rates. Similarly the use of monetary policy to achieve more or less perma- nent reductions in the level of aggregate demand would also be ex- pected to move the level of interest rates up while the use of fiscal policy would be expected to move the structure of interest rates down. As suggested above, the effects on thrift institutions of unforebeeii changes in interest rates is essentially asymmetric. Reductions in the level of rates lowers their costs, by lowering deposit rates. The reduc- tion in receipts is less immediate as it requires the turnover of the existing portfolio of mortgages. On the other hand, increases in in- terest rates have very imnniediate and dramatic effects, putting upward pressures on costs immediately while revenues respond only slowly. The above three are the major factors that economic theory suggests should influence interest rates. By 1964 there was little indication that inflation would become so persistent, aggregate demand would ri.e so dramatically, and that monetary policy would be called on to shoulder such a large part of the burden of countercyclical policy. Besides the term structure impacts, an unexpected increase in the level of interest rates also has unfortunate implication for thrifts. With a predictable level of interest rates, past and/or future earnings from mortgages should have been sufficient to enable thrifts to cope with a temporary reversal of traditional yield spreads, such as occurred in 1966. However, when the structure of rates did not return to its expected level, but instead, was higher, thrifts found themselves with large holdings of older, lower yielding mortgages that put an effective ceiling on their ability to offer higher deposit rates. 3 It is p^r-ible that an increase in aggregate dri-mand emold be nceoninahipd by lower, not higher real rates of interest. If monetary expansion Is the original stimulus to aggregate demand, then most economists would expect an initial lowering of interest rates which In turn induces the higher level of aggregate demand. Again the higher level of agerecate demand could give rise to inflation and induce a subsequent rise in nominal Interest rates. 4Comparing the period 1955-1964 and 1965-1974 shows that the average absonlute change in the semi-annual rate of growth of the money supply has increased from .J2 percent to 1.3.5 percent. The standard deviation in the semi-annual growth rate of the money supply rose from .98 percent to 1.2 percent. Analogous conclusions hold for interest rates. 36 Thie situation was further compounded by the fact that in such an 'environment any new or smaller thrift institution had a substantial advantage over older, larger institutions. The newer, smaller institu- tions would not have a large overhang of low yielding mortgages. As they attracted deposits and grew they could put virtually all of their funds into newer, higher yielding mortgages. Similarly depository in- stitutions with asset holdings of shorter maturities were able to com- pete more aggressively. Their shorter maturities meant their earnings would reflect the new higher level of interest rates more quickly than the earnings of thrift institutions. To summarize, the changed environment since 1965, specifically higher and more variable interest rates, has threatened the tradi- tional role of thrift institutions and exposed them to potential insol- vencv. If sufficient numbers of depositors had demanded their funds, thrift institutions would have been forced to liquidate their holdings of mortgages. High market rates of interest work to lower the market value of existing assets with lower rates of interest. It is not incon- ceivable that the market value of the mortgage portfolio of a good number of thrift institutions has at times been insufficient to cover their total deposit liabilities. Thus the continuation of old ways of doing business-borrowing short and lending long-in a changed environment-higher, more variable and unpredictable interest rates-has the potential of threat- eninjr the solvency of a number of thrift institutions and by extension the stability of the whole financial structure. Just because we have had these. problems in the past is no guarantee that they will continue in the future, but neither is it a guarantee that they will never reappear. There is a need to consider alternative forms of organization that will behive well in both good times and bad. NEW TECHNOLOGY Another element of the changing environment of financial markets lhas important implications for the organization of depository institu- tions: The development of electronic funds transfer systems. I want to make. two major points here. (1) The development of new technology for money management is blurring traditional distinctions between tiime and demand deposits, and (2) these new technologies offer promise of a significant reduction in the costs of managing money, reductions that should be passed on to consumers. It is the forces of competition that economists would rely on to see that these savings are ind(leed passed on to consumers in terms of lower transactions costs and higher yields on account balances. In summary, the changing environment is making traditional forms of organization and regulation obsolete. Changes in the level and vanratioll in interest, rates pose problems of possible instability. New terhi lolo.zy is ,breaking down old distinctions. IPAST RIISPONSE OF PUBLIC POLICY 'l'e d(evelopmnets of the last ten years have not occurred in a vac- uiuim. 11The pl rinriois position of savings, and loans and the pro- no, nced cycles in mortgage lending and homebuilding have prompted public policy responses. h however, the continual discussion of the need for financial reorganization strongly implies that past responses have not been sufficient. A brief discussion of the major aspects of past responses is useful for getting some perspective on what should and should not be continued. CON TROLS ON DEPOSIT RATES Controls on deposit rates were introduced in 1966 in response to the sorts of pressures described above. High short term interest rates made direct market securities more attractive than deposits at thrift institutions; commercial banks, and some smaller savings and loan associations, were becoming more aggressive in competing for savings deposits. Larger thrift institutions found themselves in a difficult position. Higher interest rates and aggressive competition were pres- surizing them to raise their deposit rates yet their earnings were to a large extent predetermined by their holdings of mortgages made at lower interest rates. It was in this environment that controls over deposit rates were extended to thrift institutions in September 1966." Deposit rate controls do work to limit inter-institutional competi- tion for deposits but they do not eliminate the competition betweeii deposits and direct market securities. The term intermediation means the use of specialized financial institutions as intermediators between wealth holding units-i.e., households-and debt units-borrowers, some of whom may b. other households. Disintermediation means the disruption of this process as wealth holding units lend directly to debtor units. One way of lending directly is to buy credit market securities directly. Thus deposit rate controls cannot be expected to limit disintermediation. In fact deposit rate controls may accentuate disintermediation as financial institutions are limited in the response they can make to high market interest rates. Academic economists are close to unanimous in their condemnation of Regulation Q ceilings on savings deposits. There are two major thrusts to this condemnation. (1) The ceilings produce distortions that work to limit the amount of credit to some sectors. Units that see a diminished supply of credit are those that traditionally borrow from depository institutions that are constrained by the regulation, i.e., households. (2) The ceilings have unfortunate distribution effects as wealthier savings units have the resources and sophistication to get around ceilings. As a consequence, poorer, less sophisticated sav- ings units are left paying the price of regulation by getting lower returns on their savings. That households have been sensitive to interest differential is beyond dispute. Numerous econometric studies of household savings behavior have found the allocation of household savings to be responsive to interest rate differentials. The data in Table 2 illustrate this point. The importance of direct market securities in the savings plans of households shows marked swings, swings that are attributable to inter- est rate differentials. While deposit rate controls have limited inter- institutional competition they have had no impact on the competition of direct market securities. At times of high market interest rates households have directed a substantial portion of their savings away r See Jaffee (1973) for a more complete discussion of the adoption of deposit rate controls. 38 from depository institutions in general, and thrift institutions in particular, and purchased general market securities instead. TABLE 2.-THE ALLOCATION OF DISPOSABLE HOUSEHOLD SAVINGS 1 [In percent] Deposits Credit at financial Deposits Yield on Yield on 3 mo market institutions at thrift deposits at Treasury Year instruments plus currency institutions S. & L.'sS bills 1960-65.............................. ------------------------------ 14 86 43 --.-....----......--.... 1966--------------------------------................................. 42 58 18 4.48 4.881 1967---------------------------------................................ 6 94 34 4.68 4.321 1968.... ---------------------............................. 22 78 24 4.71 5.399 1969................................----------------------------- 82 18 19 4.81 6.677 1970 -------------------------------........ -2 102 31 5.14 6.458 1971---------------------------...............................- --- -12 112 56 5.30 4.348 1972---------------------------------................................. 9 91 61 5.37 4.071 1973.------------........--.....------------------...... 27 73 26 5.51 7.041 1974 -------------------------------- 26 74 25 5.96 7.886 19752 .......---------------------------------.................. -1 101 60 6.16 5.637 I Deposits plus credit market instruments from flow of funds statistics. 2 First 6 mo. 3 Effective interest/dividend rates paid by FSLIC-insured S. & L.'s. Source: Cols. (1), (2), (3) based on flow of funds data, Federal Reserve, col. (4) "Federal Home Loan Bank Board Jour- nal," October 1975, col. (5) "Economic Report of the President 1975," "Federal Reserve Bulletin." The ability of households to engage in these asset switches is to some extent determined by the. sophistication of the households in question and the size of their portfolios. Larger portfolios mean lower trans- actions costs and are generally associated with more sophisticated savers. Kane (1970) presents evidence from the 1962 Survey of Fi- nanr'ial Characteristics of Consumers that shows that market securities form a much more important part of the asset holdings of higher income households. The clear implication is that higher income house- hold(s have the means, experience and sophistication to get around deposit rate ceilings and obtain higher yields by direct purchase of market securities. It is the poorer, less sophisticated saver who is stuck with lower returns on his savings deposits. Given the failure of initial deposit rate controls to stop disinterme- diation, there were further public policy responses. However, these re- sponses-the elimination of interest rate ceilings on large denomina- tion savi-ngs certificates and the institution of large minimum (denominations on certain types of public securities-have only erected further barriers between the options open to poor and rich savers. Trlese responses also illustrate a more general principle: controls often require additional controls as individuals attempt to get around the original controls. The first type of response-the elimination of ceil- ings on large denomination certificates---enabled depository institu- fions to offer competitive rates of return to savers with large amounts of funds, thus linliting tlhe incentive for these savers to move their funds. The second type of response-minimum denominations on 'lrensllry ltblls and FINMA de)entures-mlade it. more (lifficlllt, for smaller savers to invest directly in market securities, thus confining them to (depository institutions with below market rates of return. As Kane says. "It is shocking to realize how hard the federal government hlias worike(l to prevent the small household saver from sharing in the hiigh interest rates of the past five years." (Kane, 1970, p. 513.) 39 Market developments have illustrated yet another general point and that is the tendency of controls to become less effective over time as new institutions are developed to get around the controls. The new institutions in this case are the money market mutual funds that developed in 1974. These funds pooled the funds of smaller savers in order to buy large denomination instruments like government securi- ties, certificates of deposits and commercial paper. These funds offered savers high short term interest rates, interest rates that in late 1974 topped 12 percent. Investments in these funds were available essen- tially on demand. The funds limited their risk by holding assets that were extremely short term and quickly marketable if necessary. They thus avoided the term structure problems that thrift institutions got into. The popularity of these money market funds obviously depends on relative interest rates, the differential between their offerings of short term market rates and the rates available on savings deposits. However such funds appear to be relatively easy to start up and close down as rate differentials change. In subsequent periods of high short term interest rates these money market funds can only pose more serious competition for thrift institutions. The next time around households may have learned from past experiences and be even quicker to reallo- cate their funds. There is one additional effect of deposit rate controls that should be discussed. As mentioned above, deposit rate control has not eliminated competition with direct market securities. Some thrift institutions have at times found themselves hard pressed to meet past mortgage com- mitments and/or demands for savings withdrawals. Their response has been to borrow from the Federal Home Loan bank system through the advances mechanism-loans by Federal Home Loan banks to member savings and loan associations-established to cope with temporary emergencies. In recent years the use of advances has developed into a major source of funds for savings and loans in times of high short term interest rates. This use of the advances mechanism has several implications. The availability and use of advances does appear to have protected the profits, as measured by reserve accumulations, of savings and loans in times of high short term interest rates. In the absence of deposit rate controls one would expect that thrift institutions would raise their deposit rates to meet competition and dip into past earnings, if neces- sary, in order to pay these higher rates. As Tobin says: Over the years this sum [reserves] had been withheld from the owners of the institutions (mostly mutual associations) to protect them against just such contingencies as occurred in 1966-69. And was it so used? No.... There can be no justification for holding dividend rates down, and interest rates in competing institutions too, so that the undistributed nonprofits of savings and loan associa- tions can grow at their normal pace. (Tobin, p. 10) Another implication. of the use of advances surrounds the financing of the advances themselves. The Federal Home Loan banks first must raise the money they use to lend to savings and loan associations. They do this by issuing their own securities in general credit markets. To some extent selling their own liabilities works to raise general market interest rates. Some critics have argued that due to the effects of the rise in general market interest rates, the use of advances is to a large extent 40 self-defeating.6 As short term interest rates rise and savings inflows drop off, savings and loan associations turn to the Federal Home Loan banks for advances. However, as the Federal Home Loan banks raise the money in credit markets to lend to the S&Ls, their borrow- ings tend to raise interest rates even more, leading to even lower sav- ings flows at savings and loan associations and ani increased demand for advances. The critics charge that the necessity of first raising the funds to lend works to raise interest rates in general, produces more disintermedi- ations and works to offset tlhe direct effects of the advances. Higher interest rates induce still larger deposit outflows (see Kwon and Thorton (1971) and (1972)). Higher rates on general market securi- ties make mortgages less attractive to institutions with portfolio flexibility. As a result these institutions reduce their mortgage lend- ing. Some critics have asserted that the net effect on homebuilding of advances is zero (see Arcelus and Meltzer (1973)). These adverse effects are, in theory, present to some extent. However, there is still the question of their empirical magnitude. Do they in fact mea:i no n,'t impact on housing? A number of observers have argued that particular aspects of the above works may be bad esti- mates of the maffnitudes involved. (See Grebler (1973), Van Hornme (173), and Sw.-m (1973b)). Swan (1975) has surveyed the results of three econometric models that attempt to account for these effects and concludes that Federal Home Loan Bank advances do have a substan- tial impact in the short run. Homebuilding activity is raised from wleat it otherwise would have been for about one year.7 Te,..ardless of the effects of advances there remains the more funda- mental question of whether the elimination of deposit rate regulation in the first place might be even more beneficial. As mentioned above most academic economists would be inclined to argue that the elimina- tion of deposit rate ceilings would be more beneficial in total. Elimina- tion of the ceilings would eliminate the interference with market alloc.atin of credit; as well as benefiting small savers in terms of ]higher yields. If one were still dissatisfied with the implications for cycles in housing there would still be the option of attempting to channel more money into mortgages either by direct government pur- clase, or by expanded pullrchlases by FNMA. In principle, an appro- priate amount of FXMA purchases would have exactly the same. im- pacts on hoiisinir and mortgage markets as Federal Home Loan Bank advances (See S\'an 1973a.) MORTGAGE MARKET INITIATIVES Developments since, 1965 have given impetus to a number of develop- ne its t1ait have worked to restructure the mortgage market. The development of tliese new institutions and new instruments have worked to break down the isolation of the mortgage market from general capital markets. Tliese developments are to be applauded. ISlTilnir Issii. its own ,.I fiilt,.K to ral4e time funds to buy mortgages. T 14m11n11illdliiLg Is subsequently depressed by less.,er amounts for a longer period of time. Tlims sii <|,itriit dipre'smlon arises because one would not expect advances In any one year to winNl. 11t1 (,ffl'.vt on the equilibrium size of the housing stock In the long run. As n result. more, bumilIng in one .yir has to b e offset by less building than otherwise would have ofvirrt.d in sui.ibs.ri.nt yvnar. Swan found snlmilar Impacts for FNMA purchases. For more details see Swan (1975). 41 Financial reorganization should not imply the elimination of these changes. Further development and extensions are to be encouraged. Among the changes that have been made mention might be made of: (1) The splitting of the original Federal National Mortgage Associ- ation into two parts, the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA) and FNMA. This split separated the two functions of the original FNMA, subsidy support to specific mortgages, now handled by GNMA, and general support to the mortgage market through the purchase of mortgages, now handled by FNMA. (2) The removal of the new FNMX and the Federal Home Loan Bank System from the federal budget. FNMA was established as a government sponsored, private corporation. The Federal Home Loan Bank System retains its role as independent regulatory agency. Their removal from the federal budget means that their portfolio decisions are not as directly restricted by political concerns about the possible impact on the federal government budget as they were before 1968. (3) The establishment of the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Cor- poration (FHLMC). FHLMC has acted much like FNMA for con- ventional mortgages. In addition, FHILMC participation certificates work to improve the inter-regional flow of mortgage credit coming from savings and loan associations.8 (4) The development of GNMA insured, mortgage-backed securi- ties. These securities have allowed for the repackaging of a group of -mortgages to make them more attractive to investors who otherwise might not be interested in mortgages. Both bond-type and pass- through type securities have been developed. Data on initial investors suggests that these securities have been purchased by non-mortgage oriented investors at times that they have offered attractive yields. (See Marcis.) Other important developments include the development of an auto- mated mortgage market information network, the development of private mortgage insurance, the development and increased involve- ment of state and local housing finance agencies, and the develop- ment of a futures market for G NMA backed mortgage securities. All these developments have the effect of breaking down the barriers of isolation that have traditionally separated the mortgage market from other capital markets. This breakdown has been accomplished by de- veloping new institutions and instruments that intermediate between the mortgage market and other sectors of capital markets, by increas- ing the flow of information about the mortgage market, and the intro- duction of elements of standardization across what are essentially very heterogeneous instruments. These developments are to be applauded and encouraged. IMPACT OF FINANCIAL REORGANIZATION ON HOUSING MARKETS There are at least three aspects of housing markets that Congress is rightfully concerned about: what are the implications of financial re- 8 Both FNMA and FHLMC now have authority to purchase all types of mortgages al- though FNMA has traditionally dealt with FHA and VA mortgages. FITLMC de:.l< primarily with conventional mortgages. Giving FNMA and FHLMC authority to buy all types of mortgages is a good idea. However to the extent that discounting is an effective Way of making effective FHA and VA mortgage rates behave like market determinpid rates and borrowers choose between FHA. VA and conventional financing on the basis of effective interest rates, it makes less difference what type of mortgages are purchased by FNMA or FHLMC. 62-748-76-bk. I---4 42 form for: (1) the size of the housing stock, (2) the distribution of the stock and (3) cycles in homebuilding. The discussion below ad- dresses itself to these three concerns. In addition inflation has im- portant impacts on housing markets. Some of the impacts are direct and others arise because inflation has such strong impacts on interest rates. This section concludes with a brief discussion of the impacts of inflation on housing markets. THE SIZE AND DISTRIBUTTION OF THE HOUSING STOCK Concern about the size and distribution of the housing stock reflects Congress constitutional concern about the general welfare of Amer- icans. Economists view the size and distribution of the housing stock as reflecting the workings of individuals' demands for housing and the provision of houses and housing services by builders and landlords. Over a long period of time an economist expects that the size and distribution of the housing stock will reflect the demands of indi- viduals for housing. (In technical terms, in equilibrium individuals will be on their demand curve for housing). Major determinants of individual demands for housing are income, the price of housing relative to the prices of other goods and certain demographic char- acteristics, such as family size. (The relative price of owning or renting has important implications for the form of tenure.) Financial reorganization would not be expected to have major effects on either income or family characteristics. The major impact of financial re- organization would be expected to be on the cost of housing, spe- 'ifically the cost and availability of mortgage credit. Will financial reorganization raise or lower mortgage rates? There is no precise answer to this question. For one thing, the exact form of reorganization is yet unknown. All major proposals do forsee broader investment powers for thrift institutions. To the extent that thrifts exploit these new powers, there will be a reduction in the supply of mortgage credit for a given size of thrift institutions. Such a reduc- tion would be expectedT to raise mortgage rates. However most pro- posals for reform also incorporate expanded powers to attract de- posits: the elimination of Regulation Q ceilings and the ability to offer some form of checking accounts. Further, it has been argued that some expanded asset powers, specifically the ability to make consumer loans, may interact with expanded liability powers, the ability to offer clicking accounts, and produce even larger increases in the size of Slirift, institutions. To tlie extent that the increase in the size of thrift institutioiis means additional mortgage lending one would expect a rn.le .tion in mor gage rates. Whichl set. of forces will be dominant? How will ti lings come, out in the wash ? We simply do not. know for sure. So many of the crucial magnitudes for determining the overall rs p~os lel)%(l 111)eon the behavior of ind(lividtials and( institutions in Ia raMlONTr diiverent elnvirolnient. There are several simulations of large ','oloni(fric ,1od'ls tlhat suggest. that financial reorganization will l,:ave. little, or no impact on mnortgage rates. These simulations even rP:ise lhe le possibility that mortgage rates may decline. However, there are so me teclinivi:il questions and fundamental issues that. suggest a lO.^ <'alit(0ll1s <'oonllusion. Tlihe more technical questions about the Flr-Jaffee and H1endershott studies are discussed in the attachment. 43 Both of these studies use econometric models, modifying them in an attempt to reflect financial reorganization, and then simulating them over a period of history to see what would have happened if financial reorganization had occurred earlier. While attempts are made to rec- ognize changes in behavior, in a very fundamental sense the models still project past modes of behavior and response into the new en- vironnient of financial reorganization and the past may simply be a poor guide to future behavior in a new environment. There is another fundamental notion that users of these simulation results should be aware of. The original econometric estimation pro- vides the basic structure for the simulation exercises. The numerical coefficient that make up this structure are themselves estimates, sub- ject to some likely margin of error. The. corollary to the margin of error in the underlying coefficient estimates is a confidence interval surrounding any prediction. One would not bet all his money that actual outcomes will match the model's prediction exactly. Normal estimation errors and the stochastic nature of econometric models imply that we cannot know the future exactly, but plus or minus some error term. Thus any forecast is subject to a margin of error, the technical term is confidence interval. However simulation results are usually reported as the singled value outcomes of the solution of the mathematical equations of the model. The plus or minus extent of the confidence interval is rarely reported, partly because it would be ex- ceedingly complex and difficult to compute. What this all means in practice is that there is a wide range of possible outcomes, not just the one reported outcome, that would be consistent with the under- lying model. This wide range of outcomes undoubtedly contains ad- verse as well as favorable impacts on mortgage rates. It would seem to be a reasonable step for public policy to recognize this uncertainty about the impact of financial reorganization on mortgage rates and to consider appropriate policy actions should the impact be adverse. HOUSING CYCLES Cycles in homebuilding have been especially prominent in the last ten years. The primary cause of these cycles is the fluctuations in interest rates that have occurred over the past ten years. Increases in interest rates, particularly mortgage rates, lead to movements back along the demand curve for housing. This movement along the de- mand curve for housing implies an even sharper reduction in home- building activity. This conventional story of static, market clearing responses may be complicated by two other factors. During periods of high mortgage rates families may temporarily postpone the purchase of a home and/or developers may temporarily postpone the construc- tion of new projects to avoid what are expected to be temporarily high mortgage rates. Further the impact of higher mortgage rates may be compounded by credit, rationing, the allocation of mortgage credit on non-price terms. Credit rationing implies an even larger drop in housing activity than would be implied by simply looking at con- sumers' demands at quoted mortgage rates. The cause of this reduction in mortgage lending and increase in mortgage rates, in fact the way increases in interest rates in general get transferred to increases in mortgage rates, is from portfolio re:allo- cations induced by high market interest rates. Households reallocate 44 some of their savings away from depository institutions, especially thrift institutions, and toward the direct purchase of market securi- ties. These institutions in turn have less money to lend. Similarly,. financial institutions with portfolio flexibility reduce their accumu- lation of mortgages in favor of other, high yielding securities. During times of high interest rates people simply demand fewer new homes. Houses are very long lived assets. Economic theory sug- gests that interest rates form a larger part of the cost of owning longer lived assets. Thus fluctuations in interest rates have very strong" impacts on the costs of owning a home. Economic theory also suggests that people demand less of a commodity as its price increases relative to other prices. Housing should be no exception. Finally, for espe- cially durable commodities, like houses, price effects that might lead to a small reduction in demand ,for the stock of the good can have very large impacts on the rate of accumulation of the good which is itself usually only a small proportion of the total stock.9 The argument discussed above and the estimate in the footnote as- sume that individuals respond to new interest rates as if they expect them to remain unchanged. If individuals form expectations of inter- est rates, the outcome is a bit more complicated. If, during periods of high interest rates, people expect that interest rates will return to lower, more normal levels, one would not expect as large a decline in the basic demand for housing but there may be as large an effect on new construction as individuals simply postpone purchases that would lock them into expensive long term financing arrangements. By waiting three or six months they expect to be able to arrange much more favor- able terms. These effects of interest rates on individuals' demands for houses are not related to the institutional structure that provides mortgage fi- nancing. These responses are the normal responses an economist ex- pects when considering very long lived assets. Changes in the financial structure could not be expected to have much of an impact on the interest sensitivity of the demand for housing and new homes. Thus eycles in home-building are likely to continue to exist with or without financial reorganization. While one should expect that cycles in homebuilding will continue, with or without financial reorganization, it is not clear whether these cycles will be more or less pronounced than before. Housing cycles could be more or less pronounced because of subsequent events entirely unrelated to financial reorganization. For example, if inflation were reduced to rates of 2 to 3 percent per year, I would expect much smaller 8 This discussinn can be given a more rigorous formulation. Tmnagine a stock demand, 11, and a stock ad- just mnit process where RC = y(i-H- i)+0 I -i. RC(' iscurrent new construction; 11-1 is the stock at the end of the, previous period; A Is the rate of depreciation: and y is the coelliclent of adjustment. H Is a function, amonl other i hit1s! of the user cost of tnils of I. The response of new cost ruct ion to a change in interest ratf., R, is dRf( /drll =-ydf1/d R. Expressed as elasticities fltrR= Irn*,.r v i r.t IT'/RC, where ERC,R is the elasticity of construction with resp Lct to a clihing in interest rates; eii',c is the elasticity of the stock d,,mand with respect to a change In Ilhe usr cwsL: aiidl evr..n i, tlhe elastiit v or tihe user cost with respect to is change In inttrrpst rates. tH.,'r has brin estimated hy numerous invesigat-ors to he about -1.0. tr,rp. approaches 1 0 as the Ufe of Ih asset iprouIheles 0 and cnuild Iw approximated for a finite lifetime, on the asisunption of onei-hoss hay dleprerintlon. hv the response of the payment on a fully amortized loan to a chatIge in the interest late. For a lifetime of 50 years this is about .5 at real interest rates of 4 percent. Muth etlni-ats -y to he about .3. New conqtriiclion has been about 4 percent of the ,rock. or (II/RC)=25. Putting all these i pices together sugi(ests that tR'. could be as high as -3.75= (.3)(- )(.M5)(25). Thus a very small increase In real interest rates can have dramnliic Impacts on homebuildingn. Imagilie an Increase in Interest rates from 8to9 percent. Assumrne half of this increase Is an increase In real interest rates from 4 to 4.5 percent. Use of the above estimates Implies a reduction in residential construction of .17%. 45 fluctuations in interest rates and much smaller cycles in homebuildings, independent of any changes in financial organization. The important question is what effect will financial reorganization by itself have on housing cycles? It is impossible to give a definitive answer to this question. However, it is possible to discuss the important factors that will determine the outcome. I would identify two factors as being of crucial importance: the response of mortgage lending to a change in interest rates and effects on credit rationing. Under current institutional arrangements a rise in general market interest rates has two major effects on the supply of mortgage credit. One effect works through the reduction in savings inflows at deposi- tory institutions, primarily thrift institutions. Thrift institutions, especially savings and loan associations, virtually turn deposits into mortgages. When their deposit inflows drop off, so does their mort- gage lending. The other major effect on the supply of the mortgage credit works through portfolio adjustments by institutions with port- folio flexibility. When market interest rates rise relative to mortgage rates, those institutions with wider investment powers slow down their accumulation of mortgages in favor of other, higher yielding securities. Financial reorganization has implications for both of these factors. By removing deposit rate controls and broadening the liability base of thrift institutions it is hoped that the swings in deposit inflows, in response to a rise in market interest rates, will be moderated. Without deposit rate ceilings and with wider investment powers it is expected that thrift institutions will respond to an increase in market interest rates by raising their deposit rates in an effort to maintain deposit inflows or, at least, moderate their decline. This argument suggests that financial reorganization would moderate cycles in mortgage lend- ing, and hence cycles in homebuilding, by maintaining mortgage lend- ing and keeping mortgage rates lower than they otherwise would be. On the other hand, the wider investment powers, that are designed to enable thrift institutions to pay high deposit rates, give thrift insti- tutions the opportunity to engage in the same sorts of portfolio switches that other financial institutions can do now. This asset switch- ing ability raises the possibility that cycles in mortgage lending could be made more severe. Which of these two forces will be the dominant influence is diffi- cult to say a priori. Simulation experiments might shed some light on the question. However, neither of the two simulation studies reviewed above address themselves directly to the question of cycles. Further, any simulation exercise is subject to serious inherent limitations. All this suggests that we cannot be sure what effect financial reorganiza- tion will have on cycles in homebuilding. The second important factor for cycles in homebuilding is credit rationing. The effect of credit rationing is to moderate the movements in quoted mortgage rates for the given swings in mortgage lending. That is, credit rationing implies that mortgage rates do not rise suf- ficiently to equate demand to a reduced supply. Instead some bor- rowers are rationed out of the market on non-price grounds, perhaps by a change in non-rate terms, perhaps by simply a polite, but firm, refusal. 46 If financial reorganization were able to eliminate credit rationing as an important influence, I would expect two things, quoted mort- gage rates and the volume of mortgage lending would be higher at the trough of lending cycles. What implications would these two de- velopments have for cycles in homebuilding? Higher mortgage rates would normally mean less homebuilding, while more mortgage lend- ing would mean more homebuilding. Again, which effect would be dominant? One could argue that currently, with credit rationing as an important phenomena, quoted mortgage rates actually understate effective mortgage rates. A natural way to estimate the effective mort- gage rate would be to use the rate that would equate demand to supply, a rate that would be above quoted rates. See Jaffee, 1925, for an ex- ample of this procedure. Viewed in this way, the increase in quoted mortgage rates resulting from the elimination of credit rationing would actually be a decline in effective rates. Thus one would expect that the elimination of credit rationing would moderate cycles in homebuilding. What implications does financial reorganization have for the exist- ence of credit rationing? The answer to this question is not at all clear. To the extent that credit rationing is in part the result of specialized mortgage lending institutions whose investment options have been effectively isolated from general capital markets, then financial rM- organization, by helping to break down that isolation, may help to make mortgage lending more responsive to movements in general capi- tal markets and thus reduce factors which have made for credit ration- ing. On this view, financial reorganization would work to reduce the impl)ortance of credit rationing which in turn could work to moderate cycles in homebuilding. INFLATION AND HOUSING MARKETS Inflation has pervasivee influences in many sectors of the economy. Housing is no exception. Tle inflation in housing costs is of special concern because of the importance of housing as a basic necessity. Financial reorganization will have no direct impact on the inflation in housing costs. Further financial reorganization should not be ex- p)ected to solve problems caused by inflation in housing costs. The next. few paragraphs briefly discuss the recent inflation inll housing costs and solimc of its implications. Housing costs have increased along with most prices and nominal i'coimes. A detailed disc.us.-ion of these increases can be found in App)end(lix II, Housing Pries and Income. Generally speaking, house prices increased at alotl tlh sane. rate. as prices in general, and less tlihani income, from 1965 to 1970. When one considers land prices, as well as stuictulre prices, ho iuse prices may have increased slightly faster than prices in general. From 1970 to 1974, however, house prices-botlh structuretir and land-increased substantially more than prices in general. Their increases exceeded the increases in several popular jmieasiires of incole(le. Actual selling prices, which are a combination of the pure inflation in prices and changes in the characteristics of houses and lots, increased faster tlhan prices in general from 1965 to 1970 and less than prices in general froi, 1970 to 1974. Mortgage payments, which reflect move- 47 ments in selling prices and mortgage terms, showed substantial in- creases in both periods as the effect of increases in sales prices was compounded by the increase in mortgage interest rates. What has the increase in house prices done to the ability of most Americans to buy a house? This question is exceedingly difficult to answer, primarily because there is little agreement as to what sort of a house people should be able to afford. The tax advantages of owning a home depend on individual circumstances and the effect of capital gains is difficult to handle. When realized, capital gains work to reduce a family's real housing costs, but when buying a particular house, future capital gains have a large uncertain element. Some of the prob- lems in doing such a calculation are discussed in Appendix III, Who Can Afford a New House? This discussion also presents some rule-of- thumb calculations using data for new homes financed under FHA section 203. These calculations ignore tax and capital gains questions. This exercise suggests that there has been little change over the last twenty-five years in the proportion of the population that can afford a new FHA home. Data for 1974 show a drop in the proportion of the population that, using twenty-five percent of its income for housing, could afford a new section 203 home. However data for this one year may reflect the temporary influence of the beginning of the current recession with its associated drop in income. At the present time it is impossible to tell whether there has been a fundamental change in the ability of Americans to buy their own home or whether we are ob- serving the very real, but temporary, effects of the recession. The calculations in the Appendix suggest little change over the last 20 years in the proportion of families that can afford new FHA houses. The other side of that coin is that there has been little, if any, decline in the still substantial proportion of the population that has trouble finding decent housing for a reasonable percentage of its income. With- out meaning to deny the importance of this need, one should not ex- pect financial reorganization, per se, to solve the problem. Inflation in both housing and other prices, through its effects on in- terest rates, has had other important impacts on housing markets. To the extent that variable inflation has been responsible for the large variability in interest rates, inflation shares a large part of the respon- sibility for the recent boom-bust cycles in housing and the associated problems of thrift institutions. This impact of inflation on the term structure differential and the associated impacts for thrift institutions and housing markets has been a major theme of the whole paper. In addition, inflation, through its effects on interest rates, has strong impacts on the timing of real and nominal outlays when buying a house. Briefly, to the extent that interest rates reflect the expectation of inflation before it occurs, families face increased mortgage costs now, before their income rises along with general inflation. Tliese families will face smaller real mortgage costs in the future as their mortgage payments will remain unchanged while their nominal in- come rises along with prices in general. A full discussion of these effects is beyond the scope of this paper. The interested reader is re- ferred to the series of papers written under the HUD-MIT contract on alternative mortgages (see New Mortgage Designs for Stable Hous- ing in an Inflationary Environment) and "Inflation Induced Distor- 48 tions of the Real Economy: An Econometric and Simulation Study of Housing and Mortgage Innovation," an unpublished Ph. D. thesis by James Kearl. POLICY ALTERN-ATIVES Assuming that some form of financial reorganization is enacted and given a concern about the effects of reorganization per se on housing and mortgage markets, what sorts of responses might be considered? I will discuss six proposals. I cannot offer a systematic justification of why only six or why these six except the pressures of time and the results of circumstances. All six proposals are really aimed at the mortgage market and would be expected to have impacts in hous- ing markets as they raised or lowered mortgage rates on average and as they affected cyclical swings in mortgage lending. 1. DO NOTHING One course of action would be to do nothing as regards special arrangements for housing and mortgage markets in general. VWhat is being suTested here is to do nothing as regards the general impacts of financial reorganization on housing Mand mortgage markets. One might still want to consider housing subsidy programs of one sort or another to aid specific groups of people with specific hoisinf prob- ",m.s. but on this view one would do nothing as regards general inter- vention in mortgage markets.10 There are probably a fair number of academic economists who would naree with this policy position. They might, well argue that the present predicament of thrift institutions is due in some, or perhaps large, degree to past government regulation. In particular tax inducements and regulatory constraints created the set of institutions that borrow short and lend long. When these institutions got in trouble it was fur- ther government regulation-deposit, rate control-that perpetuated the old ways of doing business and perhaps added to the magnitude of recent cycles in homoebuilding when savers began investing in direct market seculrities.11 To simply eliminate deposit rate controls and ex- pon these institutions to the forces of competition for deposits would l1, ill advised if these institutions were still forced to invest virtually all their assets in mortgages. However, if they are also given expanded inve- nient powers then one might wonder what else needs to be done.2 If, as has been suggested, the futuTre continues to see periods of dra- matic reversals in the term structure of interest rates, well. the past has Warned ev'ervblodv that scl things can happen and financial reorga- ilization This given these instit it ions the opportunity to diversify their ])port folios in order to cope with such periods. I' Tn fact none "f thi other pronoqln (1i.o.p1 lielow are mennt to h e viewd'ri nq hniilnz il,,:Ii,,- nr',ir'qm All ofTfr Lenral sn-nmort frr thie mnrtLnc, mnrlt nndl nre o rnnl.tpnt with or rllhniitf nlitinncil Mna liliep. nlimed at vtippiefie rrnin. TIowovpr. some of the programs coildl emIlly lip modified to offer lfTprentlInl limnpt fit io lower Ineomp groups. 11 ITn i.rilit i'nnO l ',' i n0 l without 41,',,,, t rnte erlln,]|". lonrl finds that thp ImnonRitlon rf rPllnaq mnakep for hi1liher pa'ks nnil lower tronmgh. Th, eonclideq. ". It would annonr l )it .vi ', 1.iI1. the vr lliiw.:s w r iltunllYv slglitly deNtIalt Izing In the effects on lhouglng." il't-nir. i '271.) 7 A i 1vif'tps of tl0i- fri.o. 11 nr'L' l it ld tmaurket po ,nll4ton vrotl1d. Tpriimnnldy alo nr-ii, not Nlii't for itl'r.r Invtnt ent imw\,rz' hut. morr f"ndrimpntnlly. no rnptreftlonn on nnv Invps-. mont tTflonr. Three mnav he n ornnition prolilem nq tlhe riilps of thbp rnmp Pre elinnpeed. 1.''oTo, Rnv nro fre t lilonillv i ,r'n"l nhonut -iili pr' ielpmi r fprrlrn' 1nftend tn tf lk nhmint op"',Iliirilim witfl fl;o |*w ril',q Thi,-n frnnrtflnq nrno'lpne --tho ep0stinu ponrtolIo of low vIh.llin' mo-rf :'';iVh- nT1clit i,1-tlf\' ','irui :ort of o'Pnornrpv ,ihs.-'d epnoInllyv If dotn.nlt rnt eoitfrol.- w'ore pldi fnti,-'l s.'il-utlv. The i',tif" $ V for a c-iihill. becomes less if the explratli n ,f 1. i o; ,it rate con I rol. Is fixel now for some line In lhe future. 49 As for the question of what would happen to mortgage rates in such a world, proponents of this view might well respond, "what does it matter whether mortgage rates go up or down?" Higher mortgage rates would eventually mean a smaller housing stock in the aggregate and lower mortgage rates would eventually mean a slightly larger housing stock, but who is to say that the housing stock or the mortgage rate should be such and such a number. Housing concerns for special groups are apt to remain whether we have financial reorganization or not, whether the mortgage rate goes up or down. The special needs of these people should be met by direct subsidy of one form or another. It would be a great mistake to reject financial reorganization, with its associated benefits for wide groups of people, because of uncertainty about its possible adverse impact on a smaller group of people. One should not expect financial reorganization with its associated implications for the ecicncy of financial markets to solve the housing problems of low and moderate income families. There is a strong presumption that their needs can be more efficiently met by direct subsidy. Whatever the mortgage rate ends up to be will reflect the market's impersonal determination of the rate necessary to balance the forces of supply and demand. One would not expect the mortgage rate to get far out of line from other interest rates, adjusted for the differen- tial risks and costs of servicing mortgages. If mortgage rates did rise way above other rates adjusted for differential costs, then profit opportunities would exist for some institutions to make mortgages. Believers in the market mechanism would expect this opportunity to be exploited. As for high mortgage rates today, who is to say mortgage rates of 9 to 9.5 percent are high when inflation is occurring at rates of 10 to 12 percent a year and when corporate bond rates also are 9 percent. From 1955 to 1964, mortgage rates averaged almost 150 basis points higher than the Aaa corporate bond rate. That differential has now dropped to around 50 basis points. That is, the increase in mortgage rates on both a percentage and absolute basis has been less than the increase in corporate borrowing rates. In other words, corporate borrowers have seen a larger increase in their costs of borrowing than households. Proponents of this free market position would also not be surprised to see cycles in homebuilding in the future. Such cycles are inherent in the long lived nature of houses. Whether these cycles would be more or less pronounced than before is hard to say and, some proponents might argue, beside the point. I must admit that there are some strands of the above argument that are quite appealing to me as an economist. However implicit in the whole argument is basic faith that minimizing government regula- tion and constraints will enable the free play of markctt forces to allo- cate credit to housing in the most socially desirable way. One may simply be skeptical of that argument. Past problems with the mort- gage market may not be entirely the result of mismanagement by the government, but instead may be almost inherent in the nature of mort- gage lending. If the latter is the case, then freer markets may not necessarily solve all the problems of mortgage markets and appropriate government policy actions may be needed. Along these lines the pro- posal for expanded operations of the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation may deserve special attention. 50 2. MORTGAGE INCOME TAX CREDIT A key feature of the Financial Institutions Act is the mortgage income tax credit (MIITC). This provision of the bill would give a tax credit to anyone holding qualifying residential mortgages. The magnitude of the tax credit is related to interest income from qualify- ing loans and, for financial institutions, the magnitude of qualifying loans in the institution's total portfolio. Early versions of the MITC worked as follows: If an institution has 10 percent of its assets in quali- fying loans, it can reduce its taxes by 1.5 percent of its mortgage interest income. The magnitude of the credit increases until, when qualifying loans total 70 percent or more of assets, the reduction in taxes is 3.5 percent of mortgage interest income. Discussion surrounding the MITC suggests that the tax credit is expected to help achieve three objectives: (1) to broaden the supply of mortgage credit and moderate cyclical fluctuations; (2) to provide reduced borrowing costs for homeowners; (3) to allow uniform taxa- tion of different financial institutions. The tax credit works to raise the after tax return to an institution making mortgage loans, assuming it meets the minimal mortgage holding requirements to qualify. Thus the credit is expected to make mortgages more attractive and to induce more mortgage lending. It is hoped that the forces of competition will work to pass on some of this tax subsidy to homeowners in the form of reduced mortgage rates. Finally, the MITC is tied up with other tax changes that will hopefully work to make taxation of finan- cial institutions more uniform. Currently there are, in essence, differ- ent tax provisions for different types of financial institutions. Adoption of the MITC and the elimination of current differing tax procedures would allow for uniform taxation. While few would argue with the desirability of the objectives mentioned above, there are serious ques- tions about, the ability of the MITC to achieve these objectives, espe- cially the first two, and about the associated costs. BROADEN SUPPLY OF MORTGAGE CREDIT The MITC is expected to make mortgages more attractive to lenders by raising the effective after tax yields on these loans. It is expected tfliat this increase in yield will affect tlihe behavior of institutions with tax liabilities and portfolio flexibility; specifically commercial banks and mutual savings banks. The cyclical impacts of tlie VITC are a bit unclear. There is nothing counter cyclical in the MITC that could work to offset existing cy- clical forces. Tlie MITC would be in effect at all times. Only by attracting thle new lenders wlio would continue to make mortgage lo:mns tliriurh thick and thin could the MITC work to moderate cyclical fluctuations in lending. COMMERCIAL BANKS In 1-ie niretrrate commercial banks currently hold just less than nine p.,'.eeit of tleir assets in mort(rages. Ten percent holdings are tli mininimn requirement to be eligible for the. tax credit. For banks just below the ten percent floor, the one percent additional mortgage lending makes them eligible, for the tax credit on the whole of their mortgage holdings. Thus these institutions have a powerful incentive to increase their mortgage lending. However, for banks with only 2 or 3 percent of assets in mortgages the gains are much smaller. Table 3 illustrates this point.13 For a bank holding 9 percent of its assets in mortgages, and using the assumed mortgage rates, the effect of the tax credit is to transform the 9 percent before tax return on the .additional 1 percent of new mortgage lending to a 11.2 percent return. However for a bank holding only 3 percent of its assets in mortgages, :the increase in effective yield for the additional 7 percent of lending is only 35 basis points. Mortgage holdings of commercial banks average 8.9 percent of as- sets. However one would not expect mortgage holdings in the aggre- gate to rise to ten percent of total assets as there is a substantial amount .of bank assets in banks with very low mortgage holdings. As shown in Table 3, the MITC offers very little incentive to these banks to increase mortgage lending. In particular, large banks in New York 'City and Chicago hold over 19 percent of total commercial bank assets, but only 3.1 percent of their assets are in mortgages. Also there are a substantial number of banks that one would presume currently hold more than ten percent of their assets in mortgages. In particular, non-large member banks and nonmember banks, which account for 51 percent of total commercial bank assets, currently hold 11 percent of their assets in mortgages. As a class these banks would have a much smaller incentive to increase their mortgage lend- ing. Thus, some banks, but certainly not all, would have a strong incentive to increase their mortgage holdings to the ten percent of assets level. Once a commercial bank reaches the 10 percent of assets level there is a small incentive to continue to expand mortgage holdings. Addi- tional mortgage lending beyond the 10 percent floor does earn the mort- gage credit and, further, each additional one percent of mortgage holdings enables an institution to earn a slightly higher credit on all its mortgage holdings, not just the new loans. The magnitude of this effect is relatively small, ranging from 31 to 42 basis points as the proportion of mortgages in total assets rises from 10 to 20 percent. Much o,f the tax credit would be paid for mortgage loans currently on the books. One wonders exactly how much additional mortgage lending would be stimulated by the increase in yield? A casual survey of existing econometric investigations of commercial bank portfolio behavior raises serious questions as to how much. Most of these investigations have used time series data on commercial bank portfolio behavior. It is not uncommon to find only a limited response of commercial bank mortgage holdings to changes in the mortgage rate. For example, see Bosworth-Duesenberry. In fact, some investi- gators have been unable to find any significant response of commercial banks' mortgage holdings to mortgage yields. See Hendershott and Valliani, Silber, and Swan. All this suggests that there may be only a minimal response by commercial banks to the increase in effective mortgage rates implied by the MITC. '"It should be noted that the response to the Interest differential resulting from the MITC tends to eliminate the differential. Increased mortgage lending would be expected to reduce the mortgage rate. Switches out of other assets would be expected to raise those Interest rates. 52 TABLE 3.-EFFECT OF MORTGAGE INTEREST TAX CREDIT [Assumptions: Rate on new mortgages = 9 percent. Average rate on existing mortgages = 7.5 percent. Marginal tax rate = .48. Mortgage interest tax credit = 1.5 percent] Tax credit Percent Volume of Before tax After tax on existing assets in new lending return on return on Tax credit mortgages Equivalent mortgages (percent of new new on new per new Total after before tax beforee) assets) mortgages mortgage a mortgage b mortgage e tax return d return 9--.---.- ----- 1 9 4.68 0.135 1.013 5.828 11.207 6 ---......----------- 4 9 4.68 .135 .169 4.984 9.585 3.............. --------------7 9 4.68 .135 .048 4.863 9.35Z * (1 Tax rate) (Mortgage rate) b (.015) (Moit-age rate). e (.015) (income from existing mortgages) + (volume of new mortgages). d sum of 3 previous columns. S(Total after tax return) (1 Tax rate). THRIFT INSTITUTIONS The effect of the MITC on the behavior of thrift institutions is not at all obvious. Savings and loan associations are currently holding about as many mortgages as they can. Few people would expect them to hold more. Further, holding additional mortgages, by increasing their dependence on mortgage,-. would only intensify their problems as regards changes in the term structure of interest rates. The thrust of other proposals for financial reorganization is to lessen the de- pendence of thrifts on mortgage lenllding. Mutual savings banks hold sliglitly less than 70 percent of their assets in mortgages. Based on the assumptions underlying Table 2, the MITC would have the effect of raising" the effective before tax yield on mortgages from 9 percent to about 9.9 percent for an average mutual savings bank. However, for both savings and loan associations and(l mutual savings banks it would be possible and profitable to reduce their federal income tax liability by reducing their mort gage holdings slightly and holding a lir.ited amount of tax free municipal securities instead. Consid(ler a thrift institution of a given size. Consider whether it should make an additional mort(racre loan or byv a tax free municipal security. Under the MITC a mutual savings bank would have an after tax return of about 5.14 percent from making an additional mortgage loan. A savings and loanl association would have an after tax return of about 5.0 percentt.4 Either thri 't it4 it lution could, at current yields. earn a, before and after tax return of over 7 percent by buying tax free municipal securities.'5 Not, only are. tax free seI'ritie. a good investment ulit they work to redlce1 tax liabilities. In fa't, it is possible for a thrift institution to increase its after tax income and avoid all income taxes by holdinr an appropriate almomit, of tax fi'e minictuipals. Table 4 illustrates this (poitt for savings a1d l(o, as.11iiti1.. For an institution of a given size all a gi'vel( dep()sit rte, (dep()-it costs are fixed and unaffected by its p portfolio deci'-ions. As\ -l switcli betw'eell mortgages and Th, flifTfironn' In vl'lMldR reflv(t,4 iiin frnet thnt. on avernge. ntiitnl Ravines hanks ark below the' 70 prw-rcpnt MITC limit. Thiu, fiirthie'r rnort,'n pe invvstmpnts not only earn a tax 'r', .lil li 1t i li" iJ ioiili riik. fhli' ii'a iili''. if the 1.'itillt on Ill xi..thI..r niit-tnr-zP lhil tt- Incr-. The .irm pn[rIl.-,i, of nfter fix -yillvlk I lah..rnevt. from ni-sovlited spervicinrg cost. Includling sLich costs wn'i lriw r the' rut ift'vr I;x return ,!i 1IortvI: s. oA p rtfolif)o rf niiintinlipal .ei, uritie.s lians .int(, servicing costs, but they are surely lower thanii th i,., ol," ii jort ..i Irtl',iilli. 53 municipals has a magnified effect on taxable income-reducing tax liabilities substantially-but a much smaller effect on the MITC. The large reduction in tax lial)ilities is balanced off against the small loss in the tax credit until tax liabilities in fact disappear. At the same time the tax free return of municipal securities helps to raise after tax income. In the example shown in Table 4, based on 1973 data, savings and loan associations would be able to raise their after tax income and eliminate their tax liabilities by switching 22.7 billion dollars worth of mortgages into tax free municipals. This asset switch reduces their mortgage holdings from 85 to 77 percent of total assets, a ratio that still qualifies them for the maximum tax credit. The advantage of this particular asset swap depends on relative interest rates. Currently these sorts of asset swaps are especially attractive. Yield spreads may in the future move in a way that miti- gates the profitability of such swaps. However, ignoring servicing costs on both assets, municipals have had a higher after tax return than mortgages would have under a MITC plan for almost the past twenty years. Including servicing costs would surely work to make municipals even more attractive as their servicing costs are quite likely .-maller than those for mortgages. TABLE 4.-ILLUSTRATION OF POSSIBLE TAX AVOIDANCE BY SAVINGS AND LOAN ASSOCIATION [Assumptiors: New mortgage rate, net yield: 7.5 percent.* Tax free municipal rate, net yield: 7 percent] Reduce mortgage Simulated 1973 holdings by with MITC $22.7 bil 1 Total assets------------ -----------------------$264.4 (bil) 264.4 2 Mortgages_. ------------------------------------------ 225.7 1-22. 7 203 3 Ratio--------------......----.--- --------.--... --------------- ..... .... 85 .77 4 Taxable income -------------------------... ------------- 2. 655 [-.075(22.7)1 .953 5 Mortgage interest income. ------------------------------ 15.180 [-.09(22.7)1 13.137 6 Taxes based on taxable income. ---------------------------- 1.274 .457 7 MITC --------------------------------------------- .531 .460 8 Taxes owed... ----------------------------------------- .743 0 9 Tax free income -----------------------------------.. -- 0.0 [-+-(22.7X.07)] 1.59 10 After tax income------------ ------------------------- 1.912 2.543 gross mortgage yield, 9 percent, minus servicing costs, 1.5 percent. Simulated 1973 lines 1-5: Actual data, FHLBB; line 6: (.48)(line 4); line 7: (.035)(line 5); line 8: line 6-line 7; line 10: line 4-line 8 + line 9. Reduced mortgage holdings lines 2, 4, 5, 9 reflect arithmetic shown; lines 6, 7, 8, 10 as above. It is possible to reduce tax liabilities by switching municipals for *assets other than mortgages. The profitability of different potential switches would depend on the particular structure of all interest rates and the magnitude of holdings of assets other than mortgages. Mutual savings banks do hold substantial assets in forms other than mort- gages. Savings and loan associations, however, simply do not hold many other assets that they could switch for tax free securities. To summarize, the impact of MITC on thrift institutions' holdings of mortgages is ambiguous. The MITC raises the before and after tax return on mortgages, and for that reason may make mortgages more attractive to mutual savings banks. However the associated changes in taxation also make it possible for both mutual savings banks and savings and loan associations to raise their after tax income and reduce their tax liability by holding tax free municipal securities. 54 The exact magnitude of the asset switching effect, and in particular its impact on mortgage holdings, is difficult to predict, but it has the potential for reducing mortgage holdings by thrift institutions, es- pecially savings and loan associations.16 OTIIER INSTITUTIONS The MITC is apt to have only minimal impacts on life insurance companies and pension funds. These institutions pay little or no income taxes and thus the tax credit has little value to them. REDUCTION IN MORTGAGE RATES How much, if any, of the mortgage tax credit will get passed on to homeowners in the form of lower mortgage rates? This is a complicated question with several different aspects. While all qualifying mort- gage debt would be required to have residential property as collateral, not all this debt need be incurred in order to buy a home. To the extent that the tax credit makes mortgage loans more attractive to financial institutions there will be an incentive to change the form of other borrowing to that of qualifying mortgages. Thus. effects of the tax credit may diffuse as a subsidy to general lending. The precise magni- tude of this effect is impossible to know. Some abuses are sure to occur, their magnitude is, however, uncertain. The decline, if any, in mortgage rates following the enactment of the MITC would depend upon the slopes of the demand and supply curves for mortgages as well as the shift in the supply curve induced by the MITC. The exact nature of the shift in the supply curve is com- plicated by the existence of deposit ceilings, the differential impact of the MITC on different institutions due to differing portfolio percent- ages and the tax considerations discussed above. See Kane (1974) for a more extensive discussion of some of these points. Several of Kane's conclusions should be noted. In the absence of deposit rate ceilings, Kane concludes that ". . specialized mortgage lenders eligible for the minimum tax-credit percentage . would be able to drive insti- tutions eligible for lower tax credit percentages completely out of the market for residential mortgages." (p. 8) In this case "every dollar of tax revenue surrendered by the Treasury on new loans would be passed through to borrowers . However, competitive deposit and mortgage markets frustrate a second objective of the legislation by perversely reenforcing incentives for maintaining the existing pattern of institutional specialization in mortgage loans." (p. 10) In the case of noncompetitive markets, as for example with deposit rate ceilings, a different result emerges. The magnitude of the decline in the mortgage rate is strongly influenced by the size of the tax credit available to the marginal lenders, who are apt to be commercial banks. Further the differential between the low and high tax credit lenders would accrue to the lenders, not the borrowers. Thus Kane concludes, "The lower the tax-credit percentage enjoyed by the marginal lender, the higher would be the mortgage rate paid by the borrower and the 16The above analysis is clearly a partial analysis and Is only meant to be suggestlvP. The complete general equlllbrum responses are difficult to compute. In particular, If tlhee asset swops took place one would expect that mortgage rates would rise and the rate on munleipals fall. If these swaps Increased after tax profits and If deposit rates were not controlled, then there would be competitive pressures to raise deposit rates. 55 greater proportion of Treasury revenue losses on new loans that would flow as a windfall to higher tax credit lenders in the financial industry." Kane also argues that the tax loss to the Treasury is apt to be quite substantial, significantly exceeding figures prepared by the Treasury. Kane's figures do not include the possibility of avoiding a substantial part or all of any remaining tax liability by holding taxfree municipal securities. This latter possibility suggests that the tax loss could be even greater. In conclusion, the precise impact of the MITC on the mortgage rate is difficult to determine. There seems to be a presumption that the MITC will reduce the mortgage rate. It is not clear how large any reduction will be. It might be quite small. To the extent that the demand for mortgages by household remains strong and lenders with low tax cred- its are needed to provide the final dollars of mortgage credit, there will be a smaller reduction in the mortgage rate and a larger element of windfall gain to high-tax-credit thrift institutions. Finally the cost to the treasury in terms of lost revenue is apt to be quite large and in excess of earlier official projections. 3. CREDIT ALLOCATION Proposals for credit allocation are a recurrent theme. Most recently proponents of credit allocation have proposed schemes as a way of helping low and moderate income housing, state and local governments and small businesses. There is probably a general agreement among economists that a program of credit allocation could have the intended effects of increasing lending to the favored sectors and decreasing lend- ing to other sectors. However most academic economists probably show a strong dislike for credit allocation schemes, if not an open hostility.17 This generally negative reaction arises because of serious questions about the magnitude of the effects on lending, the associated costs of an effective program and thus the desirability of any program of credit allocation. Since money is to some extent fungible, to what extent would favor- able loans be used for unfavored purpose? Sectors of the economy that were denied credit would have an incentive to develop procedures that circumvented the credit allocation restrictions. The question is to what extent would these procedures be able to offset the original restrictions? .-Slightly ? Substantially ? Completely? If controls were imposed on only a subset of lenders, for example, commercial banks, the resulting mar- ket forces would provide strong incentive for other financial institu- tions to fill in the lending gap that would then exist and thus circum- vent the original controls. How strong would these forces be? Pro- ponents of credit controls tend to view the problems of possible circumvention as small and manageable. Opponents, on the other hand, tend to view these problems as substantial. All of these problems of circumvention could to some extent be limited, and perhaps eliminated, by more finely drawn regulation and more careful and complete reporting and administration. However all these attempts to limit the leakages would require a more cumbersome w The subsequent discussion Is strongly Influenced by a recent paper by Thomas Mayer and refers to a program of mandatory credit controls. 56 and costly bureaucratic structure of administration. Further they are apt to have unintended and unforeseeable side effects as they increase the regulation and limit the freedom of innumerable special financial arrangements that, particular borrowers and lenders have arranged. The question that, needs to be answered is whether the costs of admin- istration are worth the benefits that might flow from such a program. Unfortunately there is no precise way of determining exactly what these costs and benefits will be. Consequently proponents and oppo- -,ents are left to rely on their basic intuition and prejudices in estimat- ing what the costs and benefits are likely to be. Again proponents see .Jmall costs and large benefits while opponents see large costs and small benefits. A recent paper by Rao and Kaminow investigates the possible im- pacts of a system of asset reserve requirements. Asset reserve require- ments are only one form, although a popular one, that credit controls mi.rht take. Rao and Kaminow argue that their results are of broader significance and will be essentially unchanged for any credit alloca- tion policy that operates by affecting the portfolio preferences of fi- narIcinl institutions for different types of assets. After investigating their theoretical model where portfolio deci- sions by individuals and institutions are influenced by what happens to interest rates, Rao and Kaminow conclude that "selective credit controls will have the impact on interest rates that policymakers would generally anticipate." However they go on to note that the niagnitude of the effects depends upon a variety of factors and it is possible that the controls would not have the desired effects on real investment. In other words, it is possible that while controls would lower mortgage rates, and raisebusiness borrowing rates, actual home- building would decline. Rao and Kaminow talk of four conditions which make selective credit controls more effective. One condition is what they call "special- ization", or the sensitivity of demands for particular ty)es of assets to particular borrowing rates,. Selective credit controls are more effective if the demand for hos 0s do('es not respond to interests rates other than the minortgarge rate and if the demands for other assets are similarly not influenced by the mortgage rate. The second condition is called "dichotomy." Selective credit controls are more effective if the demand for houses is less responsive to the returns from holding other assets and if the demand for other assets is less responsive to the returns from holding houses. Economic theory suggests that individuals allocate their wealth among a variety of assets depending upon the relative rates of return on different assets. In particular the asset demand for houses would in theory depend not only upon the returns from holding houses, but also the returns from holding other assets. Rao and Kaminow find that the effectiveness of selective credit controls is largest if the demand for houses is not affected by other, competing rates of return. The third condition hlias to do with the breadth of coverage of con- t rols. Controls are more effective if they extend to all financial institu- tlons. Controls are less effective if they exclude some financial institutions. The fourth condition hlas to do with thlie financing of business invest-' men t by issuing securities directly to households. Most of the Rao- 57 Kaminow paper assumes that both mortgage lending and business lending is done by financial institutions. The possibility of bypassing financial intermediaries and borrowing directly from househllolds weakens the effect of selective credit controls on financial institutions. This situation also gives rise to the possibility of the perverse result where the controls would have their intended effect on interest rates but need not have the desired effects on actual investment. It is analysis such as that illustrated by the Rao-Kaminow paper that underlies a general feeling that selective credit, controls such as credit allocation schemes could have their intended effect. However most economists would point to the limited nature of this conclusion. First, the. Rao-Kaminow paper explicitly details the situations under which selective credit controls are apt to have a smaller impact-the possibility of direct financing by non-favored sectors by issuing securi- ties to households directly; the existence of financial institutions out- side the scope of the direct controls; the sensitivity of the demand for any one asset to rates of return on assets in general; and finally the sensitivity of the demand for any one asset to a variety of interest rates as they offer alternative ways of financing investments. Second, the Rao-Kaminow paper does not explicitly consider a num- ber of other objections to selective credit controls. In particular, there is no explicit recognition of the costs of administration. One element of this cost is the explicit costs of both private institutions reporting compliance and regulatory agencies monitoring compliance or the lack thereof. Another element of this cost is the implicit cost in terms of loss of freedom and the extension of government control. In addi- tion, the Rao-Kaminow paper does not have any formal treatment of how the existence of selective controls might alter the basic institu- tional environment. For example Rao and Kaminow do discuss how the impact of selective controls would be lessened if a portion of rele- vant financial institutions were excluded from the controls, but they do not discuss how controls on all current financial institutions might by themselves induce the creation of new institutions that would be outside the controls.18 There are a number of other objections to credit allocation schemes that should also be mentioned. It is difficult to define precise categories of loans to be either favored or disfavored. There are inevitably grey areas between categories of loans. Thus, specific regulations are apt to do two things. One, they may cause a real inconvenience to in- dividuals or institutions with legitimate credit needs who would pre- fer to finance activities in relatively unconventional ways. Second, they provide strong incentives for individuals and institutions with disfavored needs to change the form of their borrowings to forms that accommodate to regulation. The existence of grey areas may also have undesirable effects from the dynamics of the politics of establishing and maintaining a pro- gram of credit allocation. The definition of privileged sectors may need to be expanded to such an extent as to become meaningless in order to gather enough political support to initiate a program of credit rationing. Subsequently, to the extent that the program is in fact successful and reduces the availability of credit to some sectors 18 The development of money market mutual funds is an Illustration of precisely this point. 62-748--76--bk. I---5 58 there will be continual pressures on the Congress and/or the enforce- ment agency to again expand the privileged sectors. Drawing a lesson from the histories of a number of regulatory agencies, a large major- ity of economists would not be optimistic about the possibility of maintaining distinctions as between privileged and less privileged sectors. Another frequent objection to schemes of credit allocation is that they are apt to interfere with the efficiency of the economy overall and the financial sector in particular. How much weight individual economists put on this point depends for the most part on how much they believe that markets work like textbook competitive markets. With competitive markets funds go to borrowers who are willing to pay the highest price, borrowers who by definition can use the funds most productively. If financial markets are reasonably competitive and credit allocation schemes are effective, they must reallocate funds away from more productive users to less productive users and hence the efficiency of the economy as a whole suffers. Similarly, financial institutions develop expertise in the types of lending that they can do most efficiently. If credit allocation schemes are effective they will force some or all institutions to engage in types of lending they would not otherwise engage in, types of lending they are less efficient at. Obviously how much weight one places on these arguments depends on one s prior conception of how competitive and efficient existing markets are. I want to make two points concerning this question. One, economists probably believe that markets are more competitive and efficient than do non-economists. Two, financial markets are severely limited and constrained by government regulation, and thus may not closely approximate the textbook notion of competitive markets. Some forms of regulation and control exist to give the government control over the, money supply and to insure the stability of, and hence con- fidence in, the financial structure. However, in the view of runny economists other regulations have the effect of restricting competition and exacerbating the problems credit allocation are designed to help. If this view is correct, then it is not at all obvious that adding new controls-credit allocation-to undo the effects of old regulations is the preferred course for public policy. One could simply eliminate the original outdated controls. 4. VARIABLE RATE MORTGAGES A number of observers have suggested that variable rate mortgages (VITM's) should be considered as a possible solution to tlhe problems of thrift inistittitions.19 There are perhaps as many VRM schemes as there are proponents of the idea. To attempt a systematic (liscussioll of all the proposals is simply infeasible. The common underlying fea- tivre is that the interest rate paid by a borrower would not be constant IDVarlablo rnte mortgnges are only one of severalni possible variantions In trnditionnl iiiiimrtgiii. thUlit one miighit wn t to ronslder. In partliulnAr. theri, has been discussion of prive levpl adjusted mortgages and graduated pnyment mortgages. Time and cirenmstanc'e r,,strict the dlitinsim lihere to vnrlnable rate niortnogePq. For n more complete diseus'Ion of other nltrnnintlvM sapt, Modiglliit n (nd Lessard. N wu' Mortiyage Designa . .and Kenrl's ..1tud1y of IlOiisin. g lInd lun 'rt gtitg. llii t oiIl*1 . 59 over the life of the loan, rather it would vary in response to changes in some reference rate agreed to when the loan was originated.20 The basic idea, common to all the proposals, is to make the earnings from a mortgage portfolio more responsive to changes in short term interest rates. If these earnings were more responsive to movements in short term rates then thrift institutions could afford to pay deposit rates that were competitive with short term market rates. In such a. world it would be expected that institutions could do without deposit rate controls and that when short term rates rose they would not suffer massive deposit outflows. Thus mortgage lending would be stabilized over a cycle in interest rates. Several things should be pointed out. To the extent that long term rates, like mortgage rates, are correct predictors of the sequence of future short term rates, then VRM's tied to short rates would work only to change the time sequence of interest and principal payments. After a mortgage was paid back, the VRM or a traditional mortgage would, in retrospect, look the same to both the borrower and the lender. However, the V"RM does introduce strong elements of uncertainty. Viewed before the fact, one simply does not know whether the un- known sequence of rates on a VRM will in the end be equivalent to the fixed rate on a traditional mortgage. Further, it may be of small con- solation to some households that especially high mortgage payments will, sometime in the future, be offset by especially low payments. The VRM does make a real difference, beyond shifts in the payment stream, when the sequence of short rates does not, in fact, turn out to be equivalent to the initial long term rate. In these cases there is currently an obvious asymmetry depending on whether future short rates turn out to be lower or higher than implied in initial long term rates. If short term rates turn out to be lower than expected, then a VRMf borrower's payments will also be that much lower. With the current mortgage instrument one would expect that, when expecta- tions were adjusted to reflect the realizations of lower than initially expected short term rates, long term rates, including the mortgage rate, would decline. Assuming the decline to be of sufficient magni- tuide, one would expect mortgage borrowers to refinance. When the sequence of short rates turns out to be higher than initially expected, then VRM's make a real difference of substantial impact. It is at precisely these times that thrift institutions get into trouble and the VRM is designed to help them out. The VRM helps them out by requiring larger payments from borrowers. While these larger pay- ments from borrowers would help lenders, they obviously are not so good for borrowers and, not surprisingly, have been resisted for this reason. With the current mortgage instrument, a borrower's payments do not rise. To briefly summarize, when future short term rates are lower than originally expected, a V-RM mandates lower payments while market forces would be expected to lower payments with the current mortgage instrument. If future short term rates are higher 20 Proposals for VRM's differ in terms of the reference rate proposed, the adjustment of the payment stream when the reference rate changes-does the size of the payment changpp or the maturity of the loan or both ?-limitation on the cumulative magnitude of possible changes, the frequency of changes, and other safeguards and options that would be avail- able to consumers. It should be mentioned that the reference rate need not be a single interest rate but could be an average of several rates. 60 than originally expected, a VRM mandates higher payments while the current nmiortgage instrument leaves payments unchanged. Borrowers obviously lose under a VRM with unexpected increases in short termn rates as compared with the alternative of a traditional mortgage with a fixed interest rate and a fixed stream of payments. However, under some circumstances, borrowers with traditional mort- gages are big gainers. One could view VRM's as requiring borrowers to share some of their current big gains. Specifically, if short term interest rates rise umexpectedly because. of unexpected inflation, then borrowers would be expected to have capital gains on their property and higher normal incomes as a result of the inflation. With tradi- tional mortgages the capital gainl accrues entirely to the borrower. The VRMI would require the borrower to share part of the capital gain with the enderr. The sharing analogy can perhaps be carried too far. The VRM re- quires payment to the lender when interest rates rise, that is when thi- capital gain takes place. The borrower would probably not realize tlHit capital gain for some time. The borrower is thus forced to finance the early payment of part of the as yet uncertain capital gain to the lender. There may also be significant distribution effects. Interest rates respond to inflation in the economy as a whole, i.e., the average of price increases over all sorts of goods in all sorts of places. It is possible that houses in general, or particular houses in particular places, would not experience capital gains that matched economy wide measures of in flation. There are other circumstances where, when making higher payments under a VRM, borrowers would not simultaneously be receiving other benefits that might finance these payments. If the unexpected in- crease in short-term rates is in response to a change in real interest rates, not changes in the rate of inflation, then borrowers would not be expected to have capital gains with which to finance higher mortgage payments. What impacts might VRM's have on thrift institutions and housing? As with tlhe general question of the impact of financial reorganization, this (question can not be answered with certainty. The wide scale in- troduction of VRMNI's could change borrower and lender behavior in ways that would be exceedingly difficult to capture with existing simulation models. Further, the variety of VRM proposals means that even if we had the perfect simulation model, there might not be one an;\ver to the question; the answer could well differ from proposal to proposal. With these caveats in mind, mention might be made of somlie silinulation work done bv Professor James Kearl. Kearl simulates tlhe complete adoption of VRM's over the period 1962 through 1973 and finds that the introduction of VRM's, accompanied with the elimi- nation of deposit rate ceilings, does three things: (1) the housing stock is snialler, (2) profits of savings and loans, as measured by their re- serves, are larger, and (3) the size of savings and loans, as measured by their total deposits, is smaller.21 Kearl attributes these results to the implicit change in the role of savings and loan associations. With earnings tied to short term rates, 21 K ir's simnulations Involve the extreme assumption that all mortgages are converted to V\ 'HIi. In such situation there la a less pressing case for broader investment powers for thrift InKtitutions. If VRM's formed only a small part of the mortgage portfolio of thrift Institutions, there would still be a strong case for wider Investment powers. 61 savings and loan associations are no longer intermediating between long and short term interest rates and hence no longer earning the profits that come from taking that risk. These lower profits on average mean lower deposit rates on average, a smaller industry, less mortgage lending, a higher mortgage rate and hence a smaller housing stock. In particular most of these effects appear to come in the last part of Kearl's simulation. In particular, the variable rate on mortgages and, with a lag, the deposit rate paid by savings and loans drops from mid 1969 through 1972. This lower deposit rate means fewer deposits, less mortgage lending, etc. The role of reserves at savings and loan associations in the model used by Kearl is difficult to interpret. Kearl's particular results about the growth in reserves needs to be interpreted with care. Within the model transfers to reserves are, for the most part, measured as the difference between mortgage interest income and deposit interest ex- penses. There is no feedback from large reserve accumulations to higher deposit rates, a feedback one would expect in the real world. To the extent that savings and loan associations were able to use their higher reserves to increase deposit rates, one would not expect as large a reduction in either the size of savings and loan associations or the size of the housing stock as implied by Kearl's simulations. In spite of this limitation of the simulations, Kearl's results raise some funda- mental questions as to whether VRM's could be expected, by them- selves, to solve the problems of thrift institutions. One can have serious doubts that the conversion of all mortgages to VRM's would solve the problems of thrift institutions. One could also oppose the conversion of all mortgages to VRM's on other grounds. However, neither of these two positions need imply that one should also be opposed to allowing the introduction of and experimentation with VRM's. As implied in the discussion above, the VRM shifts the risks involved in interest rate changes as between borrowers and lend- ers. In a world where both types of loans existed, there could well be borrowers and lenders who, at times, would find VIRM's mutually beneficial. To prohibit the use of VRM's would, in these cases, relegate both borrower and lender to less preferred options. The basic principle here is that, with adequate safeguards and information, more choice is better than less choice. 5. TERM STRUCTURE INSURANCE Some observers have suggested that the federal government should offer interest rate insurance to mortgage lenders.22 Under such a pro- gram, the federal government would guarantee to lenders that if some reference interest rate, which might be a single interest rate or an average of several rates, rose above its value when the mortgage loan was made, then the federal government would pay to the lender the increment in the reference interest rate times the outst;,din,: principal of the mortgage. Thus if interest rates rose. lenders- with this rate insurance would see their income keep paco with the rise in interest rates instead of remaining unchanged. Note that mortgage payments by homeowners would remain unchanged. The purpose of this proposal is to solve the problem of the impacts of adverse move- 22 This proposal is discussed In more detail by James Pierce. . 62 mnients in the term structure of interest rates on thrift institutions. In this regard the term structure insurance is very similar to the VRM, however there is a big difference in who is paying. What benefits would one expect in this world where the earnings of mortgage lenders were protected against adverse movements in the term structure? With the simultaneous abolition of deposit rate ceilings, one would expect that the forces of competition would pass these higher earnings on to depositors in the form of higher deposit rates. These higher deposit rates would enable thrift institutions to remain competitive with direct market securities. To the extent that these higher deposit rates prevented massive disintermediation then cycles in homebuilding would be moderated. It should be noted that the proposal makes little sense without the abolition of deposit rate ceilings. What happens when interest rates, including mortgage rates, de- cline? Exactly what would happen would depend upon the form of term structure insurance. One version of this scheme would have mortgage lenders swap the income from their mortgages for a flow of income determined by the reference interest rate. Under this ver- sion income to mortgage lenders would decline when interest rates in general declined. Again homeowners payments would be unchanged at a level determined by the original lending rate. In such a situation one would expect that institutions would compete for making mort- gage loans by offering automatic rolling over of mortgage loans when interest, rates decline. That is the institutions would treat homeowners as if they had paid off their existing high rate mortgage and had taken cut a new mortgage that reflected current, lower interest rates. With this sort. of response the government would cease to get the original higher mortgage payments and would in essence be offering insurance only against increases in interest rates. An alternative ver- sion of the interest rate insurance proposal would recognize this onesidledncss and simply offer insurance against an increase in in- terest rates. This term structure insurance solves the fundamental problem of the impact of adverse shifts in the term structure of interest rates. One could imagine offering such insurance only to institutions that invested a substantial portion of their assets in mortgages. That is the insurance could be offered only to thrift institutions. In this case the proposal would achieve a change in substance without a change in form. There would be no need to allow thrift institutions broader asset or liability powers because the term structure insurance would achieve the same result. Alternatively one could imagine allow- ing broader powers to thrifts and offering the insurance to any and all mortgage lenders. . What would such a proposal do to mortgage rates and what would it cost the governmentV The impact on mortgage rates and the cost to government both appear to depend on how the term structure in- surance would be implemented. In particular, would the insurance be free? If not, how would a price be determined? If the insurance were offered for free, I would expect new mortgage rates to look very much like short-term interest rates. If institutions did not need to worry about the risk of interest rates rising and if they could attract large amounts of funds at rates that were competitive to other short 63 term rates, then lending these funds out as mortgages would be profit- able until the mortgage rate dropped to something just above their deposit rate plus an allowance for the costs of making and servicing the loan. Thus, with free insurance and assuming some fairly auto- matic rolling over of mortgages when interest rates declined, the in- terest rate insurance makes the mortgage a short term instrument as far as financial institutions are concerned while it still looks like a long term instrument for households. The costs to the government of this sort of scheme could be quite substantial. With the automatic rolling over, all mortgage rates would decline when rates in general declined, but when rates in general rose, mortgage rates for old borrowers would not rise. They would stay at their recent low point. New loans would be made at higher rates, but again whenever mortgage rates declined they would bring down with them all loans made at higher rates and carry them down as far as the reference rate dropped. Thus whenever interest rates in general, in- cluding the reference rate rose, the federal government would be liable for at least the differential between current rates and their recent low times the whole stock of outstanding mortgages2 3 While such an arrangement would solve the problem of financial instability it also represents a huge subsidy to anyone with a mortgage. It seems quite clear that this sort of subsidy is entirely unjustified. If the insurance were not free, but instead carried a price, what sort of price might one expect financial institutions to be willing to pay? What implications would that have for mortgage rates and for the cost to the federal government? The expectations theory of the term structure suggests that, in principle, the differential between long and short term interest rates would be a good measure of what institutions minoht pay for this interest rate insurance. If the expectations theory-that long rates are good predictors of future short rates-is correct, there is, in fact. less need for this sort of insurance. One does not need insurance against all future increases in short rates. In particular one does not need insurance against expected future increases. Term structure differentials could be expected to take care of these increases. However, to the extent that thrift institutions are risk adverse, interest rate insurance would be attractive to them even if long rates were good predictors of future short-term interest rates. There is a much stronger case for insurance against unexpected increases in short-term rates which, by definition, are not accounted for by regular term structure differentials. It was argued above that one might view much of the change since 1966 as having been unex- pected, primarily the result of government action and inaction. In this case, some form of interest rate insurance seems appropriate. The above discussion suggests that thrift institutions might pay something based on the term structure differential for interest rate in- surance. If these institutions are risk averse they might even be willing to pay something more. On the other hand, if these institutions felt that the federal government would still bail them out if they got into massive problems they might only be willing to pay something less. If the term structure is a good predictor of future interest, rates and if this differential does reflect what thrifts would pay for rate insur- 231 say at least because some mortgages might have even lower rates from a lower earlier trough. These mortgages would entail even larger payments. 64 dance, then, barring large. unexpected shifts in the level of interest rates, over the long run this insurance would involve only minimal outlays. There would be times when more is taken in than paid out and other times when the reverse occurred, but over the long run things would even out. A couple of other features should be noted. This insurance would presumably be offered on a voluntary basis to financial institu- tions. That is the government would stand ready to undertake such insurance when an individual institution wanted it and paid for it. If a particular institution held very strong views about future interest rates that were different from market evaluations as summarized in the term structure differential, then it need not buy insurance. In par- ticular if a particular institution felt rates would rise more sharply than implied by the market determined term structure, then the insur- ance would appear to be a good deal. If the institution felt rates would not rise as rapidly, the insurance would appear to be a bad deal, the premium would be too high, and it need not purchase it. As mentioned above there have been times, especially recently when the term struc- ture differential has been negative. On the expectations view, this nega- tive differential reflects expectations that short rates are temporarily high and will decline. In these cases one would expect that the demand for rate insurance would not be very strong. What implications does term structure insurance have for housing and mortgage markets? This is a difficult question to answer. The pro- posal has some similarities to variable rate mortgages and thus the results of the Kearl simulations may be applicable. Savings and loan associations give up their term structure intermediation, one might expect that they would have slightly lower returns on average, hence lower deposit rates, less deposits, less mortgage lending, higher mort- gage. rates and a slightly lower housing stock on average. However, tlhe insurance proposal is not exactly the same as a variable rate mortgage, in particular there are different impacts on borrowers and different impacts as between increases and decreases in interest rates. Thus the Kearl results may be only suggestive of some possible effects. Clearly the proposal needs further study and thought in order to sort out all its likely impacts. 6. EXPANDED OPERATIONS FOR FIILMC This final proposal is directed only at the problem of credit ration- ing. Many observers who have been concerned about the severity of recent declines in housing activity feel that the severity of the decline is due in some degree to credit rationing. When market interest rates rise, savings inflows decline, mortgage lending declines and mort- gage rates rise to ration some potential borrowers out of the market. Credit rationing suggests that additional borrowers are rationed out of mortgage market by other means. On this view the mortgage rate d(loes not rise fast enough to eq(iiate0 demand with a substantially re- duced supply. Some l)orrowers want mortgages and are willing to pay for them at existing mortgagee rates. The lenders simply do not have the finids anid either refuse to len<1 a'lnd/or i:mke other ternis so one(rois as to discourage these borrowers. This lack of lending in turn results in not only less residential construction but frustration as people may liave difficulty moving among existing units. .An expanded role for the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corpora- tion (FIILMC) could eliminate the problem of credit rationing l)y 65 assuring a supply of mortgage credit at appropriate interest rates. It should be noted carefully that nothing is guaranteed about the mort- gage rate. The only guarantee is that if someone were willing and able to pay the going mortgage rate he will be able to get a loan. Undoubtedly many people have proposed similar ideas in the past. I do not mean to slight anyone by omission. I associate the idea with a paper written by Warren Smith in 1970. Smith's proposal would have the FHLMC make a market in conventional mortgages by always being willing to lend mortgage money at a rate equal to its borrowing plis administration costs.24 In particular, if the demand for mortgages increases, FHLMC would be expected to raise more money in order to make loans. If raising this money raised their borrowing costs, then it should raise its mortgage rate. As Smith says, "Under such a system, potential mortgage borrowers should always be able to obtain accom- modation, provided they were willing to pay the prevailing interest rate." Note again that what is being assured is that mortgage money will be available, nothing is being guaranteed about the mortgage rate. How would FIHLMC buy mortgages? Smith suggests that FHLMC establish a schedule of prices that reflect its costs and then that FItLMC should be willing to buy all the mortgages offered to it at those prices.25 Mortgage lending institutions would always have the option of originating a mortgage loan that could be sold immediately to FHLMC, retaining appropriate origination and servicing fees. Thus an institution could make mortgage loans even if it did not have any funds of its own to lend out provided there were borrowers who were willing to pay the going mortgage rate. What implications does this proposal have for cycles in homebuild- ing? To the extent that there continue to be cycles in interest rates and to the extent that these cycles in interest rates result in movements along the demand curve for houses and mortgages, there will still be cycles in homebuilding, but under the Smith proposal these cycles would not be aggravated by credit rationing. Smith's proposal would presumably work very much like GNMA insured mortgage securities. That is FHLMC securities would essen- tially be a repackaging of the underlying mortgages. If this repack- aging makes mortgages more attractive to traditionally non-mortgage oriented lenders, it could provide a strong and continuous link be- tween mortgage markets and general capital markets, and essentially eliminate credit rationing as a factor in housing and mortgage markets. Credit rationing has effects that need not show up in cycles in homebuilding. People simply get angry and frustrated when they want something, are willing to pay the price and are simply denied access to it. Transfers in existing housing units can be delayed, often with frustration, significant non-pecuniary costs and sometimes with 24 The particular institution involved is not an essential feature of the proposal. Thp siuhb.piupnt discussion aoiunips use of the FHLMC primarily because Smith (lid. ThIerp is, one important as)ect in which the particular institution is important. Thli.s aspect nlso suggests why FNMA should not be expected to serve the same .function. Smith would have the FHLMC stand ready to buy as lone as the yields it could earn "bear a stable and cons ltent relationship to the current borrowing costs." (p. 97) FHLMC would thus work much the way an economist would expect a textbook competitive market to work. One should not expect FNMA to operate in a similar manner. While it is public sponsored, it has stockholders who are interested in maximizing profits, not in social improvements. 25 A schedule of prices would be necessary because mortgages differ by maturity, loan- to-value ratios, and original interest rate. 66 significant pecuniary costs. Smith's proposal, by eliminating credit rationing, would eliminate these costs and frustrations. What would it cost the government? If the FHLMC prices its pur- chases to reflect its real costs there should be no direct costs to the government. There could be an indirect cost of unknown magnitude if holders of FHLMC securities perceived these securities as essen- tially very close substitutes for government securities. In this case, more FHLMC securities would be equivalent to more government securities in general and would be expected to raise the rate on both types of securities. Symmetry would suggest that the FHLMC should be willing not only to buy mortgages at stated prices, but also to sell mortgages at tho'.e same prices. In terms of eliminating the problem of credit rat ioning, it is more important that the FHLMC buy in times of tight money. It is at lose times that most observers feel credit rationing is an important phenomena. When interest rates are declining, the mortgage market seems to work pretty well and the need for correc- tive action is substantially reduced. A BRIEF SUMMING UP Let me say a few words regarding my personal evaluation of these six proposals. I react negatively to the proposals for mandatory credit allocation and the mortgage income tax credit as presented in the Fi- nancial Institutions Act. With respect to the variable rate mortgage proposal, my understanding of the political realities of the situation says it is not a viable option. My understanding of the economics of the proposal says there is good reason to doubt if it could be the panacea for all the ills of housing and mortgage markets. However I would still argue that one need not be opposed to allowing the introduction of and experimentation with variable rate mortgages. There could well be borrowers and lenders who, at times, would find variable rate mort- ages mutually beneficial. To prohibit the use of these instruments would, in these cases. relegate both borrower and lender to less pre- ferred options. The basic principle is that, with adequate safeguards and information, more choice is better than less choice. There are some strands of the do nothing more proposal that are quite appealing to me as an economist. However implicit in the whole argument is a basic faith that minimizing government regulation and constrailits will enable the free play of market forces to allocate cred(lit to housing in the most socially desirable way. One may simply l)e skep- tical of that argument. Past problems with the mortgage market may lnot 1)c, entirely tl1 result of :voi'ltbible errors in government policy, but isteai Iall tlie problems of mort'gafre markets amild appropriatee govermueient po,! i(y factions may be need(led. 'i1ii leaves the l:st two proposals, insurance against interest rate ijncre:.('s and tle expan(led role for the FIILMC. I think that the in- surnnce proposal has some interesting aspects lbut I would like to hear mor0e discw-sion of tlie proposal l)efore committing myself. Currently I would stronjv support a carefully conceived program for expand- ing the role of tlhe FIILM[C. APPENDIX I SIMULIATIONS OF FINANCIAL REORGANIZATION The discussion below is a more detailed examination of papers by Ray Fair-Dwight Jaffee and Patrie Hendershott.1 Both of these papers attempt to evaluate the impact of financial reorganization by simulations of large econometric models. These models, estimated by sophisticated statistical techniques, are attempts to explain actual behavior. By hypothesizing how financial reorganization would change behavior, the authors make appropriate changes in their equations and resimulate their models. The comparison of the simulations with and without these changes is used as an indication of the impact of financial reorganization. Although the authors consider different sorts of changes and sim- ulate them in different ways, both papers come to similar conclusions: financial reorganization will have little if any adverse impact on housing and mortgage markets. In fact there are a number of simula- tions in both papers which show a substantial decline in the mortgage rate as a result of financial reorganization. If these conclusions could be accepted with a high degree of certainty, they would only strengthen what is already a strong case for financial reorganization. However, a detailed look at some of these simulations, along with the general sorts of considerations discussed in the basic paper, lead me to a more skeptical position. Because of the limitations of these pa r- ticular models and simulations, and most likely of any model and its simulations, I would reject the authors' conclusions as unproved and assert instead that we simply do not know what the impact of financial reorganization will be on housing and mortgage markets. The ap- propriate response in this case is not to oppose financial reorganization because we are not sure of its impacts on housing and noritgage markets, but rather it is to consider supplementary policies that would guard against any undesirable impacts. FAIR-JAFFEE Ray Fair and Dwight Jaffee have run simulations of financial reor- ganization with the Federal Reserve-MIT-Penn (FMP) econometric model.2 The FMP model is a very large econometric model with special attention given to the mortgage market. The Fair-Jaffee simulations are primarily concerned with impacts of financial reorganization on housing and mortgage markets. The Fair-Jaffee simulations are im- 'I am indebted to Ray Fair, Dwight Jaffee and Patric Hendershott for valuable com- ments on an earlier draft of my comments. 2 See Fair and Jaffee. "Ain Empirical Study of the Hunt Commission Report Proposals for the Mortgage and Housing Markets." in Policies for a More Comipetitire Financiail R .-fem. Boston Federal Reserve Bank Conference Series No. 8, 1972 and Jaffee, "The Extended Lending, Borrowing and Service Function Proposals of the Hunt Commisinm Rhport," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, November 1972, pp. 990-1000. (67) portant because they represent some of the first efforts to quantify the impacts of financial reorganization. Their work was published in 1972 and tries to evaluate the sorts of clainges proposed by the initial Hunt Commission Report. In partic- ular they simulated the FMP model, with and without changes, from 1960 to 1970. They then used the differences between simulations as a measure of what might have happened had the indicated changes been made in 1960. This attempt to replay the past under new rules is meant to be suggestive of the future impact of a changes in the rules. The major simulations they report attempt to measure the impacts of (1) removing regulation Q ceilings, (2) granting new service func- tion-checking accounts and consumer loans-to thrift institutions, and (3) granting wider investment powers to thrift institutions. The Fair-Jaffee results are partial simulations of the FMP model. The complete FMP model was not simulated. Three sectors, currency, labor and employment were held exogenous. Holding these three sec- tors exogenous would appear to preclude the possibility of any feed- back effects through changes in income as a result of any changes in residential construction. Holding employment and labor productivity ('constant would appear to hold real GNP constant. Thus, in thlie Fair- Jaffee simulations, any expansionary impacts on residential construc- tion could not have multiplier impacts on tlhe level of income. As a result any decline in interest rates is likely to be overstated as increases in in.olme would be expected to moderate any decline in interest rates. Fair-Jaffee are interested in what they call long run impacts. As a result they report simulation results at three separate points in time. 1 year, 5 years and 10 years after the indicated change. They do not report the time paths of relevant variables following the implementa- tion of financial reorganization. Thus one is not able to see what if any impact their simulated changes would have had on the cyclical response of housing and mortgage markets. At best the Fair-Jaffee simulations will show what would have happened to the stock of houses over a long period of time. The general conclusion reached by Fair-Jaffee is that the sorts of changes they consider would have little serious impacts on housing and mortgage imiarkets. After ten years their simulations show only slight differences between thle housing stocks with or without financial re- organization. I however, there are several questions about specific simu- latioiis and one important feature of the model that minliht lead one to be less sure that these changes would have only minor impacts. Fair-Jaffee simtilated expanded service functions by artificially add- ing to tlhe yield spread betwveenll deposit rates at thrift institutions and coiiimercial banks. In the FMP model inflows of funds to specific de- p)ository institutions depend in part on thle rates they pay on deposits vis-a-vis delposit rates at other institutions. Fair-Jaffee simply add so n.mynv ba-is points to that diffevrential in a way that favors thrift insti- illtiht s. lxpalindled service fiunctions-c-lecking accounts and consumer lendin iower-wouild allow thrifts to offer "one-stop"" banking. Fair- Ja ffte's simulations assume that tlhe advantages of "one-stop" banking cab lhe ejplated to ain interest rate d(lifferelitial. They silmunlate two such differentials, one of 25 basis points and anothler of 50 basis points. Both of these simulations have rather sub- staitial impacts on deposit flows. In tlhe case of the 25 basis point 69 simulations, deposits at thrift institutions rise by over 13 percent after ten years. The 50 basis point simulation shows an increase in deposits roughly twice as big. Since in the FMP model thrift institutions basically turn deposits into mortgages, the amount of mortgage lend- ing rises substantially and the mortgage rate falls.3 One may be skeptical of the magnitude of the deposit shift. The magnitude of the shift in funds simply seems too large. In the simulla- tions a substantial part of these funds come from commercial banks. One simply would not expect that commercial banks would allow a transfer of funds of this magnitude to occur without responding. One would expect them to compete for these deposits, either moire aggres- sively than before or in ways that the FMP model cannot adequately measure. Either response means that the Fair-Jaffee simulations over- state the magnitude of the deposit switches. Fair-Jaffee attempt to simulate the effects of wider portfolio powers by adjusting tlhe equations for mortgage acquisitions by mutual sav- ings banks and savings and loan associations. These adjustments are accomplished by reducing the value of all coefficients in the relevant equations by al)propriate amounts. 10 percent in one simulation and 30 percent in the other. This procedure has the effect of reducing average mortgage holdings by roughly the indicated percentages. But it also has the effect of making the portfolio allocation decision of both savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks less sensitive to changes in relative rates of return.4 In fact one might well expect that wider investment powers would make investment decision more, rather than less. sensitive to relative rates of return on alter- native assets. One would especially expect this sort of result for sav- ings and loan associations. This increased rate sensitivity could have important impacts on the magnitude of mortgage lending, especially during periods of high demands for credit when interest rate differ- entials have typically moved against mortgages. Neither the Fair- Jaffee simulations nor the presentation of their results enable one to reach a judgment on this question. Fair-Jaffee assume that wider investment powers will increase the earnings on thrift institutions and that these higher earnings will be passed on to savers in terms of higher deposit rates. Additional simu- lations are presented to suggest that these marginally higher deposit rates will give rise to substantially higher deposit inflows. (The mag- nitude of the responses is similar to the simulation results for ex- panded service functions.) Again one might simply be skeptical of the magnitude of the response. Beyond these specific questions, there is a basic feature of the FMP model that appears to be responsible for the general direction of the Fair-Jaffee results. This feature is the very high interest sensitivity of 3 Actually the increase in mortgages exceeds the increase in deposits. In both simulation-- mortgages increase by about $1.08 for every $1.00 increase in deposits. Siwulatiin. pre- sented in Jaffee (972a. p. 205) suggest that mutual saving-s banks will eventually in- crease their holdings of mortgages dollar for dollar with an increase in deposits. This result is most likely the result of experience in the late fifties and early sixtie- when thp increase in mortgage holdings divided by the increase in deposits at mutual savinz- banks waN greater than unity. This period is a substantial part of the estimation period for the FMP model. Behavior since 1965 has been quite different. Over the period 1O95-l1973 the increase in mortgage holdings was only 65 percent of the increase in deposits. 4 In particular the parti;il derivatives of asset demand functions with respect to a 4--liane in interest rates are reduced. As Dwight Jaffee has pointed out to me the .Iaticiripx are unchanged. However the argument developed hire -zingPsft. that for saviinz- and1 loan associations one might expect that wider inve-tmenr powers would inr:p!a-, not decrease, both the partial derivative and the elasticity. 70 the demand for mortgages. As reported in Jaffee (1972a) : "A 10-basis- point increase in the mortgage rate . causes the mortgage-demand- house ratio to decline by over 7 percent." (Page 164.) Fair-Jaffee report a housing stock of $564.3 billion at the beginning of 1965. A 10 basis point reduction in the mortgage rate then would have in- creased the demand for mortgages by over $40 billion. Expressed as an elasticity, these numbers imply that the elasticity of the demand for mortgages with respect to a change in the mortgage rate is 9.5. That is a 1 percent change in the mortgage rate results in a 9.5 percent change in the demand for mortgages. Conversely, with an unchanged housing stock, a 9.5 percent change in the stock of mortgages would be associated with only a 1 percent change in the mortgage rate, about 9 basis points at current rates. What all this means is that, in the Fair-Jaffee simulations, rather large changes in the quantity of mortgages will be associated with only very small changes in the mortgage rate. These small changes in the mortgage rate, in turn, imply only small changes in the equilibrium stock of houses. Thus in the FMP model the stock of houses is rela- tively insensitive to the sorts of changes simulated by Fair-Jaffee. This insensitivity is built into the model from the beginning through the high mortgage rate elasticity of the demand for mortgages. There are several reasons to be skeptical of the mortgage demand elasticity in the FMP model and hence some reason to be suspicious of their result of minimal impact on housing. In particular, there are some peculiar features in the estimated mortgage demand equation and the resulting estimate of the mortgage rate elasticity seems too high. The mortgage demand equation as estimated attempts to explain the demand for mortgage debt arising from both the existing stock of homes as well as the flow of new homes constructed. This concern with both elements of the demand for mortgages is a good thing but the particular implementation of this concern has some implausible re- sutilts. The equilibrium mortgage-debt/house ratio for existing homes is constrained to equal the mortgage-debt/house ratio for new con- struction. The latter ratio has been a bit above .7 for the last fifteen years. While we do not have directly data on the equilibrium mort- gage-debt/house ratio for existing homes, the actual ratio of the stock of inortrare debt to the stock of houses is simply nowhere near that ]high. Meltzer suggests a ratio of .375 for 1970, substantially below .7. 'The data Fair-Jaffee present in their table 1 suggests a rIatio of 44 percent, still substantially below .7. The mortgage demand equation in the FMP model has another re- lated peculiar result. As mentioned before the equation assumes that the equilibrium mortgage-debt/house ratio for the existing stock of liiumes is equal to the ratio for new construction. Further this ratio is estimated to depend on both the mortgage rate and the corporate bond rate. For the period 1966 through 1974 the implied mortgage-debt/ house ratio averages .85. It is over 1.0 for 8 quarters, a result that is not (1lly implausible, but also impossible if traditional collateral require- mients are to be met. In contrast, Federal Home Loan Bank Board data show that tlhe loan-to-value ratio for new homes with conventional mortgage financing averaged .74 over the same l)period. From a mortgage-debt/house rate of .85, 20 basis point reduction in the mortgage rate would be sufficient to send the implied ratio over 1.0. The simulations reported in Jaffee, 1972b, show a reduction in the inortgage rate of 39 to 47 basis points. In fact Jaffee himself warns "bnot to extrapolate the results of this equation to the range of interest rate spreads at which the collateral requirement, in the aggregate, be- comes binding on households." (Jaffee, 1972a, p. 164.) What all this is meant to suggest is that the mortgage demand equa- tion in the FMP model has several peculiar features: the equality of debt/equity ratios on new and existing homes, a very large mortgage rate elasticity, and implausible implications for much of the period since 1966 as well the period of simulated change. In light of these problems and in view of the crucial role of the equation in the simula- tions, one might well be skeptical of Fair-Jaffee's major conclusion of little or no adverse impact on housing and mortgage markets. LIENDERSHOTT Patric Hendershott, along with several collaborators, has developed a large econometric model of financial flows based on flows of funds data. Hendershott has simulated his model to represent the proposed VIA changes.5 Hendershott's simulations are only partial simulations not full simulations of his model. The simulations appear to include only the financial sector, flows of funds and interest rates. Levels of production and income are held constant. Even within the financial sector certain things, such as deposit rates, are also held constant.6 Hendershott's simulations suggest that there would be a substantial stimulative effect on residential construction. Such a development would be expected to have multiplier effects on income with associ- ated feedback effects on interest rates and financial flows that to some extent would undercut the original stimulate effects on residential con- struction. Hendershott's simulations do not have these multiplier and feedback effects and are thus not a complete evaluation of the FIA proposals. The simulations are incomplete in another important way. Some of HIendershott's simulations show substantial decline in the mortgage rate. One would usually expect that deposit rates at thrifts would also decline in the face of a large decline in the yield on mortgages. If deposit rates declined, then deposit inflows would also decline and the final decline in the mortgage rate would be smaller. Unfortunately Ilendershott's model does not allow for this effect as all deposit rates are exogenous. Feedbacks from the real sector and from endogenous deposit rates would moderate any decline in mortgage rates. It seems unlikely that 5 See P. Hendershott. "The Impact of the Financial Institutions Act of 1975," in Housing Goals and Mortgage Credit: 1975-80, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Housing and Urban Affairs of the Committee on Banking. Housing and Urban Affairs. United States Senate, 94th Congress, 1st session, September 22, 23 and 25, 1975. See also unpublished appendix. A revised version of this paper, with comments by Cassidy and Swan, is forthcoming in a volume from the Department of Housing and Urban Develop- sent. 6 The exact simulation model is never presented. There are references to versions of the molel in other papers but one is never sure exactly what equations are in or out of the simulations. A related point is that one does not know what the form of the simulation equations i-. This latter point turns out to have some relevance. See Cassidy's discussion of Hendershott's modification of the estimated equations. 72 they would, by themselves, result in an increase in mortgage rates. However, failure to account for these feedbacks means that the Hen- dershott simulations paint much too optimistic a picture. Hendershott's simulations are only partial simulations in another important respect. The model is simulated in flow terms only and ig- nores entirely the initial stock adjustments as institutions initially react to expanded powers under the proposed FIA changes. Hender- shott acknowledges that the initial stock adjustments will be much larger than the flow adjustment. However the impact of these initial stock adjustments is simply ignored. Hendershott's simulations give one no idea what sorts of impacts these initial adjustments might have.7 Simulation results in the papers are reported in a rather peculiar way. Instead of the time paths of responses, Hendershott reports a single number, the median response over the last two years of his five year simulation period. One simply has no idea what is happl)ening over time. Are the differences from the control simulation-and hence the impact of the FIA proposals-getting biroger over time? Smaller over time? Are they oscillating in some peculiar fashion? One simply does not know. Another limitation of the use of medians is that one has no idea of how the FIA proposals would affect the cyclical responses of house- holds and thrift institutions. Would they tend to aggravate or mod- erate cyclical tendencies? There appears to be an a priori presumption that the expanded asset and liability powers should moderate cyclical effect, but Hendershott presents no simulation results that bear on this question. Again one simply does not know. In the Hendershott model, portfolio allocation decisions by mutual savings banks appear to be substantially more sensitive to interest rate differentials than the decisions of savings and loan associations.8 Hel(lershott adjusts the interest., rate coefficients to reflect the impact of tihe mortgage investment tax credit. For both institutions tihe result, of the tax credit is to reduce the interest sensitivity of their portfolio decisions. However the more basic question is whether the FIA proposals, specifically the expanded investment powers, will maki, savings and loans more like mutual savings banks? In partiicular, will their portfolio allocation decisions now show inter- est rate sensitivity like that of mutual savings banks? If the answer to this question is yes, then there is much more uncertainty about the long run and cyclical impacts of new investment powers. The Hender- sllott siimulantions, like others, extrapolates old behavioral relation- slips whenll the, proposed changes may imply fundamentally different relat ionshlip)s. 7 iH iid, rI.Itrh it argii,- that t lie stock nd.iu tinents must evvi'nlt'illy have lin 111mpa11t of tli. samIO -Ilin at his flow imi,,.-ts. i-n, in thi rs e there Is still thle question of timlni,- whi1li IIenfd.fr.hott doe, not address. Further the relation between I[endershott's stock and flow vtiiifilori,. is unr1V:ir. On this point see Cassldy. T'lhere I. some cn'iifsision niiii t which Inrstitution Is minore rate senstive. Aecordlin Ino ed, 1iin te', pre.-ie'1l by liIndershott anrid Villani rate chining induces mutual .ivnlls hanks to reillat. i only the flow of new funds wihi savilnvs and lioan associations re'allcwat, n part of their ,toklhioli. ncs as well as the flow of new funds. This asymmetricnl treatmnnl ,41ri., ;i % it pectilnlar and is at variance with a large part of current work on Iportfolio thliery. I 'unoriif Il his- 1 i m,Yi ,i rie. l trentim-nt nid loedi ki n nly at the estimated rtwflidents fir iit restr i ntt. s-iisit1 11 ily shows thiit tho ipefl(liclpnt for mnUtiial savings banks is over 201) times s I lirge as th,. l (enffli. nit for snvlngs and loan :lss.(falatlni-. 73 SHendershott.'s basic methodology is to shift his estimated asset de- mand functions to reflect the impact of expanded investment powers and the changes in the determination of tax liabilities. These equation shifts also reflect expanded liability powers for thrift institutions. The precise nature of these shifts is to a large extent arbitrary and ad hoc. To what extent will savings and loan associations make use of ex- panded powers to hold consumer credit and corporate debt instrument? If they hold more of these new assets, what type of assets will be reduced? Mortgages? Government securities? We simply do not know the answers to these questions. It is to Hendershott's credit that he tries various assumptions, however one could still question some of Hendershott's alternatives and wonder whether his assumed shifts are not a bit too optimistic. There are two major areas where I have questions about the re- allocations Hendershott uses: One, the size of demand deposit shifts; and two, the use of new investment powers. Hendershott assumes that thrift institutions will end up holding 15 to 35 percent of household demand deposits. Using figures for the end of 1973 this would amount to 7.7 to 16.2 percent of total deposits of thrift institutions.9 Evidence from states where thrift institutions now have the power to issue demand deposits shows substantially smaller holdings of demand deposits. Anderson and Eisenmenger report data for mutual savings banks that can issue demand deposits in four states. In 1970, demand deposits as a percent of total deposits ranged from 1.5 to 6.4 percent. Additional evidence comes from the development of NOW accounts in Massachusetts and New Hampshire. At the end of 1973, 18 months after their introduction. NOW account deposits represented only 1 percent of deposits at mutual savings banks offering NOW accounts. "However, 55 percent. of these accounts were opened by transferring funds from another account which the de- positor held with the same institution. Thus, even the 1 percent figure overstates the gain in savings banks deposits created by NOW ac- counts." (K. Gibson, p. 22.) It is possible that expanding portfolio powers, in particular the ability to make consumer loans, might work in a way that makes de- mand deposits at thrift institutions more attractive then they are at the institutions surveyed above. While a possibility, the magnitude of this synergistic effect is difficult to measure. Even allowing for some such effect, the evidence surveyed above suggests that Hendershott's least favorable demand deposit, shift (15 percent) may well be too optimistic. There is the further question about how these new funds will be invested. Hendershott says that "the thrifts will [be expected to] invest the funds [demand deposits] in a manner more similar to com- mercial banks (70 percent in short term assets. 30 percent in longs and mortgages) than the normal pattern of thrifts (5 percent in shorts and 95 in longs and mortgages)." (Hendershott, 1975, p. 3:)0.) He then goes on to assume that only 10 to 30 percent of new cherkinog accounts will be invested in short term assets. 9 According to Federal Reserve flow of fund, dati. hon-zehr,ldq. personal trusts ndl nonprofit organizations held demand deposits and currency of $170.2 billion at tho 'n'1 nf 1973. Assume that $150 billion of that is demand deposits. (The resulting $20 billion in currency translates into $93 for every man. woman and child.) Total deposits at thr'ift institutions at the end of 1973 were $323.6 billion. 62-748-76-bk. I-- 6 74 What difference does it make to the simulation results whether thrift institutions capture a large or small fraction of household demand deposits and whether they invest a large or small fraction in short term assets? The precise answer to this question would require new simultations. However an approximate answer is suggested by the following. The difference in the mortgage rate between Hendershott's large demand deposit share simulation (35 percent of the market with 10 percent in shorts) and his small demand deposit share simulation (15 percent of the market with 30 percent in shorts) is 15 basis points. That is. the mortgage rate is 15 basis points higher in the simulation where thrifts capture the smaller fraction of household demand de- posits and invest less of those funds in mortgages. Hendershott claims that the 35 percent of market with 10 percent in shorts implies that 18 percent of present demand deposits would flow into home mort- gages. The 15 percent of market with 30 percent in shorts implies that ) percent of present demand deposits would flow into home mortgages. Thus every 1 percent of demand deposits into mortgages appears to lower the mortgage rate by 1.25 basis points. The evidence from mutual savings banks and Hendershott's own discussion suggest that his less favorable assumptions, 15 percent of market with 30 percent in shorts, may be too optimistic. One might assume instead that thrifts will capture only 10 percent of household demand deposits and will invest 70 percent of these funds in short term assetss. The 10 and 70 percent figures imply that only about 1.75 percent of existing demand deposits would flow into home mortgages. Using the interpolation developed above, the even smaller market share and larger holdings of shorts suggests that the mortgage rate would be about 5 basis points higher than in Hendershott's unfavorable simula- lation and 20 basis points higher than in Hendershott's favorable simulation. Trhe other major area of uncertainty has to do with the portfolio sliifts induced by the new investment powers proposed by the FIA. No one knows for sure to what extent these new powers will be used. Ilendershott presents two alternatives but again one might still won- der how sensitive the results are to alternative portfolio shifts. Some additional work that Hendershott performed for the Senate TBanking, Housing and Urban Affairs Committee suggests that the results are indeed quite sensitive to alternative assumptions about. port- folio slifts. The simulations for the committee have two major differ- cics. One, the committee has thrifts exploiting their new powers sli iht ly more, and two, in order to exploit these new lending powers, the committee has thrifts making a much more substantial shift away from mortgages. What happens to the mortgage rate under these two alternatives? ITendcrslhot.t's assumptions lead to a reduction in the mortgage rate of 5 basis points while the committees assumptions lead to an increase in the mortgage rate of 45 basis points. One does not have to choose between these two simulations. One just has to note that to rule out any possible increase in the mortgage rate one would have to argue Iliat. Hendershott's simulation is the worst possible case. However taking a weighted average of the two results suggests that there are a wide, range of plausible. outcomes-only slightly more pessimistic than Tlond(lerslott but considerably less pessimistic than the committee- tllIat woulId result in hlighler mortgage rates. 75 Further both of these simulations incorporate the 15 percent of household demand deposits with 30 percent in shorts assumption. One might instead assume that thrifts will capture only 10 percent of the market for household demand deposits and invest 70 percent of these funds in short term assets. The discussion above suggests that these alternatives would mean a mortgage rate that was another 5 basis points higher. . Our basic point is not that the mortgage rate will be 5 basis points higher or lower, but rather that there is a wide range of uncertainty. Further, the uncertainty is not how far the mortgage rate will fall, but rather whether it may not increase. APPENDIX II HOUSING PRICES AND INCOME Increases in housing prices have become of increasing concern. Public policy has been committed to seeing that all individuals be as- sured of a decent home and a suitable living environment. To further this goal a number of public policy measures have been designed to promote homeownership. There is a growing fear that increases in the price of housing may make these goals impossible to achieve. Before committing public policy and public resources it is important to look carefully at the relevant numbers. Tables 1 to 13 present data on income, general prices, housing prices and mortgage payments since 1960. It is important to look at data from a variety of sources because the way different series are constructed may make them more or less appropriate for particular uses. Series that appear to measure the same thing may show quite different results. Sometimes these differences can be understood by taking account of the conceptual differences in the series. INCOME All the series on income in Tables 1 and 2 show a continuing in- crease in income since 1960. The Census series on median family in- come and the GNP series on per capital disposable income tell roughly the same story over the period 1965-1970 although there are some differences in the two sub periods. Average per capital disposable in- come is the broadest measure of income and for many purposes is the most appropriate measure of income. It shows substantial increases in both nominal and real income (nominal income adjusted for the change in prices) over any broad period of time.1 Only in 1974 did real per capital disposable income fail to increase. Data on median family income shows a pattern similar to that of average per capital income, except that the increase in the nominal level of income fails to match the increase in prices in three years, 1970, 1971, and 1974. Data on average spendable earnings tells a substantially different story-little or no growth in real income over the whole period 1965 to 1974. As detailed below this series is subject to several serious shortcomings that limit its usefulness as a broad based measure of 'Percentage increases in real income are approximately the difference between the percentage increase in nominal income and the percentage increase in prices. 76 purchasing power. However tlhe figures do suggest that there may be a substantial group of people who have not shared in the increase in real income suggested by the figures on both disposable income and median family income. Census data on median family income is a measure of income before taxes. The other two series attempt to measure spending power after taxes. Figures on disposable income average all sources of income for all people and is thus the most appropriate, broad based measure of spending power. The series on spendable earnings attempts to measure wa-e and salary income of production and nonsupervisory workers on private, nonagricultuLiral payrolls. As a result it ignores certain iim- poritant sources of income. Further, the way in which the series is co st rueted introduces certain biases. The series is derived from payroll data and in essence averages the earnings of full and part time workers. The increasing proportion of part time workers in the basic data means that the series understates earnings for full time workers. Further, the series excludes three im- portant. categories of family income: fringe benefits, income earned by other family members and all other sources of income. To summarize, the data on median family income and average per capital income show substantial increases in both nominal and real income. However the series on spendable earnings suggests that there may b)e a group of people who have not shared to the same extent in the general increase in real income. HOUSE PRICES When looking at house prices one needs to carefully distinguish be- tween selling prices of houses and house price deflators. One also needs to distinguish between the housing units themselves and land. Indexes of house selling prices measure what is happening to selling prices of houises-structures and land-that are actually sold. As a result they capture not only any inflation in house prices but also any changes in the characteristics of houses sold such as a change in size or quality of the structure and/or the land. House price deflators on the other land attempt to measure only the, pure inflation by correcting for changes in the (quality of houses. There are separate deflators for struc- tures and land as well as ones that include both. Data on house prices and deflators are shown in Tables 5 to 8. HOI'SE PRICE DEFLATORS Tlie ('ensuis Bureau index attempts to measure the pure inflation in land and striuctire prices. It uses regression analysis to control for changes in tlhe characteristics of homes. However the index does not correct. for changes in lot size. Tie Censius Bureau index uses total paymitents for landl as a measure of thie inflation in land prices and thius uin(derstates tlhe increase in land prices as lot size lhas decreased. Tlie GNP residential construction deflator is based on the Census Bire.au index. 'lie residential construction deflator is a measure of iintlation in :t r4ucturie prices only. "'le residential construction deflator i-, oh btaitiled by adjust ing the Census Bureaui in(lex to exclude all etf'ects of land prices. As a rTesult it is a good measure of the inflation of con- strh ilion costs Nit a poorer measure of what is happening to house lpries beci-a -e houses are usually sold with land. 77 The Boeckh index is also a measure of inflation in construction costs. However there is a major shortcoming in the Boeckh index. As a result, the Boeckh index overstates the inflation in building costs and shows considerably more increase than the residential construction deflator. The Boeckh index is in essence an average of wages and the cost of materials. It makes no allowance for increases in labor productivity and/or material substitution. As a result the Boeckh index overstates the. inflation in housing costs by about 11/- percent per year over the period 1965-1974 and 1 percent over the period 1970-1974. FHA collects data on the price of land of FHA insured property. This data is subject to several weaknesses but strongly suggests that there have been substantial increases in land prices. VWhat do these different deflators show has happened to construction costs? The available deflators confirm that there has been a substantial increase in construction costs. Over the period 1965-1970 construction costs of structures as measured by the GNP residential construction de- flator rose in line with overall prices as measured by either the overall GNP deflator or the consumer price index. All of these indexes robe about 23 percent. The rise was substantially less than the increase in average per capital disposable income over the same period. Income was more than keeping pace with prices in general and construction costs in particular. The Census Bureau index, which includes land prices, shows a slightly larger increase over the same period. When one considers the limitations of the way the Census Bureau index treats land prices, there is a suggestion that the Census Bureau index might understate- the pure inflation in house prices including land. Since 1970, construction costs have risen substantially more than prices in general. A comparison of the residential construction de- flator with the overall GNP deflator and the CPI suggests that over the period 1970-74 construction costs rose by one third more than the average of other prices. Structures were becoming relatively more expensive. The Census Bureau index, which includes land prices, shows a slightly smaller increase over the period 1970-1974. This result seems especially surprising in view of the FHA data on land prices and is most likely the result of the way the Census Bureau index treats land. Allowing for an increase in land prices at even faster rates than struc- ture prices suggests that house prices including land showed a pure inflation substantially greater than prices on average. Not only was the inflation in houses prices faster than that of prices in general over the period 1970-1974, but it exceeded the increase in income. Over the period 1970-1974, construction costs, as measured by the residential construction deflator, rose by about as much as average per capital disposable income. The FHA data on land prices shows an even larger increase. Combining the data on construction costs and land prices suggests that the increase in house prices-structures and land-ex- ceeded the increase in income. HOUSE PRICES There are several series on sales prices of homes. They are shown in Tables 7 and 8. It should be remembered that these series on selling 78 prices measure not only any pure inflation but also include changes in the characteristics of units and/or lots. The Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB) and the Census collect information on the sales price of conventionally financed new single family homes. Both series tell a similar in terms of rates of increase although some details differ. (The levels of the two series differ for a technical reason: the Census figure is a median, the FHLBB series is a mean which is higher because of the inclusion of some very expensive homes.) The Census figure is probably the more appropriate figure to use as a measure of the cost of an average house. Being the median price means that one half of all houses sold had a sales price less than or equal to the median price while the other half had sales prices greater than or equal to it. Over the period 1965-1970, both series show an increase in the sales price of new homes in excess of the pure inflation as measured by the house price deflators, suggesting that people were buying bigger and/better houses. The period 1965-1970 was also a period of strong gains in real income and a period when the inflation in construction costs was similar to general inflation. Over the period 1970-1974 increases in sales prices of new homes did not match the increase in construction costs, suggesting that people were buying smaller homes and/or homes of reduced quality. In con- trast to the earlier period, 1970-1974 was a period of smaller gains in real income and a period when the inflation in construction costs sub- stantially exceeded the general rate of inflation. The Census Bureau also collects data on sales prices of new units with FHA and VA financing. These data show a slightly different picture. Over the whole period 1965-1974, both series show larger increases than for conventional financed homes. Further the pattern of increases in the two subperiods also differs from the pattern for conventional financed units. The figures for the separate period are more v'aried than those for conventionally financed houses and reflect among other things the impact of the 235 program as well as the timing of changes in FHA and VA regulations as to maximum house prices and interest rates. EXISTING HOUSES Both the FHLBB and the National Association of Real Estate Boards collect data on prices of existing homes. Tables 7 and 8 present the FHLBB data on sales prices of existing homes. Over the periods 1965-1970 and 1970-1974 the FHLBB data for existing homes shows virtually the same increases as the FHLBB data for new homes. The year to year movements differ but the longer period increases are quite similar. It should be noted that the data collected by the National Association of Real Estate Boards shows a slightly higher rate of increase. The similar response of prices of new and existing homes should not be too surprising. One would expect that when two goods are close substitutes their prices should show similar movements. If their relative prices move far from normal relations one type of housing represents an especially good buy when compared to the other. In such a situation an economist would expect that individuals would switch their buying plans and reestablish the traditional differentials. The increase in prices of existing houses points up another aspect of the recent inflation in house prices and that is the large capital gains that most current home owners have experienced. In addition most homeowners are highly levered with mortgage financing and have thus experienced substantial rates of return on the equity investment in their homes. MORTGAGE PAYMENTS Monthly mortgage payments are determined by the interaction of mortgage terms-interest rate, maturity, loan-to-value ratio- and house prices. If mortgage terms remained unchanged monthly mortgage payments would rise in step with house prices. Over the period 1965-1974 mortgage terms have not remained unchanged. Data from the FHLBB survey of conventional mortgage lending allows one to detail the change in mortgage terms. The average maturity of con- ventional mortgages for new homes has increased, which by itself would tend to reduce monthly mortgage payments. The average loan- to-value ratio has also increased which by itself would tend to increase monthly mortgage payments. However, dwarfing both these figures has been the increase in interest rates that has resulted in a substantial increase in monthly mortgage payments. The combination of the in- crease in house prices and the change in mortgage terms has resulted in an increase in mortgage payments of 105 to 120 percent from 1965 to 1975. Tables 9 to 11 detail these changes. Over the period 1965-1974 the increase in mortgage payments is substantially in excess of the increase in average incomes. Using Census data, the ratio of mortgage payments to income has risen over the period by almost 20 percent. But this ratio needs to be inter- preted with care. Imagine a family in 1965 with the median family income of $6,957 buying a median priced new home with conventional financing at a price of $22,700. This family would have mortgage payments in 1965 of $1,265 equal to 18.2 percent of its before tax income. Imagine another family in 1974 with the 1974 median family income of $10,836, buying a 1974 median price new home with conven- tional financing for $38,000. This family would have mortgage pay- ments in 1974 of $2,793, equal to 21.8 percent of its before tax income. The second family thus has initial mortgage payments that take up 3.6 percent more of its before tax income than was the case for the first family (3.6 is 20 percent of 18.2). However when one considers the case of the first family in 1974, nine years after it purchased its home. one gets a decidedly different picture. If the income of this family kept pace with median family income, the ratio of mortgage payments to before tax income would have dropped dramatically. In fact it would have dropped to 9.9 percent. This is because the traditional mortgage contract fixes pay- ments in nominal terms over the life of the mortgage. The yearly mortgage payments remain at $1,265. On the other hand the family's nominal income would be expected to grow, reflecting both inflation and trend increases in productivity. As a result the ratio of mortgage payments to income would fall. The family that bought a home in 1965 is now sing a smaller fraction of its income to meet mortrare pay- ments. Further, the family that bought a home in 1974 can expect a similar decline in the fraction of its income that must be used to meet mortgage payments. COST OF HOMNEOWNE-RSHIP Mortgage payments are an important cash outlay for homeowners but they are not a complete measure of the costs of homeowning. In 80 particular one would want to account for additional expenditures for property taxes, insurance, and maintenance and repair. Detailed (lata from the CPI series on the cost of hlomeownership show that these three categories of expenses have all increased less than average income. As seen in Tables 12 and 13, over the period 1965-1974 the in- flation in maintenance and repair expenditures was 88 percent, almost as much as the increase in average income, while taxes increased by 65 ) per1 1't and insurance premiums by 38 percent. An economist would want to make four further adjustments to arri\-e at what. he would call the cost of housing. In particular he v.-outild want to eliminate the principal portion of the mortgage pay- ment-that ic a form of saving. Secondly, he would want to allow for thle opportunity cost of the homeowner's equity. If a family rented, it would invest its current equity and earn a return on that money. Thirdly, he. would want to make some allowance for thlie capital gains on houses which works to reduce the cost of housingg. Fourthly, lihe would want to take account. of special income tax preferences for hliomeowners that also work to reduce the cost of housing. TABLE L.-SELECTED MEASURES OF INCOME, 1960-1974 Average Median Per capital Weekly Family Disposable Spendable Year Income Income Earnings 1960-----------------------------------------------....................................................... $5,620 $1,937 $72.96 1961------------------------------------------------....................................................... 5,737 1,984 74.48 1962 ...--------------------------------------------------.................................................... 5,956 2,065 76.9 9 1963.......----------------------------------------------- 6,249 2,138 /8. b6 1964.......................-----------------------------------------------.... 6,569 2,283 82.57 1965 -----------------------------------------------...................................................... 6,957 2,436 86.30 1966............................-----------------------------------------------............. 7,500 2,604 88.66 1967----------------------------------------------------....................................................... 7,933 2,749 90.86 1968 ....-.....................-...-....-....... --------.. 8,632 2,945 95.28 1969 .................----------------------------...--..... -- --------------- 9, 433 3,130 99.99 1970 .................................................-----------------------------------------------..... 9,867 3,376 104.61 1971 -----------------------------------------------..................................................... 10,285 3,605 112.21 1972........................................... .........-----------------------------------------------.. 11,116 3,843 120.79 1973 ....................................................---------------------------------------------- 12,051 4,296 127.41 1974-----------------------------------------------....................................................... 12,836 4,623 134.37 Source; col. 1: "Current Population Reports, Consumer Income," Series P-60, numbers 49, 93, 98. col. 2 "Economic Report of the President, 1975," table C-18. col. 3 "Business Statistics, 1973," p. 85; "Survey of Current Business," June 1975, p. S-16, TABLE 2.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF INCOME, 1960-1974 Average Median Per capital Weekly Family Disposable Spendable Year Income Income Earnings 1960................................................-..... 3.7 1.7 1.5 1961 .. .... ..---------------------------------........... ...- ----------2.1 2.4 2.1 1962 .......-----------------------------------------------.............................................. 3.8 4.1 3.4 1963 .. ...........................----------------------------..-------------------.. 4.9 3.5 2.0 1964.................................................... -------------------------------------5.1 6.8 5.1 1965 ........................-------------------------------------------------.............. 5.9 6.7 4.5 1966 ...............-------------------------................. 7.8 6.9 2.7 1967 .........-......... ........-----------------------.. 5.8 5.6 2.5 1968 ... -.....---. ............................... ---------- -----8.8 7.1 4.9 1969 ................................................... ------------------------9.3 6.3 4.9 1970 ...........------- ...................------------------------------------------.. ....... 4.6 7.9 4.6 1971.-----------------------------------.................................................... 4.2 6.8 7.3 1972 ...-.........------------... ------------........--------------............. ... 8.1 6.6 7.6 1973 ... ..... .------------- 8.4 11.8 5.5 1974 .- ... ----------...-----------------...... ...... -..-..... -... 6.5 7.7 5.5 1965 1970 ................................................ -----------------------41.8 38.6 21.2 1970 1974.................................................. -------------------------------------------30.1 36.9 28.4 1965 1974.................................................. -------------------------------------------84.5 89.8 55.7 Source: see Table 1 81 TABLE 3.-SELECTED MEASURES OF GENERAL PRICES, 1960-1974 GNP Implicit Consumer Price Deflator Price Index Year (1967=100) (1967=100> 1960....----------.. ---. -.. -......--------------------------------------------- 87.8 88.7 1961 .. .. ....... ...-- -.. ..-......--- ....--...... .... ...--- -- --- -- - 89.0 89.6 1962..........................----------------------------------------------................. -------------- 90.0 90. 6 1963--------------...................... .................-.-..--.---. -- - -- --- 91.1 91.7 1964 .....-------------------------------------------------------------- 92.6 92.9 1965.---...-------- ------------------------------------------------ 94.3 94.5 1966.... -.------------------------------------................ -------- ------------------ 96.9 97.2 1967..........----------------........----....------------------..--..----..--..---..--------- 100.0 100.0 1968.............---------------------------------................------.--..-------------------- 104.0 104.2 1969......................................-----------------------------------------------------------.- 109.0 109.8 1970...-.......----------------------------------------------.--------------- 115.0 116.3 1971...... ------------------------------------------------------------- 120.2 121.3 1972.............................................-------------------------------------------------.------------ 124.3 125.3 1973-----. -----.-...-..--. --------------------- ----------------------. 131.2 133.1 1974 .-------. -------------.------------------------ ------------ 144.7 147.7 Source: col 1: "Economic Report of the President," 1975, Table C-3 (converted to 1967 base). col 2: "Economic Report of the President," 1975, Table C-44. TABLE 4.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF GENERAL PRICES, 1969-1974 GNP Imolicit Consumer Year Price Deflator Price Index 1960-........------------------------------------------------------------ 1.6 1.6 1961 ----.--. ------- ------.....----------------..------...... ----------.......--- 1.3 1.0 1962 ........................... .... .. .. .. ... ....... .... .. ...... ... ....... .. 1. 1 1. 1 1963 --------- ------- --------------------------------------------------. 1.3 1.2 1964 ------------------------------------------------------------------- 1.6 1.3 1965 -.......---------.--..--- ------------------------------------------ 1.8 1.7 1966.-.---------- ----------------------------------------------------- -- 2.8 2.9 1967 --.--------------------- --------------------------------- 3.2 2.9 1968 ------------------------------------------------------------------- 4.0 4.2 1969 ------------------------------------------------------------------- 4.8 5.4 1970 ------------------------------------------------------------------- 5.5 5.9 1971- -----.-------- ---------------------------------------------------- 4.5 4.3 1972 -. ---------------------------------------.----- ------------------ 3.4 3.3 1973......---- ---------------------------------------- ------------------ 5.6 6.2 1974--------------------------------------------------------------- .......................................................................... 10.2 11.0 1957-1970-.. --------------------------------------------------------.. ...22.0 23.1 1970-1974 ..-- ------------------------------------------------------- --.. 25.8 27.0 1965-1974..------------ ------------------------------------------------- 53.4 56.3 Sources: see Table 3. TABLE 5.-SELECTED MEASURES OF HOUSE PRICE DEFLATORS, 1960-1974 Bureau of The GNP Census New Residential One Family Structures Houses Boeckh Index FHA Land Prices Deflator (Including Lot) ResiJe-.ces (./Aedjian price Year (1967=100) (1967=100) (1967=100) per square foot) 1960.------------------------------------ 84.9 na 81.8 na 1961-..----------------------------------- 85.3 na 82.0 na 1962---------- --------------------------86.7 na 83.4 na 1963---------------------- -- ------------ 88.5 90.2 85.2 na 1964 ....................................... 91.2 91.1 87.6 $.36 1965--.---------------------------------- 92.8 93.2 90.4 .36 1966-.....------------------------------------............. 95.4 96.6 94.3 .36 1967................................... ...-- 100.0 100.0 100.0 .38 1968 ------------------------------------ 105.4 105.1 102.3 .42 1969 ....................................... 111.9 113.6 116.2 .45 1970------------------------------------ 113.9 117.4 122.4 .57 1971 ------------------------------------ 119.7 123.2 132.8 .65 1972 ------------------------------------ 127.9 131.0 145.8 .75 1973.------------------------------------ 141.3 144.8 159.2 .85 1974-..---------------------------------- 155.6 158.1 172.0 .85 Source: col. 1: "Economic Report of the President," 1975, Table C-3. col. 2: "Construction Review," April 1975, Table E 4. col. 3: Business Statistics, 1973, p. 55; "Survey of Current Business," June 1974, p. S-10. col. 4: "HUD Yearbook," various years; FHA, data is for the first three quarters of each year. Na: not available. 82 TABLE 6.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF HOUSE PRICE DEFLATORS, 1960-1974 Bureau of The GNP Residential Census New One Structures Family Houses Boeckh Index FHA Land Year Deflator (Including Lot) Residences Prices 1960....................................... ------------------------------------- 1.4 na 1.6 na 1961 --------------------------------------...................................... 5 na .2 na 1962-..-------------------- ---------------- 1.6 na 1.7 na 1963.---------..........----. ---...-.-..---------.....- 2.1 na 2.2 na 1964....................................... ------------------------------------- 3.1 1.0 2.8 na 1965-----------.. -----....... --......-------------------........ 1.7 2.3 3.2 na 1966....................................... ------------------------------------- 2.8 3.6 4.3 0 1967.--------------------............- ---------------- 4.9 3.5 6.0 5.5 1968--------------------------------- 5.4 5.1 7.3 10.5 1969.... ------------------------------------- 6.2 8.1 8.8 7.1 1970....................................... ------------------------------------- 1.8 3.3 5.3 26.7 1971....................................... ------------------------------------- 5.1 4.9 8.5 14.0 1972 -------------------------------------............................... 6.8 6.3 9.8 15.4 1973....................................... ------------------------------------ 11.1 10.5 9.2 13.3 1974....................................... ------------------------------------- 10.1 9.2 8.0 0 1965-1970-..........-----------------......--.....-------------- 22.8 26.0 35.4 58.3 1970-1974.................................. --------------------------------- 36.6 34.7 40.5 49.1 1960-1974.................................. --------------------------------- 67.7 69.6 90.2 136.1 Source: see Table 5. Na: not available. TABLE 7.-SELECTED MEASURES OF HOUSE PRICES, 1963-1974 FHLBB Survey Average Price Bureau of the Census Median Price of New of Home with Conventional One Family Homes Sold Financing Conventional FHA VA Year New Existing financing financing financing 1963...----------------------------..... $22,500 $17,800 $20,400 $15,500 $15,700 1964--------------.....................--------------- 23,700 18,900 21,300 15,600 16,200 1965-----------------------------................................. 25,100 21,600 22,700 16,500 17,900 1966 ---------------..............-.---.---------- 26,600 22,200 24,400 17,500 18,000 1967............. ..------- -- 28,000 24,100 26,600 17,800 18,700 1968-....---------------------------- 30,700 25,600 28,500 19, 200 19,800 1969 ----...---.--................-------------------- 34,100 28,300 30,400 19,300 21,800 1970......................-----------------------------........ 35,500 30,000 30,800 19,200 23,700 1971---------------................---..----------- 36,300 31,700 31,900 19,800 25,300 1972-----------------------------................................. 37,300 33,400 31,600 20,500 25,100 1973 -----------------------................................. 37,100 31,200 35,100 22,100 27,200 1974...............-----------------------------............... 40,100 34,700 38,000 29,800 31,300 Source: cols 1 and 2: "Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal," various issues; Federal Reserve Bulletin, February 1969. cols 3, 4, and 5: "Construction Reports, New One-Family Homes Sold and For Sale," Series C25, various issues. TABLE 8.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF HOUSE PRICES, 1964-1974 FHLBB Survey Average Price Bureau of the Census Median Price of New of Home with Conventional One-Family Homes Sold Financing Conventional FHA VA Year New Existing financing financing financing 1964.................... ........... 5.3 6.2 4.4 0.6 3.2 1965 .... ............... ...-...... 5.1 14.3 6.6 5.8 10.5 1966 ................................. 6.0 2.8 7.5 6.1 0.6 1967 ................................. 5.3 8.6 9.0 1.7 3.9 1968 .................. ....-....... 9.6 6.2 7.1 7.9 5.9 1969 ................................. 11.1 10.5 6.7 0.5 10.1 1970 ...............................- 4.1 6.0 1.3 -0.5 8.7 1971 ................................. 2.3 5.7 3.6 3.1 6.8 1972 ................................. 2.8 5.4 .9 3.5 0.8 1973 ................................. .5 6.6 11. 1 7.8 8.4 1974............................. -------------------------------.. 8.1 11.2 8.3 34.8 15.1 1965-1970............... ............---- 41.4 38.9 35.7 16.3 32.4 1970-1974 ........................... 13.0 15.7 23.0 55.2 32.1 1965-1974........................... 59.8 60.6 67.4 80.6 74.9 Source. see Table 7. 83 TABLE 9.-SELECTED MEASURES OF MONTHLY MORTGAGE PAYMENTS FOR NEW HOMES, 1963-1974 Conventional Financing Based on Based on FHA Financing Year FHLBB data Census data (Section 203) 1963 ..------------------------------------------------ $106.59 $96.64 $92.45 1964 -------- ------------------------------------------ 111.13 99.87 94.19 1965 -------------------------------------------------- 116.58 105.43 97.46 1966 -- --------------------------------------------------- 127.51 116.96 105.16 1967 -------------------------------------------------- 136.59 129.77 117.14 1968 .....--------------------------------------.....--...---------- 156.74 145.51 124.85 1969 ... ------------------------------------------------- 184.84 164.79 144.57 1970 ......-----------------------------......--------------------- 200.83 174.24 174.41 1971 ......-----------------------------------..... --------------- 198.10 174.08 174.40 1972 ----------------------..... ..... ------.....--..-------------------- 205.12 173.77 169.96 1973. --- --------------------------------------------------- 213.65 202.13 169.40 1974...-----------------------------......................................---..-----..--..----------- 245.61 232.74 200.26 Note: cot 1 & col 2: Principal and interest payments calculated from FHLBB survey data on characteristics of conven- tional mortgage loans. Column 1 uses FHLBB data on average price of new homes. Column 2 uses Census data on median price. Col 3: FHA data, based on average price. Source: col 1: "Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal", various issues col 2: "Construction Reports, New One-Family Homes Sold and For Sale," series C25, various issues col 3: "HUD Yearbook," various issues TABLE 10.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF MONTHLY MORTGAGE PAYMENTS FOR NEW HOMES, 1964-1974 Conventional Financing Based on Based on FHA Financing Year FHLBB data Census data (Section 203) 1964....... ---------------------------------------------------- 4.3 3.3 1.9 1965 -------------------------------------------------------- 4.9 5.6 3.5 1966 ........................................ ....---------------------------------------------------- 9.4 10.9 7.9 1967..----------------------.------------------------------ 7.1 10.9 11.4 1968 ----------------.- ---------------------------------- 14.8 12.1 6.6 1969-..-------------------------..--.. ......-------------... -----------..... 17.9 13.2 15.8 1970............................................................. 8.6 5.7 20.6 1971 --------------------.--.......... --------------------------... -- -1.1 -.1 -0.0 1972..--------------------------........--------------------------...... 3.5 -.2 -2.5 1973-...- ---------------------------------------------------...... 4.2 16.3 -0.3 1974 ............................................................. 15.0 15.1 18.2 1965-1970...................................................... -----------------------------------------------72.3 65.3 79.0 1970-1974-------------------------------------------...................................................... ---27.3 33.6 14.8 1965-1974........................................................ -----------------------------------------------110.7 120.8 105.5 Source: See Table 9. TABLE 11.-MONTHLY MORTGAGE PAYMENTS 1965 1974 Purchase Price-- ---.---------------....---------------------------....................... $25,100 $40,100 Loan to value ratio ---------------------------------------------------------- 739 .753 Maturity (years) .-------------------------------------------------------......................... 25 26.8 Interest rate (percent)........................................................... --------------------------------------------------5.74 8.71 Monthly mortgage payment ------------------ ---.------.----------------... $116.58 $245.61 Percentage change from Payment 1965 Monthly mortgage payment if: 1965 mortgage terms, 1974 purchase price-...............-------------------------------- $186.25 59.8 1965 purchase price, 1974 mortgage terms---------.............. ------------------------ 153.74 31.9 1965 purchase price, L/V, interest rate, 1974 maturity-..--------------.. --------- 113.95 -2.3 1965 purchase price, maturity, interest rate, 1974 L/V............................ -------------------------119.58 2.5 1965 purchase price, maturity, L/V, 1974 interest rate---------.---------------- 151.99 30.4 1974 purchase price and mortgage terms.. --------------------------------- 245.61 110.7 Note: calculated from data from FHLBB survey of conventional mortgage lending. 84 TABLE 12.--SELECTED MEASURES OF THE COST OF HOMEOWNERSHIP FROM THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX 1960-1974 Overall Index of Cost of Mortgage Home- Rate Property Maintenance Year ownership (1967-100) Taxes Insurance and Repair 1960 - 1961 ...-..--- ......----------. 1964................................. 1965- --- ------- ----- 1966 ................................. 19667...........--................. 1968 --------------.-...... -..... 1969 ---.........--- .....---..-..... 19690.... .. ...... ............ ... ...... 19 70 -- - -- - - - - - - - - - - - - - 1971 -...0.......................... 1972........ ---......-............ 1973.....----....-................ 1974 .................--- --- .--- 86.3 86.9 87.9 89.0 90 .8 92.7 96.3 100.0 105.7 116.0 128.5 133.7 140.1 14F. 7 163.2 95.3 92.8 91.1 90.0 89.4 89.7 95.3 100.0 106.7 120.0 132.1 120.4 117.5 123.2 140.2 na na na na 87.9 91.5 94.4 100.0 1C5.6 111.9 121.0 131.1 145.7 152.3 151.2 76.9 77.2 77.7 80.0 84.1 89.8 94.6 100.0 104.7 109.3 113.4 119.9 123.2 124.4 124.7 84.6 85.9 86.5 87.7 89.5 91.3 95.z 100.0 106.1 115.0 124.0 133.7 140 7 151.0' 171.6 Source: all cols.: "BLS Handbook of Labor Statistics, 1973, Monthly Labor Review," January and March 1975. Na: not ava able. TABLE 13.-PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN SELECTED MEASURES OF THE COST OF HOMEOWNERSHIP FROM THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX, 1960-1974 Overall Index of Cost of Home- Mortgage Property Maintenance Year ownership Rate Taxes Insurance and Repair 1960.................................------------------------------- 2.3 4.6 na -0.3 1.7 1961................................. ------------------------------- 0.7 -2.6 na 0.4 1.5 1962..... ------------------------------- 1.1 -1.8 na 0.6 0.7 1963 .... ---------------......................... 1.3 -0.2 na 3.0 1.4 1964 ................................. 2.0 -0.7 na 5.1 2.1 1965.............................------------------------------- 2.1 0.3 4.1 6.8 2.0 196) ............................... 3.9 6.2 3.2 5.3 4.3 1967................ .........------------------------------- 3.8 4.9 5.9 5.7 5.0 196F .... ...........------------------------------- 5.7 6.7 5.6 4.7 6.1 1969............. -------------------------------... ...... 9.7 12.5 6.0 4.4 8.4 1970 .............------------------------------- 10.8 10.1 8.1 3.8 7.8 1971-------------------------------................................. 4.0 -8.9 8.3 5.7 7.8 1972 ...................... ........ 4.8 -2.4 11.1 2.8 5.2 1973 ... .... ... ----------------------------- 4.7 4.9 4.5 1.0 7.3 1974 .......... ...------------------------------- 11.2 13.8 -0.7 -0.2 13.6 1965 1970 -...... .....---------- 38.6 47.3 32.2 26.3 35.8 1970 1974 .......................... 27.0 6.1 25.0 9.5 38.4 1965-1974............................ --------------------------- 76.1 56.3 65.2 38.3 88.0 Source See Table 11. Na: not available. APPENDIX III WViio CA.N AFI'FOIf) A iN]W IlOL-SI" "Who can afford a new house?" h as become a popular question in 1975. (Caria Hills, Secretary of I 1' ), \;s rel)ported by the Associalted Pres as ;isay ilig tlIat iI 1975 only 31 percent. of Americans could afford at new m(ed(ian priced holile. A st idy for Thie (Joint Ecoim ic ('oinmit- i'ee (JEC) reports tliat it 'required an annual illcollie of at least S,.,.,30 to afford -a le(,w iled(ian priced liiome, in 1974, as contrasted with ;L IIediian family i ol('()iue of $12,40.1 Thlese sets of figurlles have led some ol serves to b ( quite pessimiist.ic about tlhe future o)f homeownersship. I .A i tllu i d cil i rlliIiif of tils s.ntimIy is attach(h d. 85 I want to stress two major points. One, the question "who can afford a new house '", is incapable of being answered in any meaning- ful sense, and, two, the answers that have been offered present a false and extremely misleading impression of precision. These points are important because of the possibility that the answers that have been offered could lead to one of two unfortunate responses, either the enactment of hasty and ill conceived policies to meet what is perceived as a national disaster or, perhaps worse, a sense of impo- tence and Tesignation in the face of such a large problem with a consequent failure to attempt to solve any part of the problem. A lot of studies, including the JEC study, take data on average or median home prices, interest rates, etc., and, using rules-of-thumb, derive how much income is necessary to be able to afford this house. This median or average house and the associated income then become implicit standards for public policy. The use of the median priced home as a standard neglects the fact that half of new homes sold had even lower sales prices. The use of the average price means even more homes had a lower price. For example, in 1973, the Census Bureau reported that the median sales price of new one family homes sold was $32,500. For the same year the Federal Home Loan Bank Board reported an average sales price for new homes of $37,100. A linear interpolation of the census figures suggests that over 64 percent of new homes sold had sales prices of less than $37,100. I do not mean to imply that all new homes, regardless of sales prices, provide decent housing. Undoubtedly some, especially at very low prices, do not. All I mean to suggest is that it is not at all clear that a concern for providing decent housing for all families means that each family should be entitled to the average or median of all new construction. This question about what provides decent housing is at the heart of why it is so difficult to answer the question "Who can afford to buy a new house?" Every time anyone tries to answer this question their use of a particular house price implicitly introduces their own value judgment as to what is a reasonable and proper house. I do not know how one can avoid this problem. I would suggest that this problem should be faced openly and the inherent ambiguity acknowl- edged from the beginning. I would also suggest that most reasonable people, if asked to decide what provides decent housing, would decide on a house that is significantly less expensive than the average or median of all new constructions. It is perhaps instructive to redo some of the mechanical computa- tions of earlier studies using data for houses sold with FHA insurance under Section 203. This exercise is not offered in defense of the average of FHA construction as the right and proper standard for decent housing, but rather to demonstrate the variation in answers from adopting different standards and a personal belief that an explicit public policy commitment to decent homes for everyone would prob- ably end up closer to the average of FHA-insured homes than all new construction. The results of this exercise are shown in Table 1. The basic data comes from FHA figures on average total monthly housing expenses which includes mortgage payments, taxes, insurance, utilities, and maintenance and repair. In line with earlier studies these monthly 86 figures are then multiplied by 48 to determine "required income." This procedure is thus consistent with the rule of thumb of 25 percent of income for housing. Finally these figures are compared to measures of income distribution. Let me offer an interpretation of these numbers realizing that the same numbers can mean different things to different people. One. thing that impresses me is that stability of these numbers. Over the entire period since 1950 roughly 40 to 50 percent of families could have "afforded" an average new FHA house. Further there is no conclusive indication that the situation is getting substantially worse. The drop in 1974 in the percent of families with incomes above the 25 percent standard is nothing to cheer about. But at the present time, it is diffi- cult to determine whether this represents the start of a new trend or is the result of the increase in unemployment during 1974. Earlier years of recession have shown similarly low percentages. These figures do not mean that 50 to 60 percent of families are un- able to buy decent homes. For one thing many existing homes, offering decent housing, sell for less than the median price of a new FHA house. In recent, years prospective housing expenses for existing houses with FHA insurance have averaged 90 percent of expenses for new homes. Further, the use of income figures for all families is likely to be misleading. Both family income and family housing needs show definite lifecycle patterns. Median family income rises with the age of the head of household to about age 55 and then declines slightly. Many young and old families, before and after years of child raising, choose not to own their own home but prefer to rent. The effect of differing housing needs and rising incomes can be illustrated using data from 1973 and 1974. If one looks only at families headed by an individual aged 35 to 55, the percentage of families which could afford an aver- age new FHA house in 19t3 rises from 49.7 percent to 62.7 percent. For 1974 the proportion rises from 43.7 to 57.2 percent. These figures are not meant to understate the problem many families have in affording decent housing. They are meant to illustrate some of the problems and pitfalls associated with trying to measure who can afford a new house. Because of the ambiguity surrounding any social standard of what provides decent, housing, there is a natural ambiguity surrounding any related income figures. Further, using in- come data for all families results in an implied group that cannot afford decent housing which includes many families who do not want to own a house-very young and very old families. The use of a new house as the implied standard for public policy ignores the whole stock of existing homes that provides housing for most of the population. The maintenance and upgrading of the existing stock is a viable option and should be part of any national housing program. There is the danger that this option could be ignored with the continual emphasis on new housing. 87 TABLE l.-THE COST OF BUYING AN AVERAGE NEW FHA-INSURED SINGLE FAMILY HOME Average Percent of Monthly families with Prospective Median income greater Average Housing Required Family than required Year Sales Prices Expense Income* Income income 1950....----------------------------- na $75.86 $3,641 $3,319 40.9 1955 ..---------..--------.----------- $12,113 98.02 4,705 4,421 44.8 1960 -..----------..------.------------ 14,662 130.82 6,253 5,620 42.4 1961 ..----------------------------- 14,894 134.12 6,438 5,737 42.4 1962 ----------------------------- 15,169 133.48 6,407 5,956 45.1 1963 ..--------..--------------------- 15,878 138.31 6,639 6,249 46.1 1964 ----------------.------------- 16,216 142.13 6,822 6,569 47.5 1965.---.....------------..-------------- 16,815 147.54 7,082 6,957 48.7 1966 ----------------------------- 17,605 159.74 7,668 7,5CO 48.5 1967..--------...........------...---------------.. 18,611 174.80 8, 390 7,933 46.3 1968. ----------------------------- 19,568 185.93 8,927 8,632 47.8 1969---------------------------- 20,563 208.87 10,026 9,433 45.8 1970.-.---------------------------- 23,056 245.92 11,804 9,867 39.4 1971 ----------------------------- 23,835 249.28 11,965 10,285 41.0 1972..-----------.------------------ 24,788 256.30 12,302 11,116 44.0 1973...----------. ------------------ 24,672 254.45 12,214 12,051 49.7 1974..----------------------------- 26,864 295.06 14,163 12,836 43.7 Sources: col. I, 2: "HUD Statistical Yearbook," various years; FHA. col. 3: col. 2 X 48. col. 4: "Current Population Reports, Consumer Income", Series P-60, numbers 49, 93, 98. col. 5: Linear interpolation of distributions in the col. 4 sources. Na: not available. TECHNICAL NOTES ON "AVAILABILITY OF HOMES FOR ]MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES." 2 This paper by The Congressional Research Service (CRS) presents two sorts of estimates: (1) The number of new homes available for middle income families and (2) The cost of owning a new home. There are serious shortcomings in both these estimates which will be dis- cussed separately. THIE NUMBER OF NEW HOMES AVAILABLE FOR MIDDLE INCOME FAMILIES This part of the study attempts to estimate the number of homes available for middle income families. It should be made clear from the beginning that the CRS study fails to achieve this objective. A major source of data used in the CRS study is from the sales of new and existing housing units. Thus this part of the study is really a measure of sales by purchase price not availability. Once it is collected, the data on sales is contrasted to the stock of families. The result is a very low fraction. It can only measure the fraction of middle income fami- lies that bought a house. As a measure of availability it can only be called spurious and misleading. All families have some type of hous- ing. In this sense the ratio of available housing to families is 1.0, by definition. To repeat, the ratios on page CRS-17 are only estimates 2 "Availability of Homes for Middle Income Families," Prepared by The Congressional Research Service for The Joint Economic Committee, April 28, 1975. 88 of sales by sales price as a proportion of all families, they are not esti- mates of a(i calblibty. Even as an estimate of sales by sales price, the study suffers from a number of shortcomings. The number of subsidized starts is elimi- nated frum the number of new homes sold. Why these units are sub- tracted is not clear. They do provide housing for the subsidized families. Further, it appears that the number of subsidized families is not subsequently subtracted from the number of families needing 1lousing. The d(hita on the distribution of new homes by sales price is suspect as it appears to contain several errors. One such error is illustrated by referenciv to tbe studss slubtraction of subsidized units. On page CRS-5, the sti(lyv estimates "than only 6,400 Section 235 units were sold for more than $21.000." However data from Tables 245 and 175 of the 1973 HU'D Yearbook shows over 15,000 Section 235 units with a total acqui-tion cost of over $21,000. The table at the bottom of the page CRS-4 implies that there were no non-subsidized units sold in 1973 with a sales price under $20,000. However data from Tables 208 and 175 of the 1973 HUD Yearbook shows that almost 5,000 units with FHITA insurance under Section 203 had a sales price of under $20,000. FHA insurance under Section 203 is not a subsidy program. Further the study ignores mobile homes entirely. Table 354 of the 1973 HUD Yearbook reports that 566,920 mobile home units were shipped in 1973. Retail sales in 1973 were estimated at $4.4 billion. These two figures imply an average price of $7.912. (This figure is not to be taken as a precise measure of average price. The data on total sales is only an estimate and the data on units is a measure of shipments not sales.) While not a precise estimate of average price, the $8,000 figure is surely in the ball park and suggests that a substantial number of mobile homes were available with a sales price of under $20,000. The figures on new homes sold are combined with an estimate of sales of existing homes to derive an estimate of total sales. How- ever, the estimate of the number of existing homes sold makes little sense. Data on the distribution of sales of existing homes by sales price comes from the National Association of Realtors but there re- mains the question of what base does one apply these percentages to. The CRS study uses an estimate of net new units built (total housing starts minus an estimate of the number of removals.) This is neither an estimate of total sales of existing homes nor is it a good proxy for total sales. The use of the number of net new units as a proxy for total sales makes little sense. A better, but still indirect, indication of the volume of existing home sales can be derived from the HUD survey of mortgage lending. HUD surveys mortgage lenders and asks them whether loans were made on new or existing homes. Of the mortgage lenders surveyed for the year 1973. the HUD survey shows loan originations for existing 1-_ family non-farm homes of 1.446.8 billion or 1.9 times the volume of loan originations for new 1-4 family units. If this ratio of mortgage financing is representative of the ratio of units sold, it suggests that perhaps 2.150.8 million existing homes were sold in 1973. This num- ber is 1.9 times the number of single family starts in 1973. This number of 2.1 million sales is only an estimate and not a precise measure. It is subject to several sorts of errors of unknown 89 magnitude. It is relatively easy to think of some types of errors that make the number too large and others that make it too small. Whether these errors just cancel out or can not be determined, but the estimate of total sales of existing single family units of around 2 million units is surely closer to the mark than the CRS study's estimate. Using the data on the distribution of sales by sales price and the estimate of 2.1 million sales in total suggests that 408,000 existing homes sold in 1973 had a sales price of less than $20,000 (19 percent of 2,150,800 units). This figure of over 400,000 is in sharp contrast with the 124,800 homes in the CRS study. THE COST OF OWNING A NEW HOME The second major part of the CRS study presents estimates of the cost of owning a new home. The table on page CRS-19 summarizes this effort. The numbers on this page purport to correspond to the costs of and associated required income for a median priced home for various years. This exercise is analogous to the estimates presented above for new FHA insured houses. However there are several serious weaknesses that result in a substantial overi:timate of costs and required income. While not a technical error, there is the question of what sort of a house families should be able to afford. The CIS study answers that question by using figures for the average of all homes built. It should be reemphasized that there is no scientific answer to the quest ion, "How big a house should families be able to afford?" The numbers presented above, while recognizing that there is no precise answer to the ques- tion, illustrated an answer that used the average of new FHA insured homes as a standard. The CRS choice of the more expensive average of all homes sold naturally raises the required income. The CRS study uses a house price of $41,300 for 1974. (There is a timing problem asso- ciated with this number that is discussed below.) By contrast the Census Bureau reports an average price of a new FHA insured house in 1974 at $29,800. The increase in sales price of over 35 percent would, by itself, raise the associated required income by roughly 35 percent. The CRS study purports to report data for a median price house. That is a home priced such that 50 percent of homes had higher prices and 50 percent had lower prices. But in fact the study uses data from a Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FI-LBB) survey that reports the average price of homes sold with conventional financing. The use of the average rather than the median raises the selling price and im- parts an upward bias to the results as a few very expensive homes make the average exceed the median. Further, the use of homes sold with conventional financing also results in a figure higher than one that includes homes sold with FHA and VA financing. It is easy to illustrate the impact of these points. For 1974 the FHLBB reports an average price of new homes with conventional financing at $40,100. The Census reports a median price for new homes with conventional financing of $38,000, over $2,000 less. The Census also reports median prices for new homes with FHA and VA financ- ing of $29,800 and $31,300. The overall median price, regardless of type of financing, as reported by the Census is $35,900. Clearly the choice of average, rather than median, and the use of only conven- 62-748-76-bk. I-7 90 tionally financed homes has a substantial effect on the sales price. The CRS study next assumes that their typical home is bought with a 10 percent downpayment. In 1974, homes with low down- payments tended to be homes with FHA or VA financing, homes that are excluded from the CRS average. In fact the average downpayment for the average FHLBB house was not 10 percent, but rather was 24.2 percent. The change in downpayment by itself means monthly mortgage payments that. are 18 percent higher. The interest rate data in the CRS study has two problems. First of all. it is an inappropriate rate and, second of all, the choice of time periods results in a misleadingly large increase for 1974 as compared with 1973. Dealing with the second issue first, the data for 1973 and earlier years is the average of rates over the year while the data for 1974 is for only one monthly. November. (This is the same timing prob- lem mentioned above in connection with purchase price and it has a similar effect.) Mortgage rates rose continuously throughout 1974, so data for November represent a much higher figure than the average for the year. However consistency with the earlier figures suggests usinrr an average over the whole year rather than one month. Dealing with the first is.-iie, in computing the monthly payment the CRS study uses the FHLBB series on effective mortgage rates, rather tlm.n the series on tlihe contract rate of interest. The difference between the two series is that the series on effective rates is the result of adjustments to the contract rate by the FHLBB to reflect the impact of fees and cli;g es associated with making the loan. The effective rate this exceeds the contract rate. The problem with using the effective rate to determine monthly mortgage payments is that these payments are determined by the colitract rate. not the effective rate. The fees and charges are all paid when the loan is originated. They are costs of liuying the house but are more like tlhe downpayment than they are the nionthily payment. With the procedure used in the CRS study the use of the effective mortgage rate, rather than the contract rate, results in lhigrlier monthlyy mortgage payments and thus a higher required income. All of these technical errors suggest that the CRS study substan- tially overestimates the required income to buy a house. The extent of this ovecrestiiiation can be illustrated. Tlhe CRS study concludes that it takes an annual income of $23,330 to buy a house in 1974. Data on mortgage (r characteristics for the year 1974-contract rate, principal, nmaturity-the average price for the year 1974 and estimated other expenses, derived from the CRS study, suggests a required income of $20,178. almost 14 percent less than the CRS figure. Using the rule of 25 percent of income for housing this income would support an average priced new home bought in 1974 with conventional financing. If one substitutes tlie Census figure for a median priced new home, but still assitumes tlie use of (conventional financing the required income drops to $19,121, or 18 percent below tihe CRS figure. Using FIIA data for hotes insured under Section 203 during the first nine months of 1974 suggests a required income of $14,163, almost 40 percent below the ('IS figure. |