THREE ESSAYS ON THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION
BY
DENNIS L. WEISMAN
A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL
OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT
OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA
1993
FL J A
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The completion of this dissertation reflects the generous contributions of a number of
individuals both near and far over a period of many years. It is only befitting that I take this
opportunity, as I know not whether there will be another, to express to them my heartfelt
gratitude.
Professor David Sappington directed this research effort and my greatest debt is to him.
Certainly the "least painful" way to supervise a dissertation is to lay out the relevant models and
have the student "paint by the numbers." It is an infinitely more difficult and frustrating task to
teach the student how to use the tools and then allow him to learn from "intelligent failure." I
thank Professor Sappington for taking the time to teach me the tools, for allowing me to fail
intelligently, and sometimes not so intelligently, for his patience, his kindness and most of all his
friendship. Indeed, it was my privilege to have studied under one of the profession's great talents.
Professor Sanford Berg recruited me for the University of Florida, and I wish to thank him
for his vision and creativity in understanding where a collaborative venture between business and
academia could lead. He provided an environment at the Public Utility Research Center
conducive to my research interests and imposed minimal commitments on my time. I benefitted
immeasurably from his knowledge of regulatory economics, not only in my formal research but
in my work with regulatory commissions as well.
Professor Tracy Lewis shared generously of his time and abilities in discussing many of
the ideas in this dissertation. He provided constant encouragement and inspiration throughout this
effort, while keeping me focused on the next research frontier. I am most grateful to him for his
stimulating thoughts, penetrating insight and fellowship.
Professor Jeffrey Yost served as the outside member on my dissertation committee. I
benefitted on numerous occasions from his ability to relate my research ideas to those in other
fields. Moreover, he devoted many hours to the discussion of the ideas that ultimately formed
the core of this work. His insights and effort are most appreciated and gratefully acknowledged.
Professor John Lynch graciously read and commented on this work while offering support
and encouragement. His efforts are very much appreciated.
I wish to express my appreciation to a number of the other faculty members at the
University of Florida who shared of their time and intellect, both in the classroom and in private
discussions. I mention in particular Professor Jonathan Hamilton, Professor Richard Romano,
Professor Steven Slutsky, Professor John Wyman and Professor Edward Zabel.
I wish to express a very special debt of gratitude to Professor Lester Taylor and Professor
Alfred Kahn. Professor Taylor graciously has read and commented on virtually every paper I
have written over the last decade. I am grateful to him for his penetrating intellect and insight.
He is a trusted friend and a true scholar. Professor Alfred Kahn provided much critical insight
on my early work on the carrier of last resort issue. His wisdom and generous encouragement
have been a valued source of inspiration for many years.
I thank Professor Donald Kridel and Professor Dale Lehman for their valuable comments
on my research, and for their friendship, support and encouragement.
I thank Professor Robert McNown and the late Professor Nicholas Schrock for introducing
me to economic research while I was still an undergraduate at the University of Colorado. I
learned from them the importance of "asking the right question" and the courage to challenge
prevailing orthodoxy.
I wish to acknowledge Dave Gallemore, Robert Glaser and Jon Loehman of Southwestern
Bell Corporation for their support of the collaborative research venture with the University of
Florida that ultimately led to this dissertation. Jon Loehman was especially instrumental in
recognizing the long-term benefits of this project and for moving it forward. I express to him my
sincere gratitude.
Monica Nabors and Carol Stanton supplied truly superb word processing support. Their
efforts are gratefully acknowledged and very much appreciated.
I would like to thank my parents, who instilled in me at an early age the work ethic
necessary to complete this course of study.
Finally, I wish to thank my wife and best friend, Melanie, whose sacrifice was the greatest
of all. Without her love, support and encouragement, this dream of mine could never have been
realized. I shall always be grateful.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
page
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ........................................... ii
A BSTR A CT ...................................... ............... vii
CHAPTERS
1 GENERAL INTRODUCTION ................... .......... 1
2 SUPERIOR REGULATORY REGIMES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE .. 6
Introduction .... .... .................. ................... 6
Definitions of Regulatory Regimes ...................... ........ 7
Cost-Based (CB) Regulation ................................ 7
Price-Cap (PC) Regulation ................................... 8
Modified Price-Cap (MPC) Regulation .......................... 8
A Formal Characterization of MPC Regulation ................... 9
Distortions Under MPC Regulation ............................. 10
Social W welfare Results .................................... 15
Welfare-Superiority Example ................... ...... ..... 18
Recontracting Induced Distortions in the MPC Model ................. 19
Technology Distortions ................................... 21
Cost Misreporting Distortions ................... .... ....... 22
Conclusion ................... ........... ........ ........ 23
3 WHY LESS MAY BE MORE UNDER PRICE-CAP REGULATION .... 25
Introduction ............................................. 25
Elements of the Model ...................................... 28
Benchmark Solutions ................. .................... 29
The First-Best Case ....................................... 29
The Second-Best Case ......... ... ........ .... ........... 34
Principal Findings ..................... ................... 39
Conclusion .............................................. 49
4 DESIGNING CARRIER OF LAST RESORT OBLIGATIONS ......... 55
Introduction ............................................. 55
Elements of the Model ................... .................. 59
Benchmark Solutions ........... .... ........ ........ 61
Principal Findings ........................................ 69
Conclusion .................................. .... ........ 76
5 CONCLUDING COMMENTS ................................ 78
APPENDIX CORE WASTE EXAMPLE ................................ 81
REFERENCES .................. .............. ...... ......... 82
BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH .......................................... 85
Abstract of Dissertation Presented to the Graduate School
of the University of Florida in Partial Fulfillment of the
Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy
THREE ESSAYS ON THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION
By
Dennis L. Weisman
May, 1993
Chairman: Professor David E. M. Sappington
Major Department: Economics
The objective in each essay is to model the strategic behavior of the "players" so as to
capture the structure of existing regulatory institutions and yet produce tractable results. The
unifying theme throughout is a revealing comparison between a given theoretical construct and
its real world counterpart.
A substantial body of recent research finds that price-cap regulation is superior to cost-
based regulation in that many of the distortions associated with the latter are reduced or eliminated
entirely. In the first essay, we prove that the hybrid application of cost-based and price-cap
regulation that characterizes current regulatory practice in the U.S. telecommunications industry
may generate qualitative distortions greater in magnitude than those realized under cost-based
regulation. The analysis further reveals that the firm subject to this modified form of price-cap
regulation may have incentives to engage in waste and overdiversify in the noncore market
The incentive regulation literature has focused on how to discipline the regulated firm.
In the second essay, we consider how price-cap regulation might enable the firm to discipline the
regulator. We show that under quite general conditions, the firm will prefer profit-sharing to pure
price-cap regulation under which it retains one hundred percent of its profits. Profit-sharing limits
the incentives of regulators to take actions adverse to the firm's financial interests. The discipline
imposed on the regulator results in a more profitable regulatory environment for the firm.
Public utilities are generally subject to a carrier of last resort (COLR) obligation which
requires them to stand by with capacity in place to serve on demand. In our third essay, we find
that when the competitive fringe is relatively reliable, imposing a COLR obligation
(asymmetrically) on the incumbent firm will lower the optimal price. The optimal price is further
reduced when the fringe chooses its reliability strategically. A principal finding is that the fringe
may overcapitalize (undercapitalize) in the provision of reliability when the incumbent's COLR
obligation is sufficiently low (high).
CHAPTER 1
GENERAL INTRODUCTION
Public utility regulation in the United States and Europe is being transformed by a number
of market and institutional changes. Prominent among these are emerging competition and
experimentation with alternatives to rate-of-retur (ROR) regulation. These are not unrelated
events and developing an understanding of the critical interaction between them is of paramount
importance. Economic analysis is complex in such a dynamic environment because it is necessary
to model the strategic behavior of the "players in the game" in a manner that captures the
semblance of existing regulatory institutions yet still yields tractable results. This is the primary
challenge that confronts us here.
Each of the three essays that comprise the core of this dissertation begins with a given
theoretical model and then proceeds to build institutional realism into the mathematical structure.
This modeling approach allows for a revealing comparison between the given theoretical model
and its "real world" counterpart. The results of the analysis allow us to question, and in many
cases reverse, a number of principal findings in the literature. These results should prove useful
to researchers and policymakers in regulated industries.
Public utilities in the United States and Europe have traditionally been subject to ROR or
cost-based (CB) regulation.' Under this form of regulation, the utility is allowed to earn a
specified return on invested capital and recover all prudently incurred expenses. The efficiency
SWe use these terms interchangeably throughout the analysis.
I
distortions under ROR regulation are well known and have been explored at length in the
literature.
Price-cap (PC) regulation, under which the firm's prices rather than its earnings are
capped, has recently attracted considerable attention by regulated firms, public utility regulators
and the academic community. Following a successful trial of PC regulation with British Telecom,
the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) adopted this new form of incentive regulation
for AT&T and subsequently for the Regional Bell Operating Companies.
A substantial body of recent research examines the superiority of PC over CB regulation.
One of the principal findings of this research is that PC regulation eliminates many of the
economic distortions associated with CB regulation. Specifically, under CB regulation, the firm's
tendency is to (i) underdiversify in the noncore (diversification) market, (ii) produce with an
inefficient technology, (iii) choose suboptimal levels of cost reducing innovation, (iv) price below
marginal cost in competitive markets under some conditions, and (v) misreport costs.
In the first essay titled Superior Regulatory Regimes in Theory and Practice, we examine
whether the superiority of PC regulation endures once we depart from the strict provisions of the
theoretical construct. We prove that although PC regulation is superior to CB regulation, it is not
true that a movement from CB regulation in the direction of PC regulation is necessarily superior
to CB regulation.
The type of hybrid application of CB and PC regulation that prevails currently in the
telecommunications industry may generate qualitative distortions greater in magnitude than those
realized under CB regulation. Moreover, we find that the firm operating under what we
henceforth refer to as modified price-cap (MPC) regulation has incentives to engage in pure waste
and overdiversify in the noncore market under some conditions. These are qualitative distortions
3
that do not arise under pure PC regulation.2 The economic and public policy implications of
these findings are disconcerting. While regulators initially adopted PC regulation in large measure
to reduce the inefficiencies inherent in CB regulation, in practice these distortions may well be
exacerbated.
The second essay is titled Why Less May Be More Under Price-Cap Regulation. In this
essay, we examine incentive regulation from a different viewpoint, examining how the firm can
discipline the regulator by choosing a particular form of PC regulation that aligns the regulator's
interests with those of the firm.
We begin by recognizing that the firm may be able to reverse the standard principal-agent
relationship by providing the regulator with a vested interest in its financial performance. By
adopting a form of PC regulation that entails sharing profits with consumers, the firm can exploit
the political control that consumers exercise over the regulator and thereby induce the regulator
to choose a higher price or a lower level of competitive entry. Our major result shows that if
demand is relatively price-inelastic and the regulator's weight on consumer surplus is not too
large, the firm's profits will be higher under sharing than under pure price-caps. Sharing is thus
a dominant strategy for the firm, so that less really is more.
In practice there is an important, albeit largely unrecognized, distinction between the
regulator's commitment to a price-cap and the regulator's commitment to a specified market price.
As long as the regulator controls the terms of competitive entry, market price is decreasing with
entry, and such entry cannot be contracted upon, the regulator's commitment to a specified price-
cap may be meaningless. This is a classic example of incomplete contracting. The regulator must
2 Under pure PC regulation, there is no profit-sharing with regulators (consumers). The firm
retains one hundred percent of its profits.
4
be given the requisite incentives to limit competitive entry, but such incentives are absent under
pure PC regulation.
The reason that pure PC regulation is problematic when competitive entry cannot be
contracted upon is that the regulator incurs no cost by adopting procompetitive entry policies since
it does not share in the firm's profits. Under pure PC regulation, the regulator is perfectly
insulated from the adverse consequences of procompetitive entry policies. Under a profit-sharing
scheme, the regulator can adopt procompetitive entry policies only at a cost of forgone shared
profits. Consequently, the regulator will generally be induced to adopt a less aggressive
competitive entry policy under PC regulation with sharing than under pure PC regulation. This
is the manner in which sharing rules can discipline the actions of the regulator.
What may be surprising is that regulated firms are generally opposed to profit-sharing in
practice, perhaps because it is believed that the sharing rule affects only the distribution of profits,
but not their absolute level. The irony here is that the regulated firm may object to sharing on
the grounds that it subverts economic efficiency, a result consistent with our first essay, only to
discover that sharing leads to higher realized profits. We should therefore naturally expect the
regulator to support pure PC regulation and the firm to support profit-sharing, yet we observe
quite the opposite.
The third and final essay in this dissertation is titled Designing Carrier of Last Resort
Obligations. The COLR obligation essentially charges the incumbent firm with responsibility for
standing by with facilities in place to serve consumers on demand. The historical origins of the
obligation are significant because it is the asymmetry of this obligation that is the source of the
market distortion.
A public utility with a franchised right to serve a certificated geographic area maintains
a responsibility to serve all consumers on demand. Yet, at least historically, there was a
5
corresponding obligation on the part of consumers to be served by the public utility. This balance
evolved over time as a fundamental tenet of the regulatory compact. Regulators have been
reluctant to relieve the incumbent of its COLR obligation when challenged by a fringe competitor
over concern that consumers could be abandoned without access to essential services.
We find that the presence of a competitive fringe tends to place downward pressure on
the optimal price set by the regulator. When the competitive fringe is relatively reliable, the
imposition of an asymmetric COLR obligation on the incumbent firm will tend to reduce further
the optimal price. Moreover when the fringe is allowed to choose its reliability strategically, the
optimal price is lower yet. These results may support a regulatory policy of greater downward
pricing flexibility for a market incumbent facing a fringe competitor while bearing an asymmetric
COLR obligation.
Our principal finding is that the competitive fringe has incentives to overcapitalize
(undercapitalize) in the provision of reliability when the COLR obligation is sufficiently low
(high). Here, supply creates its own demand in that the need for a COLR may be validated as
a self-fulfilling prophecy in equilibrium. Moreover, any attempt by the competitive fringe to
exploit the COLR obligation by increasing reliability and stranding the incumbent's plant with the
intent of raising its rivals' costs will prove self-defeating. These findings may help explain
competitive fringe strategy in the telecommunications industry.
CHAPTER 2
SUPERIOR REGULATORY REGIMES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Introduction
A substantial body of recent research examines the superiority of price-based or price-cap
(PC) over cost-based (CB) regulation.' One of the principal findings of this research is that PC
regulation eliminates many of the economic distortions associated with CB regulation.
Specifically, under CB regulation, the finn's tendency is to (i) underdiversify in the noncore
(diversification) market; (ii) produce with an inefficient technology; (iii) choose suboptimal levels
of cost reducing innovation; (iv) price below marginal cost in competitive markets under some
conditions; and (v) misreport costs.
The objectives of this essay are twofold. First, we prove that although PC regulation is
superior to CB regulation, it is not true that a movement from CB regulation in the direction of
PC regulation is necessarily superior to CB regulation. The type of hybrid application of CB and
PC regulation that prevails currently in the telecommunications industry may generate qualitative
distortions greater in magnitude than those realized under CB regulation. Second, we prove that
the firm operating under what we henceforth refer to as modified price-cap (MPC) regulation has
incentives to engage in pure waste and overdiversify in the noncore market under some conditions.
These are qualitative distortions that do not arise under price-cap regulation.
SSee for example Braeutigam and Panzar (1989), Brennan (1989), Vogelsang (1988) and
Federal Communications Commission (1988). We shall use the terms price-based and price-cap
regulation interchangeably. The latter term has come into vogue in the telecommunications
industry due to recent experiments with capping prices by British Telecom and the Federal
Communications Commission. See Beesley and Littlechild (1989).
6
7
The economic and public policy implications of these findings are disconcerting. While
regulators initially adopted PC regulation in large measure to reduce the inefficiencies inherent
in CB regulation, in practice it may actually serve to exacerbate these distortions.
The format for the remainder of this essay is as follows. The three regulatory regimes are
defined in the second section. The third section provides a formal characterization of the MPC
regulation model. The fourth section examines the efficiency properties of MPC regulation in
comparison with CB and PC regulation. The main result is that social welfare can be lower under
MPC regulation than under CB regulation. In the fifth section, we show that the regulated firm
may engage in waste when there is a nonzero probability that the regulator will recontract and
subject the firm to more stringent regulation. The sixth section is a conclusion and an assessment
of the importance of these results for economic and public policy analysis in regulated industries.
The Appendix provides an example in which waste is profitable for the firm.
Definitions of Regulatory Regimes
There are two markets, a core (regulated) market in which the firm is a monopolist and
a noncore (competitive) market in which the firm is a price-taker.2 It is useful to begin the
formal analysis with a precise definition of each of the three regulatory regimes: CB, PC and
MPC.
Cost-Based (CB) Regulation
Under CB regulation, the firm chooses output in the core and noncore markets subject to
the constraint that core market revenues be no greater than the sum of core market attributable
costs plus shared costs that have been allocated to the core market (i.e., core market zero profit
constraint). As Braeutigam and Panzar (1989, p. 374) note, CB regulation combines elements of
2 In the telecommunications industry, basic telephone access is an example of a core service,
and voice messaging is an example of a noncore service.
8
rate-of-retur regulation with fully distributed cost pricing. CB regulation serves as the benchmark
regulatory regime for this analysis.
Price-Cap (PC) Regulation
Under PC regulation, the regulator sets a price-cap (p) in the regulated core market. The
firm is allowed to retain one hundred percent of the profits it generates subject only to the core
market price-cap constraint. Because the firm retains all of its profits under this regime (i.e., there
is no sharing of profits with ratepayers), the need for fully distributed costing (FDC) is obviated.
That is, since there is no need for the regulator to differentiate between core and noncore profits.
FDC is not required to allocate costs common to both core and noncore services. As will be
shown subsequently, it is this characteristic of PC regulation that underlies its claim of superiority.
Modified Price-Cap (MPC) Regulation
Under MPC regulation the regulator again sets a price-cap (p) in the regulated core
market. Here, however, the firm is only allowed to retain a specified share of the profits it
generates in the core market under the price-cap constraint. In practice, the firm's share of profits
is generally decreasing with the level of core market profits.
The asset base of the local telephone companies is partitioned into core and noncore (or
diversified) categories. In practice, this partition is based upon FDC. Hence, unlike the pure
price-cap model examined by Braeutigam and Panzar (1989), price-cap regulation with sharing
mechanisms must of necessity incorporate cost allocations. Notice that CB and MPC regulation
thus share a common source of economic distortion.3 In this sense, MPC regulation is a hybrid
of CB and PC regulation.
3 Under MPC regulation, however, it is not the cost allocator per se that is the source of the
distortion, but the interaction of the cost allocator with the regulatory tax function.
9
A Formal Characterization of MPC Regulation
The firm's problem [FP] is to maximize the sum of core and noncore profit through
choice of outputs, subject to a price-cap constraint. Output is denoted by y,, price by pi, and
attributable cost by c'(y,), i = 1,2, where market 1 is the core market and market 2 is the noncore
market. Revenues in the core market are denoted by R'(y,). Shared costs are denoted by F. The
firm's cost function is
(0) C(y,y2) = F + c'(yi) + c2(y).
Shared costs are allocated between the core and the noncore market by a cost allocator,
f(y,,y2) e [0,1], that represents the fraction of shared costs allocated to the core market.4 The
allocator is increasing in core output and decreasing in noncore output. Hence, f, > 0 and f, <
0, where the subscripts denote partial derivatives. The relative output cost allocator is defined
formally by f(y,,y2) = YI/(y, + y2). The firm is a price-taker in the noncore market with the
equilibrium parametric price in the noncore market given by p:. Marginal cost in the noncore
market is assumed to be increasing in output, c, > 0. We define social welfare by
Y
(1) W(yy2) = Jp'l()d + p:Y2 C(y,Y2) + S,
0
where p'(.) is the inverse demand function in the core market and S is consumer surplus in the
noncore market which is a constant because price is parametric. Let WmC(yl,y2) and WCB(y,yZ)
represent social welfare under MPC and CB regulation, respectively. We further define CB
regulation to be welfare-superior (inferior) to MPC regulation whenever Wm'C(yl,y2) < (>)
WCB(yl,y2).
The most common form of PC regulation in the telecommunications industry calls for core
market profits to be taxed, or shared between the firm and its ratepayers. Define core market
4 See Braeutigam (1980) for a discussion of cost allocators commonly used in regulated
industries and their properties.
10
profits by x t = R'(y1) f(yi,yz)F c'(yt). Let T(t,) E [0,1] denote a regulatory tax function,
where l-T(7r,) is the share of each additional dollar in core market profits retained by the firm.
In most state jurisdictions today, T(c,) is an increasing function, so T'(i,) > 0. Depending on
the jurisdiction, the regulatory tax function may be either concave or convex. Moreover, the
majority of these MPC plans employ a ceiling, either explicitly or implicitly, on core market
profits (iE ) so that T(r,) = 1, V ti, K> Finally, except where otherwise noted it will prove
expeditious to work with a constant regulatory tax function, T, i.e., T(7,) = T.
Distortions Under MPC Regulation
In this section, we characterize the efficiency properties of the MPC model with a set of
formal propositions.
Proposition 1: If T > 0 the regulated firm under MPC regulation will supply inefficiently small
output levels in the noncore market (i.e., Pe > c0).5
Proof: The Lagrangian for the MPC model is given by
(2) SE = Il-T(r1)[[R'(y,) f(y,,y,)F c'(yl)] + p:y2 ([-f(yI,y2)]F
c2(y) + 5(y, y;].6.7
5 As Braeutigam and Panzar (1989) note, a similar result was proven by Sweeney (1982) in
a somewhat different context.
6 Since there is no demand uncertainty in this model, we can represent the price-cap
constraint, pi < p., in terms of restrictions on output levels, y, 2 y\, where y, is the core market
output level corresponding to a price of pi.
7 For ease of comparison, we provide a sketch of the Braeutigam and Panzar (1989, p. 380)
proof for the CB regulation model. The Lagrangian is given by
(1.1) H = R'(y,) + p'Y2 F c(y,) c2(y2) +[f(yl,y2)F + c(y,) R'(y)j,
where X is the Lagrange multiplier on the core market zero-profit constraint. Differentiating (1.1)
with respect to y2, assuming an interior solution and rearranging terms, we obtain
(1.2) p* c = -mFf, > 0,
since > 0 when the zero-profit constant binds and f2 > 0.
The first-order condition for noncore output, y2, assuming an interior solution and a constant
regulatory tax function is given by:
(3) -/ay, = -(1-T)fF + p + f,F c = 0.
Rearranging terms and simplifying yields
(4) p c1 = -f2FT > 0.8"9
The underproduction distortion occurs under MPC regulation because each additional unit of
noncore output imposes two costs on the regulated firm. First, there is the marginal cost that is
directly attributable to producing the noncore service, ci. In addition, shared costs are shifted
from the core to the noncore market at the rate of fF. As a result, the firm gains (1-T) in
increased profits in the core market yet realizes -1 in increased costs in the noncore market. The
8 Relaxing the assumption of a constant regulatory tax function leads to a further output
distortion in the same direction. It can be shown that the equilibrium condition for this more
general formulation is given by the following expression: p: c2 = -fF[T + NiT'] > 0.
Increasing noncore market output now has two separate effects: (1) common costs shift from the
core to the noncore market, which raises profits in the core market by l-T and reduces profits in
the noncore market by -1 for a net effect of -T: (2) the increased level of profits in the core
market raises the effective regulatory tax, which reduces the level of core profits retained by i, T'.
9 Similar results hold when there is a nonzero probability that the regulator will disavow the
price-cap commitment and force the firm to recontract. Let O(7l,) and l-)(it) define the firm's
subjective probability that the regulator will recontract (i.e., honor the price-cap commitment) and
not recontract, respectively. If the regulator does recontract, the firm is assumed to face a core
market profits tax of T > 0. A natural assumption is that the higher the reported core market
profits, the higher the probability that the regulator will recontract, hence, 0'(xi ) > 0. In this case,
p c2 = -f,F[OT + S'Tx,] > 0. There are once again two separate effects associated with
increasing output in the noncore market: (1) common costs shift from the core to the noncore
market, raising profits by l- T in the core market and reducing profits in the noncore market by
-1 for a net effect of -0 T; (2) increased profits in the core market raise the probability that the
regulator will force the firm to recontract. The expected change in core market profits for the firm
is thus -O'TT,. This result provides some intuition for the distortions induced by commitment
uncertainty. See Weisman (1989a, p. 165 and notes 30 and 31) for a discussion of the
intergenerational distortions resulting from a nonzero probability of recontracting.
net effect is negative V T > 0. The magnitude of this distortion is monotonically increasing
in T.'0
Now consider the diversification distortion that arises under MPC regulation in the
presence of vertically integrated markets. As the earnings ceiling is approached so T -- 1, the
firm operating in vertically integrated markets may overdiversify, i.e., it may choose an output
level at which marginal cost exceeds the parametric price. This occurs because the high tax rate
in combination with the vertical market relationship reduces the finn's effective input cost for
noncore production. The firm responds by increasing output in the noncore market.
Some additional notation is required for making this point formally. Let z, denote units
of y, used exclusively as inputs in the production of yz. Hence, we can write z, = h(y,). The
revenue derived from the sale of z, is denoted by R'(z,).
This set-up conforms with the institutional structure of the telecommunications industry,
where y, denotes retail local calls, y2 denotes retail long-distance calls, and z, represents wholesale
local calls used exclusively as inputs to complete the local connections (access) of long-distance
calls. Hence, the demand for z, is a derived demand from 2,.
Definition 1: The input z, is an essential input in the production of Y2 if y2 cannot be produced
without z,, or y2 can be produced without z, but only at a cost that would make such
production unremunerative.
Proposition 2: Suppose that z, is an essential input in the production of yz. Then for T
sufficiently close to unity, the firm operating under MPC regulation will overdiversify if
(dz1/dy2) > -f/f1.
10 The distortion under MPC regulation can be greater than (less than) the distortion under CB
regulation. See proposition 3 and the discussion of social welfare.
Proof: The Lagrangian for the MPC regime is given by:
(5) S = l-T((x,)I[R'(y,) + R'(z,) f(y + z,y2)F c'(y, + z,)] + PeY2
[l-f(y, + z,,y2)]F- c2(y,) + 6[(y, + z,) (y, + z)*.11
Assuming the price-cap constraint does not bind, the first-order condition for Y2 is given by
(6) aa/ay2 = (1-T)[(OR'/8z, fiF-c )(dz,/dy2)-f2F] + p: + fF(dz,/dy,)
+ fF ci = 0.
Rearranging terms, we obtain
(7) p; c2 = -(I-T)[(aR'/ay, fF-cb)(dz,/dy,)-fF] -fF(dz,/dy,) -t4F.
Further rearranging of terms yields
(8) p* c2 = -FT[f,(dz,/dy2) + f,]-(l-T)[(R'/Az,-ci)(dz,/dy,)].
Assuming marginal revenue for z, is bounded, then for T sufficiently close to unity, equation (8)
reduces to
(9) p: ci = -F[f,(dzi/dy,)+ f,].12
Since z, is an input in the production of Y2, dz,/dy, > 0. The term inside the brackets in
(8) is thus positive whenever (dz,/dy2) > -f;/f,. Thus, when this condition holds, p: < c'. .
Note that we have assumed here that z, and y, have the identical cost structure and cost
allocator. This facilitates computational ease and yet does not fundamentally alter the general
result.
12 It is straightforward to show that with a binding price-cap constraint the equivalent
condition is given by p: c = -FT[f,(dz,/dy9 + f2] + 8(dp,/dz,)(dz,/dy2). Since 56 0 and dp,/dz,
< 0, none of the qualitative results are affected by the assumption that the price-cap constraint is
nonbinding.
14
Hence, when the vertical relationship is sufficiently strong (dzi/dy2 is sufficiently large),
the firm will overdiversify in that it will choose a level of output in the noncore market at which
marginal cost exceeds the parametric price.
Corollary to Proposition 2: For the relative output cost allocator, the firm will overdiversify in
the noncore market if T is sufficiently close to unity and dzi/dy, > (y, + zl)/Y2.
Proof: For the relative output cost allocator,
(10) f, + f, = (Y2 y, zO)/(y, + z, + y,)2.
Hence, from proposition 2, the corollary will hold if
(11) [y2(dzi/dy,) y, z,]/(yl + y )+ 2)> 0,
or
(12) dz1/dy, > (y, + zi)/y2,
which is satisfied for dz1/dy, and/or Y2, sufficiently large. I
Hence, if the vertical relationship is sufficiently strong and/or the noncore market is
sufficiently large, the firm will overdiversify in the noncore market.
The intuition for these results is as follows. Each additional unit of output in the noncore
market generates increased demand for the intermediate good, z,. When output increases in the
core market, shared costs are shifted from the noncore to the core market which the firm views
as a de facto subsidy to noncore production. This leads the firm to choose a level of production
in the noncore market greater than that which is chosen in the absence of a vertical relationship.
To illustrate, consider the case of access (z,) and long-distance telephone service (y,).
Each long-distance telephone call requires two local access connections, one each at the
origination and termination points of the call. This production relation implies that dz,/dy, = 2.
Hence, a sufficient condition for the vertically integrated firm to overdiversify in the long-distance
15
telephone market is that the firm's output in the long-distance market be greater than one half that
of the firm's output in the combined local and access telephone service market, or y, > (y, + z,)/2.
Social Welfare Results
The above propositions examine various qualitative distortions under MPC regulation.
In this subsection, we compare social welfare under MPC and CB regulation. The propositions
identify an important nonconvexity whereby a move in the direction of pure PC regulation may
actually reduce welfare. We begin by proving a number of useful lemmas.
Lemma 1: If T = (the Lagrange multiplier on the zero-profit constraint in the CB model)'3
and 6 = 0 at the solution to [FP], then the core and noncore output levels are the same
under CB and MPC regulatory regimes.
Proof: This result follows immediately from examination of the relevant first-order conditions.
Lemma 2: If 6 > 0, then dy,/dT = 0 and dy2/dT < 0 at the solution to [FP] under MPC
regulation.
Proof: The Lagrangian for [FP] under MPC regulation is
(13) SE = [I-T(o,)][R'(y,) f(y,,y2)F c'(y,)] + pY2 [I-f(y,y2)]F
c(y2) + 8[y, y1].
The necessary first-order conditions for an interior optimum include
(14) [l-T][R}(y,) fF cl] + fF + 6 = 0,
(15) [-T][-f2F] + p: + f,F = 0. and
13 Braeutigam and Panzar (1989, p. 378) prove that X E (0,1) in the CB regulation model so
that it is always possible to choose T equal to X. See also note 7 above.
(16) y y = 0.
Rearranging terms and differentiating the first-order conditions with respect to the tax rate, T, we
obtain
(17) [ [ -Tf][R (yi)-f1iF-ci,]+f1F]] dyl/dT+Tf12dy2/dT+dS/dT=Ri(y)-fF-c;,
(18) Tf2Fdyi/dT + [Tf,,F c jdy./dT = -fF, and
(19) dyi/dT = 0.
From Cramer's rule,
R (yl)-fF-ci
-f,F
Tf2 1
Tf 12
fF-c;2 0
(20) dy,/dT = 0 0 0
H|
where H is the relevant bordered Hessian. IHI must be positive at a maximum. Expanding the
determinant in (20), we obtain
(21) dy1/dT = 0.
Similarly for dy2/dT,
1 -TlR'i(y1)-f 1F-ci'J,+f11F
Tf F
Tf21F
(22) dy2/dT = 1
HI
Expanding the determinant in (22), we obtain
(23) dy,/dT = f,F < 0. E
R (y,) -fF-c;
-f,F
0
In the next proposition, we prove that CB regulation can be welfare superior to MPC
regulation if social welfare is initially equal under the two regimes and the price-cap (output)
constraint binds.
Proposition 3: If WMP = WcB and 8 > 0 in the solution to [FP], then for a small increase in T,
WMPC < W .
Proof: The change in social welfare, for dy, and dy2 small, is given by
(24) dW = (p, c,)dy, + (p: ci~dy,.
By lemma 2, dyi/dT = 0 and dy2/dT < 0, so that
(25) dW/dT = (p cj)dy2 < 0,
since pN > c| by proposition 1. U
In the telecommunications industry, it is common practice for regulators to freeze the basic
monthly service charge at current levels so that the price under CB regulation serves as the
price-cap under MPC regulation. In the following corollary, we explore the effect of an increase
in the tax rate, T, when the firm holds the core market output level constant, an assumption not
inconsistent with institutional reality.
Corollary to Proposition 3: If WMP = WcB, 5= 0 and core market output is constant, then for
a small increase in T, WPc < WC.
Proof: Differentiating equation (17), which implicitly defines y1, with respect to T, we obtain
(26) 11-T][-f 2F][dy2/dT] + f,F[dy,/dTI cr[d,/dT] = -fF.
Collecting terms and simplifying yields
(27) dy,/dT = -fF/[Tf, 2-c2] < 0,
since f, < 0 and the denominator is negative by a necessary second order condition for a
maximum. The result follows directly from proposition 1. M
The firm chooses output levels in the core and noncore markets to maximize total profits.
These optimal output levels jointly define an equilibrium allocation of shared costs between the
core and the noncore markets. An increase in the tax rate, AT > 0, with core market output
unchanged, perturbs the equilibrium allocation of shared costs as it now becomes more profitable
18
for the firm to recover a larger proportion of shared costs in the core market. To see this,
recognize that the cost to the firm for each dollar of shared costs allocated to the core market falls
from [1-T] to [l-(T+AT)]. The firm responds by shifting additional shared costs to the core
market. With core market output unchanged, the only way the firm can shift shared costs to the
core market is by reducing output in the noncore market. Core market output is thus the same
as under CB regulation but noncore output is lower. It follows that social welfare can be lower
under MPC regulation than under CB regulation.
Welfare-Superiority Example
We now turn to a specific example to provide some intuitive appreciation for these results.
Let the firm's inverse demand function be given by p'(y ) = 20 y1, where core market revenues
are R'(y) = 20y, y1. The parametric price in the noncore market is p, = 5. The firm's cost
function is C(y,, y,) = 92 + yj + 0.5y We employ a relative cost allocator of the form f(y1, y,)
= Yl/(y, + y,), where fl = Y2/(y + y2)2 and f, = -yl/(y, + Y2)2. Setting the firm's break-even profit
level at 10, the Lagrangian for the [FP] under the CB regulatory regime is given by
(28) S = 19y, y + 5y2 92 0.5y' + [10 + 92y,/(y, + Y2) 19y, + y].
The necessary first-order conditions for an interior optimum include
(29) y,: (19 2y,][1-k] + 92y12/(y, + y2)2 = 0,
(30) y2: 5 y, 92yiA/(y + y2)2 = 0, and
(31) X: 10 + 92y,/(y, + y2) 19y, + y, = 0.
Equations (29)-(31) represent three simultaneous nonlinear equations in three unknowns: y1, Y1,
and X. Numerical simulation techniques reveal the following solution: y, = 10.02913, y =
1.50870 and X = 0.503715.
From lemma 1, we know that if T = 0.503715 and 8 = 0, then the core and noncore
output levels are the same under MPC and CB regulation. From equation (1), it can be shown
that WMpc = WC = 54.67 + S, where S is the constant level of consumer surplus in the noncore
market. Now suppose that we allow for a marginal increase in the regulatory profits tax under
MPC regulation from T = 0.503715 to T = 0.521975. It can be shown that the new level of
welfare under MPC regulation is 45.26 + S, so that the change in welfare is -9.41. We have thus
demonstrated by example that CB regulation can be welfare-superior to MPC regulation.
Recontracting Induced Distortions in the MPC Model
One of the more serious concerns with PC regulation in practice is the prospect that the
firm will fare too well under this new regulatory regime and regulators will recontract, or subject
the firm to more stringent regulation. Let 0(n,) define the firm's subjective probability that the
regulator will recontract, in which case the firm's core market profits are assumed to be taxed at
the rate T. If recontracting does not occur, the firm is assumed to retain all of its profits. We
further define the recontracting elasticity as e, = 'ni,/0. In the next proposition, we show that
conditions exist under which the firm has incentives to engage in pure waste under MPC
regulation. Pure waste in this context refers to the purchase of costly inputs which have no
productive value.
Proposition 4: The risk-neutral firm operating under MPC regulation will have incentives to
engage in pure core waste whenever e, > (1 4T)/ T.
Proof: The Lagrangian with pure waste variables up, u., and uF, respectively representing core,
noncore and shared waste, is given by
(32) = [((x,)(1-T) + (-10( C1)][R'(y) f(y,, y2)(F + uF) c'(y,) u1]
20
+ PY2 [1-f(y,,y2)I(F + UF) c(y2) u2 + 6[y, y].
Let aggregate profits be denoted by i = i, + 7c,. By the Envelope Theorem, an increase in core
market waste is profitable for the firm whenever
(33) dr/du, = [rx,/au,] [t,['(1i)(l-T)-v'(0,)] + [4(x,)(1-T) + 1-O(,)] > 0.
Recognize that [3t,/3u,] = -1. Rearranging terms yields.
(34) O'T1, + ([OT 1] > 0,
(35) O'Tn, > 1 IT.
(36) O'TF,/ T > (1 T)/fT,
and, by the definition of the recontracting elasticity,
(37) e > (1 OT)/O .4 *
There are two separate effects on profits associated with the firm engaging in pure core
waste. The first effect is positive and corresponds to the first term in equation (34). Each dollar
of pure core waste reduces the probability that the regulator will recontract (i.e. levy a profits tax
equal to T) and thus enables the firm to retain a larger share of realized profits. The second
effect is negative and corresponds to the second term in equation (34). Each dollar of pure core
waste reduces the realized profits of the firm by precisely 1-4 T.
In contrast to CB regulation, there exist conditions under which the firm will engage in
pure core waste under MPC regulation.'5 Also note that since d/dT((1-T))/OT} = -[0 T +
14 In the more general case in which the firm is initially taxed at a rate of T, and recontracting
results in a tax of Tj, where T, < Tj, the core waste condition can be shown to be given by ,
> [l-T, T(Tj Ti)]/4(T, T,). Note that when Ti = 0, this expression reduces to e, > 1 -
o T/O T,, which corresponds to the standard MPC model examined in the proposition.
'5 Similar results hold when the firm faces a zero probability of recontracting, but the
regulatory tax function is increasing in core market profits, x,. In this case, it can be shown that
the firm will engage in pure waste whenever CT > (1-T)f/, where ET = T'(x),/T is the elasticity
of the tax function with respect to core market profits. The logic is similar to that outlined in the
text.
0(1-0 T)]/( T)2 = -1/4T2 < 0, the higher the profits tax, the lower the level of core market
profits at which the firm will have incentives to engage in pure waste. Figure 2-1 illustrates the
increasing divergence between retained and earned profits as core market profits increase.
Eventually, a point is reached where core market profits retained are nonincreasing with respect
to core market profits earned. The firm will have incentives to engage in pure waste for all core
market profit levels beyond this point. The Appendix provides an example of this phenomenon.
It can easily be shown that the firm will engage in pure shared waste whenever e, >
(l-4fT)/tfT > (I- )T)/OT. As might be expected, the conditions under which the firm has
incentives to engage in pure shared waste are more restrictive than the conditions under which the
firm will engage in pure core waste. Moreover, as with CB regulation, it is straightforward to
show that the firm operating under MPC regulation will not engage in pure noncore waste, since
this simply reduces aggregate profits.
Technology Distortions
In this subsection, we turn to the question of whether the firm will choose the efficient
technology and retain incentives to misreport the nature of its costs under MPC regulation.
In the next proposition, we assume shared costs. F, reduce both core and noncore
attributable costs. The efficient level of shared costs, F*, is obtained when the firm invests in
shared costs up to the point where the last dollar invested in shared costs reduces the sum of core
and noncore attributable costs by precisely one dollar. We define F* formally as follows.
Definition 2: F*(yl, Y2) = argmin{F + cl(y1,F) + c2(y2,F)), where c,/iF < 0 and 2ci/F2 > 0, i
F
= 1,2.
Proposition 5: If T > 0 and f -c', the firm's choice of technology is inefficient under MPC
regulation.
Proof: The Lagrangian is given by
(38) 1a = [l-T(x,)][R'(yj) f(y,,y2)F c'(y,,F)] + p:y, [l-f(y,,y2)]F
c2(yF) + 8[y1 yI].
The necessary first-order condition for an interior optimum is given by
(39) -(1-T)(f + c') (1-f) c2 = 0.
Rearranging terms yields
(40) -c cF = 1 T(f + c'), so generally F(.) # F*. M
The efficient choice of F is induced only if T(nt) = 0, V tc, (i.e., pure price-caps) or f =
-cF. Hence, in general, the firm's choice of technology is distorted. It is not difficult to show that
the magnitude of the distortion can be greater under MPC regulation than under CB regulation.'6
Cost Misreporting Distortions
Finally, one of the benefits of PC regulation is that the regulated firm has no incentive
to misrepot the nature of its costs (Braeutigam and Panzar, 1989, p. 388). In particular, it would
not have an incentive to claim costs actually incurred in the noncore market were incurred in the
core market. This is because under PC regulation prices are not raised to cover misreported costs,
as they may be under CB regulation. It is straightforward to show that the firm retains its
incentives to misreport costs under MPC regulation. We record this result in our final proposition.
Proposition 6: In decreasing order of profitability, the profit-maximizing firm under MPC
regulation has incentives to report (i) noncore costs as core costs and (ii) noncore costs
as shared costs.
16 We, like Braeutigam and Panzar (1989), can ask whether the firm will invest efficiently in
cost saving innovation under MPC regulation. In general, it will not. The proofs for MPC
regulation are identical to Braeutigam and Panzar's for CB regulation, again with T replacing X.
23
Proof: When core costs increase by 1, total profits fall by only (1-T) < 1. When shared costs
increase by 1, total profits fall by (l-T)f + (1-f) = (l-Tf) < 1. The result follows from the chain
of inequalities (1-T) < (1-Tf) < 1. U
Conclusion
Although well-known distortions under CB regulation are either reduced or eliminated
entirely under pure PC regulation, a move from CB regulation toward price-cap regulation may
not improve upon CB regulation. This is an important finding for both theoretical and applied
research, as currently these hybrid applications are the rule rather than the exception.
Under MPC regulation, the profit-maximizing firm has incentives to (i) underdiversify in
the case of independent demands, (ii) overdiversify in the case of vertically integrated markets,
(iii) use inefficient technologies, and (iv) misreport costs. Moreover, under MPC regulation, the
firm may have incentives to engage in pure waste if it believes that higher profits may induce the
regulator to recontract. This qualitative distortion does not arise under CB regulation.
This issue of recontracting and the attendant efficiency distortions resulting therefrom is
arguably one of the more serious problems with PC regulation in practice. A key premise
underlying PC regulation is that increased profits for the firm will be viewed by regulators and
their constituency as something other than a failure of regulation itself. If this premise is false,
then regulators will be under constant political pressure to recontract when the firm reports higher
profits. In equilibrium, the firm learns that this is how the game is played and the efficiency gains
from PC regulation in theory may fail to materialize in practice.
T=0
T = 0.5
T = 0.75
0 Earned
7t^ Earned
Figure 2-1: Waste Incentives with Increasing Probability of Recontracting.
CHAPTER 3
WHY LESS MAY BE MORE UNDER PRICE-CAP REGULATION
Introduction
Public utilities in the United States and Europe have traditionally been subject to
rate-of-retur (ROR) regulation. Under this form of regulation, the utility is allowed to earn a
specified return on invested capital and recover all prudently incurred expenses. The efficiency
distortions under ROR regulation are well known and have been analyzed at length in the
literature.' Price-cap (PC) regulation, under which the firm's prices rather than its earnings are
capped, has recently attracted considerable attention by regulated firms, public utility regulators
and the academic community.2 Following the perceived success of PC regulation in early trials
involving British Telecom, the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) adopted this new
form of incentive regulation for AT&T and subsequently for the Regional Bell Operating
Companies.3
Most of the formal literature on incentive regulation has focused on the manner in which
the firm is disciplined under a particular regulatory regime.4 In this paper, we examine incentive
SSee Braeutigam and Panzar (1989) for a comprehensive treatment.
2 Rand Journal of Economics (Autumn 1989) includes a special section on price-cap
regulation. See, in particular, the articles by Beesley and Littlechild (1989) and Schmalensee
(1989). See also Brennan (1989) and Cabral and Riordan (1989).
SSee Federal Communications Commission (1988).
4 See for example Baron (1989), Braeutigam and Panzar (1989), Brennan (1989), Cabral and
Riordan (1989), Caillaud et al. (1988), Sappington and Stiglitz (1987) and Besanko and
Sappington (1986).
26
regulation from a different viewpoint--examining how the firm can discipline the regulator by
choosing a particular form of PC regulation that aligns the regulator's interests with those of the
firm. By effectively reversing the standard principal-agent relationship, the firm may be able to
induce the regulator to choose a higher price or a lower level of competitive entry by adopting
a form of PC regulation that entails sharing profits with consumers. Our major result shows that
if demand is relatively inelastic and the regulator's weight on consumer surplus is not too large,
the firm's profits will be higher under sharing than under pure price-caps. Sharing is thus a
dominant strategy for the firm, so that less really is more.5
In practice there is an important distinction between the regulator's commitment to a
price-cap and the regulator's commitment to a specified market price. As long as the regulator
controls the terms of competitive entry, market price is decreasing with entry and such entry
cannot be contracted upon, the regulator's commitment to a specified price-cap may be
meaningless.6 This is a classic example of incomplete contracting. The regulator must be given
the requisite incentives to limit competitive entry, but such incentives are absent under pure PC
regulation.7
The reason that pure PC regulation is problematic when competitive entry cannot be
contracted upon is that the regulator incurs no cost by adopting procompetitive entry policies since
it does not share in the firm's profits. Under pure PC regulation, the regulator is in some sense
Schmalensee (1989) argues that in many cases, the welfare gains from sharing dominate
those from pure price-caps. This occurs because under sharing, consumers directly benefit from
the cost-reducing efforts of the firm, whereas the firm retains all of the benefits of these efforts
under pure price-caps. This welfare argument is very different from the strategic argument offered
here.
6 The local telephone companies clearly did not believe that a price-cap commitment was
meaningless, as they agreed to significant rate concessions and large-scale unremunerativee)
network modernization in exchange for it.
7 Under pure PC regulation, there is no profit-sharing with regulators (consumers).
27
fully insured against the adverse consequences of procompetitive entry policies. Under a
profit-sharing scheme, the regulator can adopt procompetitive entry policies only at a cost of
forgone shared profits. Consequently, the regulator will generally be induced to adopt a less
aggressive competitive entry policy under PC regulation with sharing than under pure PC
regulation. This is the manner in which sharing rules can discipline the actions of the regulator.
The primary objective of this essay is to show that under quite general conditions, sharing
dominates pure PC regulation in that the firm's profits are higher when profits are shared than
when they are retained by the firm in full. Sharing provides the regulator with a vested interest
in the financial performance of the firm. This is illustrated in Figure 3-1. The firm is able to
exert upstream control over the actions of the regulator by agreeing to share profits with
consumers. It may thus be able to induce the regulator to choose a higher price or a lower level
of competitive entry. What is surprising is that regulated firms are generally opposed to
profit-sharing in practice, perhaps because it is believed that the sharing rule affects only the
distribution of profits but not their absolute level. This sentiment is reflected in a recent filing
by Southwestern Bell Telephone:
Sharing of earnings is inappropriate for any regulatory reform proposal. Sharing
bands and floors continue the disadvantages, for both customer and company, of
rate base rate of return regulation. Consequently, the basic economic
principle of incentive regulation will be subverted if any form of revenue sharing
is incorporated in an incentive regulation plan. The principal operative
force in business, whether it be competitive or regulated, is the quest for profits.
(Southwestern Bell Telephone (1992), Question 18, page 1 of 1)
The irony here is that the regulated firm may object to sharing on grounds that it subverts
economic efficiency, only to discover that sharing leads to higher realized profits.
The analysis proceeds as follows. The elements of the formal model are developed in the
second section. The benchmark results are presented in the third section. In the fourth section,
we present our principal findings. The conclusions are drawn in the fifth section.
28
Elements of the Model
The regulator's objective in this problem is to maximize a weighted average of consumer
surplus and shared profits. Following the work of Posner (1971, 1974), the regulator is able to
tax the profits of the firm and distribute these tax dollars to consumers. Let P denote the
regulator's weight on consumer surplus, and (1-P) is the corresponding weight on shared profits.
The regulator's effective weight on shared profits is (1-a)(1-p), where (1-a) is the regulator's
share of total accounting profits. Through its choice of a, the firm is able to influence the
regulator's relative valuation of consumer surplus. It follows that when the firm chooses pure
price-caps (a = 1), the regulator's objective function is maximized by choosing the lowest price
(highest level of competitive entry) consistent with the firm's willingness to participate. By
choosing a value for a on the interval [0,1), the firm provides the regulator with vested interest
in its financial performance. Under conditions to be described, the firm is able to strategically
exploit this vested interest and realize higher profits as a result.
There are two players in the game to be analyzed: the firm and the regulator. The firm's
realized profits are denoted by R = r^ y(I), where it = q(p,e)p c(q,pl) denotes the firm's
accounting profits. I is the firm's (unobservable) effort level, and W(I) is a monetary measure of
the firm's disutility in expending effort. We maintain the standard assumptions that W(I) is an
increasing, convex function so that y/(I) > 0, "/(I) > 0 and y(0) = 0. We define p to be market
price, e is the level of competitive entry allowed by the regulator,8 Q(p) is market demand, q(p,e)
is the firm's demand, where q(p,0) = Q(p), q, < 0 and q, < 0.9 The condition qe 0 is referred
8 Entry (e) is modeled as a continuous variable because the terms of competitive entry are set
by the regulator. For example, in the telecommunications industry, regulators set the rates that
competitors pay to interconnect with the incumbent's network. Hence, low (high) interconnection
charges may be interpreted as liberal (conservative) competitive entry policies.
9 The subscripts denote partial derivatives.
29
to as the demand dissipation effect. Increased entry reduces the demand base for the regulated
incumbent firm, ceteris paribus. The own price elasticity of demand is defined by e, = -qp(p/q).
The firm's cost function is C(q,pl) = c(q,pl) + v(pI), where c, > 0, c, < 0 and cu > 0. We assume
further that c,(q,I) 1,, = -0 and ci(q,o) = 0 V q. The variable p is a binary parameter that takes
on the value 0 or 1.10 The price-cap set by the regulator is given by p. With consumer surplus
defined by S(p) = Q(z)dz, the regulator's measure of consumer welfare is We(p) = PS(p) +
p
(l-P)(l-a)N.
The firm's general problem is to
(0) Maximize R" = a^(p,eI) (I),
{a,e.I,p}
subject to:
(1) p p,
(2) aE [0,1], and
(3) e e argmax [W = p fQ(z)dz + (1-P)(1-a)o (p,e',I)
e P
Benchmark Solutions
The First-Best Case
We begin by establishing the benchmark first-best case. In this case, the firm's effort
choice is publicly observed and entry can be contracted upon. Formally, the regulator's choice
variables are a, e, p, I. The regulator's problem is to
(4) Maximize W' = pS + (l-P)(l-o)A(p,e,I),
{a,e,p,I}
10 Except where specifically noted, p = 1.
subject to:
(5) r = aor^(p.e,l) y(I) 2 0, and
(6) aE [0,1].
where constraint (5) ensures that the incumbent firm is willing to operate in the regulated
environment, and constraint (6) places bounds on feasible profit-sharing arrangements.
To begin, it is useful to characterize the optimal sharing rule.
Proposition 1: In the first-best case,
(i) if p3 ['A, ], then a* = 1;
(ii) if oa* < 1. then p e [0,2);
(iii) if p = 0. then a* < 1: and
(iv) R= 0.
Proof:
Proof of (i) and (ii): Substituting for S and rA(p,e,I), the Lagrangian is given by
(7) = P JQ(z)dz + (1-P)(l-c)[q(pe)p c(q,I)]
p
+ (a[q(p,e)p c(q,l)] N(I)] + [1-a],
where X and 5 are the Lagrange multipliers associated with (5) and (6), respectively. Maximizing
with respect to a yields
(8) [X-(l-P)][q(p,e)p c(q,I)] < 0 and ca[ = 0.
If S < 0, then a = 0 and the participation constraint is violated. If a > 0, equation (8) holds
as an equality, or
(8') [t-(1-P)][q(p,e)p-c(q,I)] 0 = 0.
It is straightforward to show that when the participation constraint binds, X > max [P3,1-], and
in the case of perfectly inelastic demand, X = max [(,1-S]. Suppose that max [[P1-3] = P. From
31
(8'), the first term is positive, which for an interior solution implies that 4 > 0 and a* = 1. This
proves (i). The contrapositive of (i) yields (ii). U
Proof of (iii): Suppose that ca* = 1 when P = 0. This implies that WC = 0. But if ca*
< 1, then W > 0 V I > 0 contradicting a* = 1 as an optimum. M
Proof of (iv): From (8'), if p < 1 and X = 0, we have a contradiction and R = 0. If p
= 1, then 0 > 0 which implies that X > 0 and R = 0. U
Examining the limit points for P provides some useful intuition. When P = 1, the
regulator values only consumer surplus. Since the regulator does not value shared profits (p = 1),
it provides the firm with the full share of profits. As a result, the regulator can set a relatively
low price, thus maximizing consumer surplus, while still inducing the firm to participate.
When P = 0, the regulator values only shared profits. Here, the regulator will set a
profit-maximizing price and set a at a level just sufficient to induce the firm to participate
(assuming, of course, that maximal profit is sufficiently large). This implies that the profit share
constraint does not bind.
For interior values of p, the logic is similar. For 1p (1-P), pure price-caps (a* = 1) are
optimal since the regulator can choose a price that ensures consumer surplus exceeds shared
profits. By the same reasoning, a necessary condition for sharing to be optimal (a* < 1) is that
P < (1-0). Hence, when a sharing rule is observed, it can be inferred that P < 12.
We now characterize the optimal choice of p, e and I.
Proposition 2: In the first-best case,
(i) the optimal price is decreasing with P for P sufficiently small;
(ii) e* = 0: the regulator precludes competitive entry if q,(.) < 0;11 and
It is straightforward to show that when q, = 0, price (p) and competitive entry (e) are
identical policy instruments.
32
(iii) -c, = y'(I): the efficient level of effort is achieved.
Proof:
Proof of (i):
(9) S, = -pQ(p) + (l-p)(l-ac)[q(p,e)p + q(p,e) cqqp(p,e)]
+ 4(a[qp(p,e)p + q(p,e) cqqp(p,e)l] < 0 and p[S,] = 0.
Dividing equation (A3) through by q(p,e) and rearranging terms yields
(10) -py + [(1-p)(1-a) + al][(qp/q)p + 1 c,(q,/q)] = 0,
where y = Q(p)/q(p,e) > 1. Note that p > 0 since with p = 0, r < 0 and the participation
constraint is violated. Hence the only feasible solution is an interior one. Substituting for ep in
(10) yields
(11) -py + [(l-P)(1-a) + O] [1 e[(p-c,)/p] = 0.
Rearranging terms yields
(12) 1 e,[(p-c,)/p] = pY/[(l-P)(1-y) + cl],
(12') -ep[(p-c,)/p] = py/[(1-P)(1-y) + cA] 1, and
(12") (p-c,)/p = (l-P)(-cc) + aX py1/[(l-p)(l-a) + aX] [I/e .
Now let p = 0 so that the regulator values only shared profits. By previous arguments, we know
that X = (1-P). Note that this implies from (12") that P < Under these conditions. (12")
becomes
(13) p-c/p = l/ep,
which is the standard Lemer index. The regulator behaves as a profit-maximizing monopolist
We know that for P sufficiently small, X = (1-p). The general expression for the optimal
pricing rule under these conditions is given by
(14) p-c/p = [(1-p p )/(1-)][l/ep].
Rearranging terms and simplifying yields
(15) p-q/p = [1- P3y/(l-P)1[1/E].
Holding e, fixed,
(16) '* /ap p-cq/p = l(-y(l-p)-Py)/(1-P)2][1/ep] = -y/(l-p)2(1/e) < 0. U
Proof of (ii):
(17) S- = -Pepq(p) + (l-p)(l-a)[qppp + q+p + Peq(p) c,[qpe + qj]
+ 4[lqppp + qeP + Pq c[qppe + qj,]] 0; and e[S] = 0.
Dividing equation (17) through by p, < 0 and rearranging provides
(18) -PQ(p) + (l-p)(1-oa)[qp + q cq,] + La[(qp + q(p) cqp]
+ [(1-P)(1-a) + Xk][p-cql[qjp,] 0.
The first line of equation (18) is identical to equation (9), which is identically zero at an interior
optimum. The second line of (18) is strictly positive if p > Cq (required for satisfaction of the
participation constraint) by (i) demand dissipation (q, < 0) and (ii) pe < 0. This implies that
SPe < 0, which, by complementary slackness, requires that e* = 0. U
Proof of (iii):
(19) A, = -(1-p)(1-a)c, + k[-acI V(I)1 = 0.
A comer solution is ruled out by the assumed properties of the cost function. For p sufficiently
small, X = (1-P) and (19) reduces to
(20) -c, = '(I).
For 1 = 1, (19) reduces to
(21) hX[-c,] = X/(I).
By previous arguments, the profit-share constraint binds at P = 1 which implies that a = 1.
Hence, again
(22) -c, = V'(I),
34
and the efficient level of investment in effort is achieved. Recognize from the first-order
condition on a that if X = (1-P3), = 0 and a <- 1; and if X # (1-p), 4 > 0 and a = 1. This
proves that the coefficients on -c, and W(I) in (19) are equal V P. U
As p increases from 0, the regulator increases his valuation of consumer surplus and
decreases his valuation of shared profits. Hence, the regulator reduces price below the
profit-maximizing level, which simultaneously lowers profits and increases consumer surplus.
The regulator can set price directly since p is a choice variable, or choose a positive level
of entry (e) in order to bring about the desired market price indirectly. But the latter generates
a negative externality for the regulator in the form of the demand dissipation effect (qe < 0). By
assumption, the regulator can tax the incumbent but not the entrant(s). Consequently, the use of
e rather than p reduces the demand base upon which the regulator earns shared profits (tax
revenues). Hence, relative to price (p), entry (e) is a strictly inferior policy instrument. It follows
that as long as the regulator can choose p, he will set e* = 0.
The Second-Best Case
We now investigate the second-best case in which I is not observed by the regulator.12
This case entails perfect commitment by the regulator over entry (e). Formally, the regulator's
choice variables are e, a and p (or p), while the firm chooses I.13 The regulator's problem is to
12 The second-best problem is nontrivial here because of the presumed policy instruments.
If lump-sum, unbounded penalties could be imposed, and price could be conditioned on observed
cost, the regulator could make the firm deliver the desired I by imposing a large penalty on the
firm if dictated cost levels are not achieved.
13 The firm chooses effort, I, to maximize realized profits, or
(0) I e argmax [a[q(p,e)p c(q,1)] x(I].
Differentiating the first-order condition with respect to price, p, yields
(1) dl/dp = cq,/[--aCn W"(I)] < 0,
as c, < 0, qp 0 and the denominator is negative since ~' > 0 and c. > 0. The result that effort
is decreasing (increasing) in price (output) has been termed the "Arrow Effect" following Arrow
(1962).
35
(23) Maximize WC = PS + (l-p)( 1-a)XA(.)
({ ,p,e,I)
subject to:
(24) rt = xAA(.) W(I) 2 0,
(25) aE [0,1], and
(26) I e argmax [oat(.) y(')].
I'
The fact that the firm does not choose p in the second-best problem stems from the fact
that when the price-cap constraint binds, the regulator's ability to set p is de facto ability to set
p.
Lemma 1: The price-cap constraint binds at the solution to the general second-best problem.
Proof: It suffices to show that p > p, where p is the firm's optimal price and p is the optimal
price-cap set by the regulator. The optimal choice of price for the regulator and the firm are given
by
(27) p e argmax [(l-a)(l-)[q(p',e)p'-c(q,I)]], and
p'
(28) p e argmax [a[q(p',e)p'-c(q,I)] y(I)].
p'
The corresponding first-order condition for (27) is given by
(29) [qpp + q cq, c,(dI/dp)] = 0.
Rearranging terms and substituting for e, yields
(30) (p-c,)/p = (1 (c/q)(dl/dp)][l/ep].
The corresponding first-order condition for (28) is given by
(31) a[qpp + q cqC-c,(dI/dp)] W'(I)(dl/dp) = 0.
Recognize that dl/dp = 0 by the Envelope Theorem, so that (31) reduces to
(32) (p-Cq)/p = 1/ep.
It can be shown that dl/dp < 0, and c, < 0 by the properties of the firm's cost function.
Comparing (30) and (32), it follows that p > p. U
We now proceed to characterize the optimal sharing rule (a).
Proposition 3: In the second-best case,
(i) if p= 1, then a = 1; and
(ii) if = 0, then a < 1.
If demand is perfectly price-inelastic then.
(iii) if E [A ]then a = 1:
(iv) if a < 1, then p e [0, 1/); and
(v) XR 2 0.
Proof: Using the first-order approach to the firm's choice of effort, I, the Lagrangian is given
by
(33) S = p Q(z)dz + (1-p)(1-a)[q(p,e)p c(q,I)]
p
+ a[q(p,e)p c(q,I)] y(I)] + [-ac(, V(I)] + [1l-a].
Consolidating terms and rewriting the Lagrangian, we obtain
(34) 9 = p JQ(z)dz + [(1-)(1-a) + aXl[q(p,e)p c(q,I)] Xy(I)
p
+ 0[-ac, y'(I)] + [1-a].
(35) S. = [-(l-P)+X][q(p,e)p-c(q,I)]+[(1-p)(1-a)+aXl[-c,(dI/da)]
'/(I)(dI/da) + 0[-c, acc(dl/da) w"(I)(dlda)l < 0; a(g] = 0.
Rewriting equation (35)
(35') [X-(l-P)][q(p,e)p c(q,I)] + [(1-p)(l-a)j][-c(dI/da)] + X[-ac, I'(I)](dI/da)
+ -[-c, acn(dl/da) y~(I)(dl/da)] = 0.
37
The expression inside the brackets of the third term is precisely the incentive compatibility
constraint. Hence, if 0 > 0, the third term vanishes, and if 0 = 0, the fourth term vanishes. The
term inside the brackets of the fourth term is the first partial of the optimal level of effort (I) with
respect to a. It can be shown that this expression has a positive sign. Hence, if X > 0, the first
four terms of (35') are all nonnegative and at least one is strictly positive for p e [0,1]. This
implies that t > 0 and a = 1 V p. M
Proof of (i): Suppose that p = 1. The first three terms in (35') are nonnegative and the
fourth term is strictly positive. This implies that t > 0 and a = 1. U
Proof of (ii): We claim that for P sufficiently small, the condition, a = 1, cannot hold
at an optimum. Suppose that p = 0 so that the regulator places a weight of unity on shared
profits. If 4 > 0 at P = 0, then the regulator's pay-off is identically zero since (l-p)(1-oa)xr =
(1-0)(1-1)"A = 0. We claim that this is an optimum in order to arrive at a contradiction. Suppose
that a < 1. From (35), an interior solution requires that the first term be strictly negative =- X =
0. But if X = 0, then 7 > 0 = iA > 0 V I> 0. Since a < 1, l-a > 0 which implies the
regulator's pay-off is (l-ao)(l-p)lA = (l-a)(1)cA > 0 which contradicts > 0, a = 1 as an
optimum. Hence, 4 = 0 and a < 1. U
Proof of (iii) and (iv):
(36) p = -PQ(p) + [(l-P)(1-a) + aX][q(p)p + q cqqp c,(dl/dp)]
-Xl (I)(dl/dp) + 0[-aclc V"(I)][dI/dp] + #[-ac ,qp] = 0,
assuming an interior solution. Rearranging terms,
(36') -pQ(p) + [(l-P)(1-a) + aX][qp(p-c,) + q] + [(l-p)(1-a)(-c,)j[dI/dp]
+ X[-act V'(I)][dl/dp] + -[-acn ~"(I)][dI/dp] #[aclq, = 0.
The fourth term in (36') vanishes if 0 > 0. Hence,
(37) -PQ(p) + [(1-P)(1-a) + aXl[qp(p-cq) + q] + [(l-p)(1-a)(-c,)l[dl/dp]
38
+ 0[-aci V"(I)][dI/dp] + 0[-aciql = 0.
We assert for now (and subsequently prove) that e = 0 at an optimum so that Q(p) = q(p,O).
Dividing equation (37) through by q(p), we obtain
(38) -p+[(l-p)(1-a) + al][(qp/q)(p-cq) + l]+[(1l-)(1-a)(-c,)][(dI/dp)( /q)]
+ 0[-accn W"(I)][(dI/dp)(1/q)] + 0[-aclq][q/q] = 0.
Substituting for e, into (38), we obtain
(39) -P+[(l-P)(1-a) + oX][l e,(p-c)/p] + [(l-p)(l-a)(-c,)][(dI/dp)(l/q)]
+ [--acn "'(I)][(dI/dp)(l/q)] + Oac,q(e/p) = 0.
Let demand become perfectly inelastic so that e, = 0. It can be shown that dI/dp = 0 when e,
= 0. Equation (39) thus reduces to
(40) -P + [(l-p)(1-a) + oa] = 0.
From previous analysis, X > 0 = a = 1, so that (40) reduces to
(41) -P + X = 0.
Since X = maxIp,l-p], (41) = > 2 V2. U
Proof of (iv): If a < 1, then X = 0 and (40) reduces to
(42) -P + (1-P)(1-a) = 0.
Since a E (0,1], satisfaction of (42) requires that P < /2. U
Proof of (v): This follows directly from the proofs for (iii) and (iv) above. U
The interpretation of these results is similar to those discussed in the first-best case. Here,
the regulator must defer the choice of effort to the firm. This allows for the possibility that
realized profits are positive. In the case of perfectly inelastic demand, the (indeterminant) effort
effects disappear and the results are identical to the first-best case.
Proposition 4. In the second-best case,
(i) e = 0 if q, < 0;
(ii) -c, = -'(I), if a = 1; and
(iii) -c, > y/(I), if oa < 1.
Proof: The proof for (i) is similar in technique, though considerably longer and more tedious,
to the first-best result in proposition 2 part (ii) and is therefore omitted. For the proofs of (ii) and
(iii), recognize that -c, = y'(I) when a = 1, -c, > W'(I) when a < 1 and appeal to proposition 3.
The interpretation here is similar to that provided for the first-best case. If the regulator
can set price directly, it is inefficient to employ competitive entry in order to set price indirectly.
The efficient level of effort is obtained only if a = 1, otherwise, the firm underinvests in
cost-reducing effort.
Principal Findings
In the general third-best problem, the firm chooses a and I, and the regulator chooses p
(and e). The firm is the Stackelberg leader in this problem in the sense that the regulator reacts
to the firm's choice of sharing rule (a) with a choice of price (p).'4 The firm anticipates the
reaction of the regulator. Hence, in order to induce the regulator to choose a higher price, or to
adopt a more conservative entry policy, the firm must provide the regulator with a vested interest
in its financial performance. The firm provides such a vested interest by sharing its profits. The
firm's problem is to
(43) Maximize VR = a[q(p,e)p(e) c(q,I)I f(I),
{a,I,e}
subject to:
14 In the telecommunications industry, it is common for the firm to propose a particular
regulatory regime (i.e., choice of sharing rule, a). Once the regulatory regime is in place, the
regulator adopts a given competitive entry policy (e). The timing in the third-best case thus
conforms with institutional reality.
(44) p(e) p,
(45) ae [0,1], and
(46) e E argmax [ f Q(z)dz + [(l-p)(l-a)][q(p,e')p(e')-c(q,I)],
e
(47) subject to: a(q(p,e')p(e')-c(q,I)] y(I) 2 0.
A number of preliminary observations are in order with regard to the structure of this
problem. First, the functional dependence of p on e indicates that in this model the regulator may
affect price only indirectly through e. Second, it is necessary to subconstrain the incentive
compatibility constraint (46), which defines the regulator's entry decision, to preclude the regulator
from adopting competitive entry policies that cause the regulated firm to shut down. Third, the
price-cap, p, is exogenous. This treatment abstracts from the effect that more generous
profit-sharing might have on the price-cap, thereby focusing on the direct effect of profit-sharing
on entry policy. Finally, it is necessary to impose the condition that p(d) < p for some e, so that
it is within the regulator's control to satisfy the price-cap constraint. This formulation of the
firm's problem clearly reveals the implicit recontracting problems associated with a price-cap
regulatory regime when the regulator controls the terms of competitive entry.
To begin to characterize the solution to this problem, we abstract from the demand
dissipation effect (by setting q, = 0) and the firm's effort choice (so that p = 0, ensuring I = 0).
In this Third-Best Problem-1, the firm's problem is to
(48) Maximize R = a[q(p)p-c(q)],
{ac,p}
subject to:
(49) ae [0,1], and
(50) p e argmax [ Q(z)dz + [(l-1)(1-a)[q(p')p'-c(q)]].
p' P'
(51) subject to: a[q(p')p'-c(q)] 2 0.
The following lemma allows us to identify conditions under which the firm's choice of
sharing rule influences the regulator's choice of price.
Lemma 2. If We(p) is strictly concave and demand is inelastic (e, < 1), then p, < 0.
Proof: The regulator chooses the optimal price according to
(52) p argmax [ Q (z)dz + [(1-p)(l-a)[)[q(p')p'-c(q)]].
p' P
Differentiating (52) with respect to p, we obtain
(53) -pQ(p) + [(1-P)(l-()][[q(p-cq) + q] = 0.
An interior solution requires that
(54) a < 1-[3/[1-1][l-,p(p-c,)/p]].
Concavity of We(p) requires that
(55) a < 1- p/[(qp,/q)(p-Cq) + (1-cqq,)] + l][(l-p)].
In the case of linear demand and constant marginal cost of production, q,, = cqq = 0. equation (55)
reduces to
(56) a < -p/2(1-p).
It is straightforward to show that
(56') a < 1-[ 1/[l-p1][l-e(p-c,)/p]] < 1-P/2(1-0) = (2-30)/(1-p),
so that W(p) admits an interior solution implies WC(p) is strictly concave. Differentiating (53),
the regulator's optimal choice of price, with respect to a, we obtain
42
(57) -pq(p)p, (1-P)[qp(p-c,) + q] + [(1-P)(l-a)][qpppa(p-c,)]
+ qp(pa Cqqqp.)] = 0.
Solving equation (57) for p,, we obtain
(57') p. =[(1-P)][qp(p-cq)+ql/ [-pq +[(1-P)(l-a)]Iqpp(p-c,)+qp(l-cqqqp)+ql]].
The denominator on the right-hand side of (57') is negative if Wt(p) is concave. The numerator
on the right-hand side of (57') is positive if
(58) qp(p-c,) + q > 0.
Dividing (58) through by q, we obtain
(59) (q/q)(p-Cq) + 1 > 0.
Substituting for rp in (59) we obtain
(59') 1 Ep(p-cq )/p > 0, or
(59") Ep(p-Cq )/p < 1.
A sufficient condition for (59") to be satisfied is that ep < 1, or demand be price-inelastic.
It follows then that if demand is inelastic (e, < 1) and We(p) is concave, then
(60) p, < 0. U
Here, inelastic demand is necessary to ensure that shared profits are strictly increasing with market
price.
The following lemma establishes the firm's benchmark level of profits under pure PC
regulation.
Lemma 3: In the Third-Best Problem-I, the firm earns zero realized profits under pure price-caps
(a = 1).
Proof: The Lagrangian for the regulator's subconstrained optimization problem is
(61) S = p fQ(z)dz + [(l-P)(l-a)l[q(p)p-c(q)] + 4a[q(p)p-c(q)l].
p
Consolidating terms, we obtain
(62) a = p3 Q(z)dz + [(l-p)(l-a)+akl[q(p)p-c(q)].
p
Imposing the pure price-cap (a = 1) condition,
(63) E = [3 fQ(z)dz + X[q(p)p-c(q)]].
p
Differentiating (63) with respect to price, we obtain
(64)) -pq(p) + X[qp(p-Cq) + q] = 0.
Since p > 0 (by assumption) and q(p) > 0, a necessary condition for an interior optimum is that
X > 0 which implies that rR = 0, or the firm earns precisely zero realized profits. *
Lemma 3 establishes that the regulator will set a price under pure PC regulation that just
prevents shutdown of the firm. When the firm chooses pure PC regulation (a( = 1), it severs the
regulator's vested interest in its financial performance.
Having established that the firm can do no better than break even under pure price-caps
(a = 1), we now turn to the question of whether the firm can earn strictly positive realized profits
under profit-sharing (0 < a < 1).
Proposition 5: If qp = cqq = 0 and P/1-P < 1 [2ep/(l+e-)], there exists an a E (0,1) such that
tR > 0 in the solution to the Third-Best Problem-I.
Proof: Note that p = Cq for a = 1 and appeal to the proof of proposition 6. M
Proposition 5 establishes conditions under which the firm can realize higher profits under
profit-sharing than under pure price-caps. Figure 3-2 illustrates this result. For a E (0,a*), the
regulator will choose a price greater than marginal cost when the firm agrees to share profits with
consumers. The result is strictly positive realized profits for the firm. Here, a "greed strategy"
(i.e., zero sharing) is self-defeating in the sense that the firm succeeds only in retaining one
44
hundred percent of zero profits.'5 This result illustrates the recontracting problem with PC
regulation. When entry cannot be contracted upon (and qe = 0), entry (e) and price (p) are
identical policy instruments. Hence, in choosing o, the firm is affecting the absolute level of
profits as well as its distribution. Setting p = 0 suppresses the firm's choice of effort in this
problem, which avoids the indeterminacy that arises when effort affects variable costs.
We turn next to analysis of the third-best problem in which the firm chooses the level of
effort (I) so that p = 1. In this formulation of the problem, we assume that effort affects the fixed
costs of production, but not variable costs, so that the firm's (observed) cost function is of the
form C(q,I) = F(I) + c(q), where F(I) denotes fixed costs with F, < 0 and Fu > 0. In addition, we
assume an interior level of effort arises, as will be the case, for example, if Fi(q,I)l-,, = -o and
FI(q,o) = 0 V q.
We refer to this problem as the Third-Best Problem-II:
(65) Maximize xR = ([q(p)p-C(q,I)] x(I),
{ a,p,I)
subject to:
(66) as [0,1], and
(67) p e argmax [ Q Q(z)dz + [(l-P)(I-o)l[q(p')p'-C(q,l)],
p p,
(68) subject to: a[q(p')p'-C(q,I)] i(I) > 0.
We begin again by examining how the regulator's optimal choice of price, p, varies with
the firm's choice of sharing rule, a.
Lemma 4: If We(p) is strictly concave and demand is inelastic, then p, < 0 in the Third-Best
Problem-II.
15 It is important to emphasize here that the firm does not share in order to increase the price-
cap, as this is fixed. The firm shares in order to discipline the actions of the regulator (i.e., to
discourage adoption of liberal entry policies).
45
Proof: The first-order approach to the regulator's optimal choice of price yields
(69) -pQ(p) + (l-p)(1-a)I[qp(p-c,) + q F,(dl/dp)] = 0,
where the participation constraint is initially omitted. It can readily be shown that dl/dp = 0 since
c,(q) = 0 so that (69) can be written as
(70) -pq(p) + [(l-p)(1-ao)][qp(p-c,) + q] = 0,
which is identical to (53) in the proof of lemma 2. The remainder of the proof is identical to that
provided in lemma 2 and is therefore omitted. U
Lemma 5: In the Third-Best Problem-1, the firm earns zero realized profits under pure
price-caps (a = 1), and so sharing rules (0 < a < 1) weakly dominate pure price-caps (a
= 1).
Proof: Recognizing that dI/dp = 0, the first part of the proof is identical to that provided for
lemma 3 and is therefore omitted. If the participation constraint binds, then rR = 0. If the
participation constraint does not bind then R 2 0. U
We proceed now to determine the conditions under which the firm can realize strictly
higher profits under sharing than under pure price-caps. Our main finding is stated formally in
the next proposition.
Proposition 6: If qp = Cqq = 0 and P/[1-P] < (Ep-1)2[ l-e(p-Cq)/p]/[(l+e2)], there exists an a E
(0,1) such that it > 0 in the solution to the Third-Best Problem-lI.
Proof:
(71) dnR = [q(p)p-F(I)-c(q)-aF,(dI/da)-V(I)(dI/da)]da
+ a[4q(p-cq) + q F(dl/dp)] V(I)(dl/dp)] dp = 0.
Recall that dI/da = 0 by the Envelope Theorem and dI/dp = 0 so that (71) reduces to
(72) dnR/dp = [q(p)p F(I) c(q)]do/dp + t[qp(p-cq) + q].
Hence, the gradient of the firm's iso-profit locus is
46
(73) dp/daxlo, = p, = -[q(p)p-F(I) -c(q)]/a[qp(p-c,) + q(p)] < 0.
See Figure 3-3. Let e(a) be the regulated price such that, given a, ie = 0.
The regulator's optimal choice of price varies with a in the unconstrained case according
to
(74) p* =[(1-P)][qp(p-Cq)+ql/ [-pq~+[(l1-)(1X-a)l[qpp(p-c)+qp(1-cqp)+q]].
We note that p* < 0 if demand is inelastic and the concavity condition is satisfied. Let p*(a)
define the regulator's optimal (unconstrained) choice of price conditioned on the firm's choice of
ca. Let p(cx) define the effective price set by the regulator for each choice of at by the firm.
It follows that
(75) p(cx) = max{p(a),p*((a)).
The reasoning is as follows. If the regulator sets p(ca) < p(ax), the firm's participation constraint
is violated. Hence, price can never be set less than pi(a). If p*(cx) > P_(x). We is higher at p*(xa)
than it is at Q(xa). But if p*(a) > E(a), then rR > 0 and X = 0.
We derive conditions for p*(a) > p(a), proceeding as follows:
(1) Observe that p(ca) > Q(a).
(2) Determine the conditions under which Ip*l > IpI.
(3) Determine if the conditions in (2) hold on a nondegenerate interval.
(4) Conclude that 3 at e (0,1) for which p*(ca) > O(a) = x > 0 = sharing dominates pure
price-caps.
In the case of linear demand and constant marginal cost of production, qp = Cqq = 0.
Equation (74) reduces to
(76) p* = [(l-p)][qp(p-Cq) + q]/[-pq, + 2(1-P)(l-a)qp],
and recall that
(77) p, = -[q(p)p-F(I)-c(q)]/ac[qp(p-c,) + q(p)] < 0.
Let
(78) P. = -[q(p)pj/caqp(p-cq) + q(p) < 0.
Recognize now that l l > IIl, since F(I) + c(q) > 0. Dividing equation (78) through by q, we
obtain
(79) In = -p/al[(q/q)(p-cq)+l].
Upon substitution of ep,
(80) t = -p/a l-ep(p-Cq)/pl.
Dividing equation (80) through by q,
(81) p* = [[(l-p)][(qp/q)(p-c,)+ll][2(1-P)(1-a)-p][(qp/q)].
Upon substitution of ep,
(82) p* = -[(1-j1)][1-e(p-Cq)/p]/[2(1-P)(1-a)-p][e/p].
Multiplying through by p,
(83) p* = -[(l-P)][p-e(p-c,)]/[2(l-P)(1-a)-1P]p.
The relevant comparison is between equations (80) and (83). We explore sufficient conditions
for Ip*l > I1al, or
(84) [(1-P)][p-e,(p-cq)J/[2(1-p)(1-ax)-p3]e > p/a[l-e,(p-Cq)/p].
Multiplying the numerator and denominator on the right-hand side by p,
(85) [(1-P)][p-e,(p-c,)]/[2(1-p)(1-a)-p]e, > p2/aop-p,(p-c,)],
(86) oa[(l-3)][p-ep(p-c,)12 > p-[2(1-PI)(1-c)-P3e,,
(87) ca[(l-P)][1-ep(p-c)/p]2 > [2(1-p)(1-ao)-p]ep,
(88) a[l-ep(p-cq)/p] > 2(1-a)ep 2[(1-P)(l-a)-3]ep,
(89) t[l-eP(p-cq)/p]2 > 2(1-a)ep, and
(90) a[l-ep(p-c,)/p]2 > a(l-e)2 > 2(1-o)ep,
48
since (p-Cq)/p < 1. Expanding the middle term in (90),
(91) a(l-2Ep+ EC) > 2(1-a)ep,
(92) c(l-2c;+ ep)-2e,+2ae,> 0, and
(93) oa(l+e2)-2Ep> 0.
Solving (93) for cc,
(94) a > 2E,/(1+e).
Let c = 2e,/(l+Ep). By lemma 2, Wc(p) admits an interior solution when
(95) a< 1-[p/[l1-il[1-e,(p-c,)/p].
Let a = l-[p/[l-p][l-,p(p-cq)/pl] Hence, if the exogenous two-tuple (P,ep) defines a
nondegenerate interval such that a < ., 3 ca = ( a) such that Ipil > IgI, = p*(a) > I2(o) c
S> 0. It follows that the firm earns higher profits under sharing (0 < a < 1) than under pure
price-caps (a = 1). U
Figure 3-4 illustrates the relationship between the gradient of the iso-profit locus (p) and
the gradient of price along the iso-welfare locus (p*). If x < a, there exists a sharing rule (0 <
a < 1) for which p* diverges from p, and the firm earns strictly positive realized profits. U
The cost incurred by the regulator when he raises price (reducing consumer surplus) is
increasing in both 3 and Ep. Hence, if demand is relatively inelastic and the regulator's weight
on consumer surplus is not too large, the firm's profits will be higher under sharing than under
pure price-caps. Figure 3-5 illustrates the values of P and rp for which profit-sharing leads to
strictly positive realized profits for the firm.
Corollary to Proposition 6: For p = e, = 0, the firm earns strictly positive realized profits
V ae (0,1).
Proof: Appeal to the proof of proposition 6, and note that p = Ep = 0 = ( ) = (0,1).
49
Conclusion
The focus of the incentive regulation literature has been on how best to discipline the
regulated firm. Here, we have examined how the firm's choice of sharing rule can serve to
discipline the regulator's choice of price or competitive entry. This led to our major result that
if demand is relatively inelastic and the regulator's weight on consumer surplus is not too large,
the firm's profits will be higher under sharing than under pure price-caps. Hence, the finding that
sharing is a dominant strategy for the firm, or less is more.
The fact that regulated firms consider sharing rules a capricious repatriation of earnings
suggests that the strategic implications of sharing are not well understood. There is a tendency
for the firm to confuse the regulator's commitment not to lower the price-cap with the regulator's
commitment not to lower market price. Yet, if the regulator controls the terms of competitive
entry and competition is effective in reducing market price, the price-cap commitment is de facto
no commitment at all. In fact, a price-cap commitment may be worse than no commitment at all
because the regulator is forced to lower price indirectly with an inferior policy instrument (i.e.,
competitive entry). Paradoxically, the regulator's willingness to honor the price-cap commitment
can be harmful to the firm.
Regulatory
P A
A
P Consumer
expenditures
profit-sharing
Figure 3-1: Profit-Sharing as a Means to Exert Upstream Control.
(P = Principal, A = Agent)
Public
Utility
Authority
............ ...........
-C
Figure 3-2: Feasible Values of ao for p, < 0.
Figure 3-3: Firm's Iso-Profit Loci.
P
p(1
0
SR> 0
1
R
no=
1 a
Pa
XR> 0
P (
Pa
a a 1 a
Figure 3-4: Gradient Comparison of p* and p.
p(1)
0
R
7C =0
1
0
Figure 3-5: Feasible Region for (P. c,) that Define Nondegenerate
Intervals for (a, c).
CHAPTER 4
DESIGNING CARRIER OF LAST RESORT OBLIGATIONS
Introduction
The advent of competition in regulated industries, such as telephone, electric power and
natural gas, has caused economists to study the effects of asymmetric regulation on social
welfare.' This research has examined the effect of constraining the (regulated) incumbent firm
to honor historical public utility obligations, while allowing competitive entry. These historical
obligations generally take the form of broadly averaged service rates, extensive tariff review
processes in formal regulatory proceedings and carrier of last resort (COLR) obligations. It is the
COLR obligation that is the focus of the formal analysis here.
The COLR obligation dates back to the Railway Act of 1920 which prohibited railroads
from abandoning certain routes absent the issuance of a certificate of convenience and necessity
from the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC). The ICC was generally reluctant to issue such
certificates if consumers were harmed by such abandonment, even when the continuation of
service proved financially burdensome to the railroads.2
In the case of traditional public utility services, the COLR obligation essentially charges
the incumbent firm with responsibility for standing by with facilities in place to serve consumers
on demand, including customers of competitors. The historical origins of this obligation are
significant because it is the asymmetry of this obligation that is the source of the market
1 See for example Haring (1984) and Weisman (1989a).
2 See Goldberg (1979) p. 150 and notes 18-20 and Keeler (1983) pp. 38-39.
55
56
distortion. A public utility with a franchised right to serve a certificated geographic area maintains
a responsibility to serve all consumers on demand. Yet, at least historically, there was a
corresponding obligation on the part of consumers to be served by this public utility. As Victor
Goldberg (1976) has argued, this form of administrative contract relied upon a form of reciprocity
(symmetrical entitlements) which balanced the utilities' obligation to serve with the consumers'
obligation to be served.3 This balance evolved over time as a fundamental tenet of the regulatory
compact. Regulators have been reluctant to relieve the incumbent of its COLR obligation in the
face of competitive entry over concern that consumers could be deprived of access to essential
services.4
Alfred Kahn (1971) first recognized that a nondiscriminatory COLR obligation might well
handicap the incumbent firm. The context was MCI's entry into the long-distance telephone
market in competition with AT&T. The exact citation is revealing.
It is this problem that is the most troublesome aspect of the MCI case and others
like it. If such ventures are economically feasible only on the assumption that
when they break down or become congested subscribers may shift over to the
Bell System for the duration of the emergency, they are indeed supplying an only
partial service. If the common carrier is obliged to stand ready to serve and must
carry the burden of excess capacity required to meet that obligation, it would
seem that its average total costs would necessarily be higher than those of a
private shipper or cream-skimming competitor who has no such obligation: the
latter can construct capacity merely sufficient for operation at 100 percent load
factors, with the expectation that it or its customers can turn to the common
carriers in case of need. (Kahn, 1971, p. 238)
Weisman (1989b, p. 353) makes a similar observation with regard to more recent
competitive entry in carrier access markets.5 An interesting question for analysis concerns
3 See Goldberg (1976, 1979) and Weisman (1989a).
4 For a case study of this phenomenon, see Weisman (1989c).
5 An alternative viewpoint is offered by a recent competitive entrant in the carrier access
market. See Metropolitan Fiber Systems (1989, pp. 67-70). The carrier access market in the
telephone industry refers generically to the local access component of both the originating and
57
whether an entrant will choose to strategically exploit the incumbent's COLR obligation by
underinvesting or overinvesting in reliability.6
The COLR issue per se has received little attention in the formal economic literature.
Weisman (1988) discusses the distortions caused by the utilities' COLR obligation and
recommends default capacity tariffs as a possible solution. Under this proposal, the subscriber
purchases service under a two-part tariff. The first part of the tariff is a capacity charge that
varies directly with the level of capacity purchased. The utility is responsible for capital outlays
no greater than the collective demand for capacity across the universe of subscribers. The second
part of the tariff is a usage charge. The subscriber's total usage is limited by the level of capacity
purchased. Panzar and Sibley (1978) find that self-rationing, two-part tariffs of this type possess
desirable efficiency properties.7
As a matter of positive economics, however, regulators have been reluctant to force
consumers to bear the risk of self-rationing demand. Consequently, the set of instruments
presumed available in the literature may be politically unacceptable in practice. Here, we
intentionally restrict the set of viable policy instruments to correspond with current regulatory
practice. This modeling convention facilitates a clear understanding of fringe competitor strategies
while offering practical guidance on the design of efficient regulatory policies.
The primary objectives of this paper are to characterize the optimal COLR obligation and
pricing rules in an environment where the incumbent firm faces a competitive fringe. We find
terminating ends of long distance calls. Entrants in this market also supply digital, point-to-point
dedicated circuits within a local calling area. These competitors are sometimes referred to as
competitive access providers (CAPs).
6 It is a noteworthy contrast that early entrants in the long distance telephone market supplied
relatively unreliable service, whereas recent entrants in the carrier access and local distribution
market supply what is purported to be a relatively superior grade of service.
7 See also Spulber (1990).
58
that when the competitive fringe is relatively reliable, imposing a COLR constraint
(asymmetrically) on the incumbent firm tends to lower the optimal price. Moreover, when the
fringe is allowed to choose its reliability strategically, the optimal price is further reduced. A
principal finding is that the competitive fringe has incentives to overcapitalize (undercapitalize)
in the provision of reliability when the COLR obligation is sufficiently low (high).8 Here,
(COLR) supply creates its own demand in the sense that the need for a COLR may be validated
as a self-fulfilling prophecy in equilibrium.
With a low COLR requirement, the regulator responds to increased unreliability on the
part of the fringe by lowering price so as to retain a larger amount of output with the (reliable)
incumbent. The competitive fringe can thus increase price by increasing reliability, ceteris
paribus. With a high COLR requirement, an increase in reliability will reduce default output since
the fringe serves a larger share of traffic diverted from the incumbent. The effective price
elasticity for the incumbent therefore increases with fringe reliability which implies that the
optimal price decreases with fringe reliability.
The analysis proceeds as follows. The elements of the formal model are developed in the
second section. The benchmark results are presented in the third section. In the fourth section,
we present our principal findings. The conclusions are drawn in the fifth section.
8 In general, we cannot discern whether the fringe is (over-) undersupplying reliability merely
by observing its reliability relative to the incumbent. The determination of the efficient level of
reliability naturally turns on whether the fringe invests in reliability up to the point where the
marginal benefits of increased reliability are equated with corresponding marginal costs. The
inferior quality of service which plagued MCI in its start-up phase was, at least in part, due to
regulatory and technological constraints which precluded efficient interconnection with the Bell
System's local distribution network. MCI now makes claim of network reliability superior to that
of AT&T.
59
Elements of the Model
The regulator wishes to maximize a weighted average of consumer surplus across two
distinct markets. These markets might represent the local service and long-distance (or carrier
access) markets in the telephone industry. Let P E [0,1] and 1-0 denote the regulator's weight
on consumer surplus in markets 1 and 2, respectively. These weights enable us to simulate a
regulator's interest in certain social policy objectives (i.e., universally available telephone service)
that transcend pure efficiency considerations.
There are three players in the game to be analyzed: the regulator, the incumbent
(regulated) firm, and the fringe competitor. The incumbent is a franchised monopolist in market
1 in the sense that competition is strictly prohibited. In market 2, the incumbent faces an
exogenous fringe competitor. The term "exogenous fringe" means that the regulator can exert
only indirect control over the fringe by setting prices or quantities, but retains no other instruments
to control the fringe directly. This set-up again reflects the institutional structure of the
telecommunications industry, wherein both technological advance and extemalities in the design
of regulatory policies frequently limit the ability of a regulator to directly control the degree of
competitive entry.9
The incumbent's profits in market 1 are denoted by i' = [p,-v-klq,, where p, = p,(q,) is
the market price, p,(q,) is the inverse demand function and q, is market (and firm) output.
Variable and capital costs per unit of output are denoted by v and k, respectively.
9 An example may prove instructive. The Federal Communications Commission (FCC)
regulates the electromagnetic spectrum in the United States. In the Above 890 Decision (1959),
the FCC authorized the construction of private microwave networks in frequencies above 890
megacycles. This decision effectively sanctioned competition in both interstate and intrastate
telecommunications markets, but the ratemaking authority for intrastate telecommunications was
reserved to the state public service commissions (PSCs). The PSCs could thus indirectly affect
the degree of competitive entry through telephone company rate structures, but were otherwise
powerless to affect the degree of entry directly. See Weisman (1989b, pp. 341-350).
60
The incumbent's profits in market 2 are denoted by rT = [[p,-v-kl[1-e] + ye[ (p2 v) -
k]] q2, where P2 = P2(q) is the market price, p,(q2) is the inverse demand function and q, is
market output. Let e(p,) E [0,1] denote the fringe share of market output with e'(p,) > 0. The
incumbent's COLR obligation is denoted by y e [0,1] so that ye represents the share of fringe
output that is backed-up by the incumbent as the COLR. Let 0 e [0,11 ] denote the probability that
the fringe (network) operation will fail. The variable cost per unit of output for the fringe is
denoted by V, whereas fringe fixed (capital) costs are denoted by F()), with F'(4) < 0, F"(O) >
0, F(0) = and F(1) = 0. Consumer welfare is given by WC(ql,q) = PS'(ql) + (1-P)S2(q.), where
S'(q) denotes consumer surplus in market i. i = 1, 2 and
q,
(0) S'(q) = jp(z,)dz, p,(q)q.
0
Finally, we define the own price elasticity of demand in market i by e, = -(aqi/p,)(p,/q),
i = 1,2, and the competitive fringe elasticity )y e, = e'(p2)(p2/e). We assume throughout the
analysis that the fringe output is increasing in p2, which implies that e > e2.
Lemma 1: If the output of the competitive fringe is strictly increasing in p,, then ec > e,.
Proof: Let the fringe output be given by
(1) q2 = e(p2)q2.
(2) dq2/dp. = e'(p2)o + e(dq,/dp,).
Dividing (2) through by e and q, and multiplying through by P2 yields
(3) dq2/dp, = e'(p)(p2/e) + (dq/dp,)(p/q), so
(3') dq2/dp, = e, e, > 0
when ec > eV. M
The regulator's problem [RP-1] is to
q,
(4) Maximize WCq,) = [ fpl(zl)dz -piqi ] + [1-3][1-4)I1 P jpziidz:-pq]
+ l1-P][S [ jp.(r)dz,-p2q i.
0
subject to:
(5) '1 + IT 2 0,
(6) e argmax [ l-'l[e(p2)ltP2(q9)-v 1qI F('),
(7) ) ([0.1],
(8) ye [0,11, and
(9) q, 0, i = 1,2,
where q- = q[l (1-y)e].
In [RP-1], equation (5) is the individual rationality (IR) or participation constraint for the
incumbent. Equation (6) defines the fringe's profit-maximizing choice of reliability. Equation
(7) defines the feasible bounds for the fringe choice of reliability. Equation (8) defines the
feasibility bounds for the incumbent's COLR obligation which is treated exogenously in this
problem. Equation (9) rules out negative output quantities. Note that q, represents market 2
output when the fringe operation fails since (1-y)e is the share of fringe output not backed-up by
the incumbent as the COLR. Figure 4-1 illustrates consumer surplus in market 2.
Benchmark Solutions
We begin by establishing the benchmark first-best case. The regulator's problem [RP-2]
is identical to [RP-1 ] with the exception that the incentive compatibility constraint (6) representing
the fringe choice of reliability is omitted and the COLR obligation (y) is treated as an endogenous
parameter. In this problem, the regulator has perfect commitment ability to specify, q,, q2, 7 and
A. The Lagrangian for [RP-2] is given by
q, q2
(10) Se = [ fp,(z,)dzi-pql ]+ [1-P 11-01 [ fp,(z)dz,-pQ ]
0 0
q;
+ [1-P1ll] [ f p2(Z2)dz2-pq + q,(p-v-k) + q,(p2-v-k)(1-e)
0
+ ye[0(p2-v)-kl] + 6[1-0] + p [1-y],
where X, 8 and t are the Lagrange multipliers associated with (5), (7) and (8), respectively.
In the first proposition, we show how the regulator will optimally set the incumbent's
COLR obligation (y) and the unreliability of the competitive fringe (0).
Proposition 1: At the solution to [RP-2], 0 = 1 if and only if y = 1 and 0 = 0 if and only if y
= 0.
Proof: Necessary first-order conditions for 0 and y include
(11) 0: [1l-3][S(qE)-S(q2)l + Xqe(p2-v) 8 < 0: 4[(]J = 0,
and
(12) y- [1-p][O][p2(q)-p(q2)j[eq2] + Xeq12[(p2-v)-k] 0: yfZ1 = 0.
From (11),
(i) when y = 1, S2(q ) = S2(q), 8 > 0 and 0 = 1; and
(ii) when y = 0, S2(q) < S2(q), < 0 and 0 = 0.
From (12),
(iii) when 0 = 0, P2(qb) = p2(q), S < 0 and y= 0; and
(iv) when 0 = 1, p2(q) > p2(a), > 0 and y= 1. M
If one hundred percent back-up is in place (7 = 1), the incumbent serves as the COLR
for all of the fringe output, and it is optimal for the regulator to choose a perfectly unreliable
fringe. If 4 < 1, inefficient duplication of facilities will result. Conversely, if the fringe network
is perfectly reliable (0 = 0), then it is optimal to relieve the incumbent of its COLR obligation
63
and set y = 0, since any value of y > 0 results in the deployment of capital that will never be
utilized.
Now consider optimal pricing rules for q, and q2 assuming qi > 0. i = 1,2.
(13) (p,-v-k)/p, = [ l]/ie,
and
(14) [1-p][1 + 0 [[e2+(e2-e,)(y-l)e]r + (y-l)e] ] + 4[p-v-k][(l-e)e, + eeJ/p2
+ ye[)(p2-v)-kl[e2-ejl/p2 (l-e) e] = 0,
where = [pz(qA) P2(q2)]/P2(q2). Equation (14) implicitly defines the optimal pricing rule for
market 2. Observe now that when there is no competitive fringe (e = 0), (14) reduces to
(15) (p2-v-k)/p, = [- (l-P)]/e,2.
Dividing (15) into (13) and assuming the regulator weights consumer surplus equally in the two
markets so that p = ', we obtain
(16) (p,-v-k)/p, =
(p2-v-k)/P2 e,
which is the standard Ramsey pricing rule. If we now set y = 0 = 0 so that we have a perfectly
reliable fringe with no COLR obligation, the optimal pricing rule in (14) reduces to
(17) (pl-v-k)/p = [.(l-e)-(l-p)]/[( l-e)e2+ec].
Since ec > e, the optimal price is lower with a competitive fringe than in the standard Ramsey
pricing rule, or pe < p. The presence of a competitive fringe tends to lower the optimal price in
market 2. Stated differently, the price for market 1 must now carry a heavier burden of satisfying
the incumbent's revenue requirement, or participation constraint.'" This occurs because the fringe
raises the effective price elasticity for the incumbent in market 2.
1t This type of argument was a familiar refrain on the part of AT&T when fringe competitors
(e.g., MCI and U.S. Sprint) first appeared in the long-distance telephone market See Wenders
(1987) chapter 8 and 9.
64
Let p define the optimal price when the incumbent maintains a COLR obligation (y >
0). In the next proposition, we characterize the relationship between p' and p where the
superscripts refer to COLR (c) and competitive entry (e), respectively.
Proposition 2: If y > max [, (2e,-e,)/(~2-ec)], there exists a 4 such that p < p' V 4 < ^ and
p >pc V > >4.
Proof: The optimal pricing rule in (14) can be written as
(18) (p -v-k)/p = [[(l-e)+)eXl/-[l-p][l+4[[ 2+(s2-e3)(Y-l)e]T+(y-1)e]] /A
e[)(p2-v)-k]/p2 /[(l-e)e, + eej.
(i) For ) = 0 (18) reduces to
(19) (p -v-k)/p = [iX(l-e) (l-p)]/ + yek(C2-e,)/p,] /[(l-e)e + eec <
[X(1-e) (l-P)]A/[(l-e)e2 + e]j = (p'-v-k)/p .
(ii) For 0 = 1, (18) reduces to
(20) (p -v-k)/p = [X((l-e)+el]-[l-P1][+(+(e 2-e)(-l)e]T+(Yt-)el] A/
< [L(-e) (l-p)]/iX(l-e)e2 + eej = (p2-v-k)/p2,
where i = [(1-e)e2 + ee, + ye(c,-ec)l, provided that
(21) Xe > [1-p][l+[E,+(s2-e,)(y-l)e]T + (y-l)e],
or
(22) e > [e2+(e2-e,)(Y-l)ej],
since ~, max [P,(1-P)]. Now recognize that
(23) e > 2 T2 > [e1+(e2-e )(y-l)elt, if
(24) e2 > (2-e,)(Y-l) > (E2-e,)(y-l)e.
Solving for y in (24) yields
(25) y > (2,-E,)/(E2-ec),
65
which is one of the conditions of the proposition. Observe from (23) that
(26) et = [q, q2[l+(y-l)e]]/q2 = 1 [l+(y-l)e] = (l-y)e.
Hence, upon substitution of (26) into (23)
(27) e > 2(1-y)e.
Canceling terms and solving for y in (27) yields
(28) y > ,
which is another condition of the proposition. Equations (25) and (28) jointly require that y7
max [/2, (2e2-ec)/(e~-e)], which is the statement in the proposition. Since the optimal pricing
rule is assumed to be differentiable for 0 e [0,1], it is also continuous for 4 e [0,1] and the
Intermediate Value Theorem applies. Hence, there exists a Q E [0,1] such that pc = p for 4 =
4. The result follows. U
For low values of 0, the firm realizes a net loss on its default operations since it incurs
capital costs but little or no offsetting revenues. Hence, it is optimal to set pc < p2 to minimize
the fringe output for which the incumbent serves as the unremunerativee) COLR. For high values
of ), it is as if there is not a fringe at all (note: for ) = 1, there is essentially no fringe) provided
y is sufficiently large to serve the default output and it is optimal to set pc > p;.
The next proposition characterizes the optimal price in market 2 when the fringe is
unreliable (0 > 0) and there is no COLR obligation (7 = 0).
Proposition 3: p < pI at y = 0 V 0 > 0.
Proof: With y = 0, the optimal price term in (14) can be written as
(29) (pl-v-k)/p = [.[(l-e)]/-[ 1-1][l+)[[ e2+(e,-e2)e]l-e]] /X[(l-e)e,+eej
< [(1-e) (l-P3)]/[(l-e)e2 + ee,] = pI-v-k)/pl
V 0 > 0, provided that
(30) [e, + (e,-e2)e]T > e, and
(31) [(l-e)e2 + eec] > e.
Let e, = ze, where z > 1 since e, > e,. Substitution into (31) yields
(32) [(l-e)e2 + zeej > e.
Consolidating terms yields
(33) [l+e(z-l)]e2t > e.
Observe that e2r = (l-y)e. Substitution into (33) yields
(34) [l+e(z-l)][(l-y)el > e.
Imposing the y = 0 condition of the proposition yields
(35) [l+e(z-l)]e > e,
(36) l+e(z-l) > 1, and
(37) e(z-l) > 0,
which is satisfied V e > 0 since z > 1. E
If 0 > 0, there is a nonzero probability that demand lost to the fringe will not be served
since y = 0. Hence, there is an expected loss of consumer surplus on output supplied by the
competitive fringe. The regulator desires to minimize this expected loss in consumer surplus, so
he sets a relatively low price in order to retain a larger share of total output with the incumbent.
In fact, the higher the probability of fringe failure, the lower the optimal price set by the
regulator. This result is summarized in proposition 4.
Corollary to Proposition 3: p2 < p' at y = 1 and 4 = 0.
Proof: The proof is similar in technique to that for proposition 3 and is therefore omitted. N
With a one hundred percent COLR obligation and a zero probability of fringe failure, the
optimal price is lowered to reduce unremunerative capital costs. The lower price ensures that a
larger share of output remains with the incumbent since e'(p2) > 0.
67
We now examine the general comparative statics for [RP-2], treating 0 and y as
exogenous parameters. Let H denote the bordered Hessian for [RP-2] and IHI its corresponding
determinant. Necessary second-order conditions which are assumed to hold require that IHI > 0
at a maximum. We begin by identifying the sign pattern for H and its corresponding parameter
vector for the limiting values of 4( and y.
Total differentiation of the necessary first-order conditions for [RP-2] with respect to )
yields the following sign pattern for H and the corresponding parameter vector.
0 0
(38) HI =0 and +
0
0 0
(39) H o = 0 and -
0 0
Application of Cramer's rule yields standard comparative static results which we formalize in the
following proposition.
Proposition 4: At the solution to [RP-2],
(i) if y = 1, dp,/d4 < 0 and dp,/d) > 0 for e, small: and
(ii) if y = 0, dpl/d) > 0 and dP2/d) < 0.
An increase in the rate of fringe failure with y = 1 implies an increase in default output
revenues with which to offset COLR capital costs. Since X > 0 at the solution to [RP-2], the
increase in revenues allows p, to fall. Hence, the more unreliable the competitive fringe, the
lower the price in market 1.
At y = 1, p, decreases with the price elasticity of demand in market 2 for e, sufficiently
small. The more reliable the fringe, the higher the effective price elasticity for the incumbent
68
since a smaller share of output diverted to the fringe returns to the incumbent in the form of
default output.
With no COLR obligation (y = 0), an increase in the unreliability of the fringe will cause
the regulator to reduce the price for p, in order to retain a greater amount of output with the
incumbent (see proposition 3). To ensure the incumbent firm remains viable, with a binding IR
constraint (X > 0), a reduction in p, requires an increase in p,.
Total differentiation of the necessary first-order conditions for [RP-2] with respect to y
yields the following sign pattern for H and the corresponding parameter vector.
0 0
(40) H = and +
0
0 0
(41) H o = 0 and -
0 +
Application of Cramer's rule again yields a set of standard comparative static results which we
formalize in the following proposition.
Proposition 5: At the solution to [RP-2],
(i) at 0 = 1, dp,/dy< 0; and
(ii) at 0 = 0, dp,/dy > 0.
With a one hundred percent default rate ( 1 = 1), deploying capital costs to serve as the
COLR is financially remunerative for the firm since p2 is optimally set above marginal cost and
p, falls. The effect on p. is ambiguous. An increase in p2 results in output moving to the fringe
(independent of whether it is ultimately served) which may prove to be financially unremunerative
69
for the incumbent. This occurs because raising P2 may divert more traffic to the fringe than the
incumbent can serve on a default basis for any given level of y.
With a perfectly reliable fringe (0 = 0), raising y increases the level of financially
unremunerative capital costs which are financed by raising p,. The effect on P2 is again
ambiguous. Even though costs rise with an increase in y, the presence of the fringe renders it
uncertain as to whether p, will be increased to finance these additional capital costs.
Principal Findings
We now examine the properties of the general model [RP-I]. In this modeling
framework, the competitive fringe chooses its optimal level of reliability. The regulator is the
Stackelberg leader, choosing q,, q, and y. The competitive fringe is the Stackelberg follower,
choosing 4. Recognize that the timing in [RP- ] is such that the regulator is able to affect the
fringe reliability choice (0) only indirectly, as it is assumed that the regulator has (perfect)
knowledge of the fringe reaction function. In subsequent analysis, [RP-3], we reverse the timing
and allow the fringe to be the Stackelberg leader.
We begin with analysis of the reliability choice of the fringe which appears as an incentive
compatibility constraint (6) in [RP-1]. This constraint is expressed as follows.
(42) 0 e argmax [[l-4'][e(p2)][p2(q2)-i][q2 -F(O)].
For an interior solution, (42) requires
(43) -eq(p2 9) F'(0) = 0.
If 0 < (p, V) < c, we obtain an interior solution for 0 since F(0) = o. Sufficient second-order
conditions (concavity) for a unique maximum (4*) requires that
(44) -F"(O) < 0.
70
which is satisfied since F"(o) > 0. Equation (43) can be viewed as the competitive fringe reaction
function for 4 conditioned on the regulator's choice of P2 or q2. Hence, for the regulator's choice
of p, or q,, the reaction function yields a unique Q*.
Differentiating the reaction function in (43) implicitly with respect to p2, we obtain
(45) -e'q2(p V) e(aq2/ap2)(pz ) eq, F"(4)(d0/dp2) = 0.
Rearranging terms and appealing to the definition of e, and ee, we obtain
(46) -ec(p2 V)/P2 + e2(p, 9)/P2 1 F"(0)/eq,(d/dp2) = 0.
Rearranging terms and solving for do/dp, yields
(47) dO/dp2 = [eq./F"(O)l[[(p, 9)(ez e:)l/P ] < 0.
The inequality in (47) holds because ,c > E Hence, the higher the price (p,) set by the regulator,
the more reliable the competitive fringe operation. When p. rises, the fringe can serve a larger
share of traffic at a higher price. It thus has incentives to increase reliability with a higher p2.
Note also that do/dq2 > 0 since p2 = p,(q2) and )p2/aq2 < 0.
The Lagrangian for [RP-1] is given by
(48) S = P [ jp(z,)dz,-p,q, ] + l-[1-4 p (z,)dz-p2q ]
0 0
+ [1- [ fp2(z)dz2-p2q; ]+ q,(p -v-k) + q(p-v-k)(l-e)
0
+ Yeq21[(p2-v)-k]] + p[-eq2(p2-V)-F(0)] + 6[1-01 + [l1-y].
Necessary first-order conditions for q2, assuming an interior solution and rearranging terms yields
(49) [1-P][1 + e2(a/aq2)[S(q2) S(q2)] + [e2 + (e2-e,)(y-l)e]t + (y-l)e] +
4[[p2-v-k][(l-e)e2 + eeJ/p2 + e[(p2-v)-k][2-CJ/P2 (l-e) 4e +
yezq2e(0/Bq2)(p2-v)/P2 + p[e(ph-)(e2-e)/p2+e F"()(a0/aq,.)E2/P2l = 0.
71
Equation (49) implicitly defines the optimal pricing rule for p2 in [RP-1]. Denote this optimal
price by p We define the following terms
(50) b, = ye2q2e(2.-v)/P2 > 0, and
(51) b, = p[e(p2-V)(e2-e,)/P2+e F"(4)(O/aq2)e/p2] > 0.
In the next proposition, we characterize the relationship between p 2 and p. Since the
regulator cannot specify 4 directly in [RP-1], he indirectly influences 0 through his choice of 2.
Proposition 6: At the solution to [RP-1], P < pi when y = 1.
Proof: With y = 1. S2(qc) = S2(q2). The optimal pricing rule in (49) can thus be written as
(52) (pi v k)/p = [[(l-e) + ye b, (bj/)] [l-][1l + )(y-1)e +
)[e2 + (e2,-e)(Y-l)e]T I ye[(p2-v)-k][e2-e,]/P2]/p[(l-e)e, + eej
< [h[(l-e)+fL-[l1-1] [1+[[ e2,+(e,2-e,)(y-1)e]t+(y-l)e] ]/
-_e([(p2-v)-k]/p] /[(l-e)e, + eec] = (p v k)/pj.
since b, > 0 and b, > 0. M
With one hundred percent back-up (y = 1), the regulator wants an entirely unreliable
fringe () = 1) in order to avoid inefficient duplication of facilities unremunerativee capital costs).
Yet in [RP-1], the regulator cannot control 0 directly, only indirectly through P2. From the
competitive fringe reaction function, dO/dq, > 0. Hence, in order to induce the fringe to choose
a lower level of reliability (higher 4), the regulator lowers P2 relative to [RP-1]. It follows that
P2
The optimal price is lower when the fringe chooses its own level of reliability in order
to maximize profits under a one hundred percent COLR obligation. The effect of this lower price
is not only to ensure that a larger share of traffic remains with the incumbent since e'(p2) > 0, but
also to induce more default output since do/dp, < 0.
72
In [RP-11, we assume that the regulator is the Stackelberg leader and the competitive
fringe is the Stackelberg follower. In [RP-3], we reverse the timing to explore the implications
of allowing the competitive fringe to lead with its choice of reliability (4)."
In [RP-3], the regulator's problem is to
(53) Maximize [[1-0'][e(p2)l[p,(q)-V 1[q2] F(')],
{ql,q2A,}
subject to:
q, q;
(54) ql,q e argmax p3 fpl(z)dzL-pq] +1 1-i1][1-i f p I(z)dzL-p2q
q',q 0
q;
+ [1-P][] [fp,(z.)dz2-p2q.,
0
subject to:
(55) ic + X,2 2 0,
(56) 0 e [0,1],
(57) y = and
(58) q, > 0, i = 1,2
where q2 = q,[1 (l-y)e].
With the exception of the timing reversal, the structure of [RP-3] is quite similar to
[RP-1]. One exception is equation (57) which specifies a constant COLR obligation for the
incumbent firm. As a practical matter, the COLR obligation is not a topic for standard tariff
review. In fact, in a number of state jurisdictions, the COLR obligation is a provision of state
statute and thus not amenable to review and modification by public utility regulators. Given that
The timing sequence in [RP-31 is modeled after the FCC's practice of allowing incumbent
firms to respond to new service offerings of competitors. The set of rules that the FCC enforces
with regard to the incumbent's ability to respond is referred to formally as the Competitive
Necessity Test.
73
one of our primary objectives here is to explain competitive fringe strategy in response to existing
regulatory institutions, this modeling convention appears within reason.
We begin our analysis of [RP-31 by examining the objective function of the competitive
fringe. Let ir' denote the profit function of the competitive fringe, where
(59) = [[ l-4'][e(p2)][p2(q2)- ][q] F()') .
Differentiating (59) with respect to 0, assuming an interior solution, we obtain
(60) an/d) = -e[p2,() V ] F'(0) = 0.
The first term to the right of the equals sign in (60) can be interpreted as the marginal benefit of
increased unreliability; the second term to the right of the equals sign can be interpreted as the
marginal cost of increased unreliability. Observe now that if
(61) -e[p2(q) v ] F'(() > (<) 0,
at the solution to [RP-3], overcapitalization (undercapitalization) in the provision of reliability
occurs relative to the benchmark case. To see this, recall that F"(O) > 0. Hence, if (61) is strictly
positive (negative), 4 is too low (too high) in comparison with the benchmark case. Because a
higher degree of reliability is associated with a larger capital expenditure, F'()) < 0, it is
instructive to refer to this as an overcapitalization (undercapitalization) distortion.
In the next proposition, we characterize sufficient conditions for the overcapitalization
(undercapitalization) distortion.
Proposition 7: The competitive fringe overcapitalizes in the provision of reliability at the
solution to [RP-3] if y = 0 and undercapitalizes if y = 1 and e, is small.
Proof: Differentiating (59) with respect to 0, assuming an interior solution, and rearranging
terms, we obtain
(62) -e[p2(q) V ] F'(4) = [ l-4'][e'(p2/q)(a 2/0)l[p2 V j]q
[l-4'][e][(Op,/Oq)(q/a ) [l-)'][e][p2 v ][p12/q2j.
74
By proposition 4 part (ii), q2/t04 > 0 at y = 0. Hence, for y = 0, the expression to the left of
the equals sign in the first line of (62) is strictly positive when
(63) -[(l-'][el[(p:/,lq,)( q/ L/6lq, [l-4'][e][p2 vl 1p,/aql > 0.
After canceling terms and rearranging, we obtain
(64) -(op2/aq2) [p2 9 I > 0. or
(65) 1 E2[P2 ]/P2 > 0,
which is satisfied for < 1 (inelastic demand). The second part of the proof follows from
proposition 4 part (i). M
When y = 0, an increase in reliability allows p, to rise as the regulator is less concerned
about retaining output with the incumbent since there is a reduced probability of a fringe failure.
The fringe views this increase in price as a de facto subsidy to investment in reliability which
leads to the overcapitalization distortion.
When y = 1, an increase in reliability decreases the (expected) level of default output for
the incumbent since the probability of a fringe failure is reduced.12 The effective price elasticity
for the incumbent in market 2 increases with fringe reliability. The optimal price in market 2 is
thus reduced to reflect this higher price elasticity.'3 The fringe views this decrease in price as
a tax on investment in reliability which leads to the undercapitalization distortion.
12 It is conceivable that the fringe may increase reliability so as to strand the incumbent's plant
and thereby raise its rivals' costs along the lines suggested by Salop and Scheffman (1983). This
is advantageous for the fringe, however, only when the incumbent finances the revenue deficiency
by raising the price in market 2. Yet, raising the price in market 2 will not only divert more
traffic to the fringe, but it will also induce the fringe to increase reliability resulting in an even
larger revenue deficiency for the incumbent
13 The price elasticity of demand for basic local telephone service is very small, on the order
of 0.10 or less in absolute value. See Taylor (1993). This corresponds to the condition in the
proposition that el be small.
75
Proposition 7 thus supports Kahn's (1971) original hypothesis that fringe competitors may
tend to underinvest in reliability. He argues that consumers may be reluctant to patronize the
competitive fringe unless the incumbent serves as the COLR due to concerns about service
reliability.14 We find that for a sufficiently high COLR obligation (y = 1), the fringe has
incentives to underinvest in reliability. Conversely, for a sufficiently low COLR obligation (y =
0), the fringe has incentives to overinvest in reliability. In essence, (COLR) supply creates its
own demand in that consumer concerns about fringe reliability may be validated as self-fulfilling
prophecies in equilibrium.
The implications of proposition 7 for competitor strategy in the telecommunications
industry raise interesting questions for further research. For example, MCI and U.S. Sprint now
compete with AT&T amid claims of superior reliability. It would be interesting to examine
whether these competitors have overcapitalized in the provision of reliability, and whether such
overcapitalization can be explained by a relaxation of AT&T's COLR obligation.
Similar developments are unfolding in the carrier access market where entrants are
deploying fiber optic networks with reliability standards (arguably) superior to those of common
carriers.15 Absent demand and cost information, it is not possible to determine whether these
activities represent overcapitalization in the provision of reliability. Yet, our findings do suggest
the manner in which the incumbent's COLR obligation (y) will affect the fringe competitors'
choice of reliability.
14 This suggests that e = e(p2, ,y), with e1 > 0, e2 < 0 and e3 > 0, where the subscripts denote
partial derivatives. Kahn suggests that concerns about service reliability are alleviated when the
incumbent serves as the COLR for the entire market, so e2(p2,0,l) = 0. This is supported by the
case study in Weisman (1989c). Hence, when y= 1, the fringe share function can reasonably be
expressed solely as a function of p2, which is the formulation here. Incorporating the more
general formulation of the fringe share function into the analysis is a topic for future research.
15 See Weisman (1989b, 1989c) and Metropolitan Fiber Systems (1989).
76
Conclusion
The advent of competition for public utility-like services poses complex problems for
regulators who must ultimately balance equity and efficiency considerations in crafting public
policy. Frequently, this dichotomy results in asymmetric regulation wherein the incumbent bears
responsibility for certain historical obligations not likewise borne by its competitors. Here, we
have focused on one such obligation, the responsibility of the incumbent to serve as the
nondiscriminatory COLR.
In general, we find that in the presence of a relatively reliable fringe competitor (4 < 4 ),
the optimal price (p) is lower when the incumbent is required to serve as the COLR. Moreover,
when the fringe is allowed to choose its level of reliability strategically while the incumbent must
maintain a one hundred percent COLR obligation (y = 1), the optimal price (p ) is lower yet, p
Our principal finding reveals that the competitive fringe has incentives to overcapitalize
(undercapitalize) in the provision of reliability when the COLR obligation is sufficiently low
(high). Here, (COLR) supply creates its own demand in that the need for a COLR becomes a
self-fulfilling prophecy in equilibrium. These findings may explain competitive fringe strategies
in the telecommunications industry.
As competition intensifies for public utility-like services, regulators may be forced to
consider a richer set of policy instruments to address the distortions inherent in a
nondiscriminatory COLR obligation. The insightful work of Panzar and Sibley (1978) offers some
interesting possibilities in this regard. Here, working within the confines of existing regulatory
institutions, we provide some guidance in the design of welfare-enhancing public policies under
asymmetric regulation.
p2 (q2 )
q2 q2 q2
S2(q) = A + B + C
S2(q) = A + B
where q = q2 l-(l-y)e]
with probability 1-I
with probability 0
Figure 4-1: Consumer Surplus in Market 2.
CHAPTER 5
CONCLUDING COMMENTS
This dissertation is composed of three essays on the economics of regulation. In each
essay, we began with a given theoretical model and methodically built institutional realism into
the underlying mathematical structure. This modeling approach enables us to traverse the expanse
between theory and practice while revealing the value of doing so. The results of the analysis
cause us to question, and in a number of cases reverse, some important findings in the literature.
These results should prove useful to researchers and policymakers in regulated industries. We
conclude with a statement of the principal findings from each essay and a brief discussion of
prospective topics for future research.
In Superior Regulatory Regimes In Theory and Practice, we discovered that while PC
regulation is superior to CB regulation, it is not generally true that a hybrid application of PC and
CB regulation, what we referred to as MPC regulation, is superior to CB regulation. This is an
important result for both theory and policy, as MPC regulation is the dominant form of PC
regulation in practice. While regulators were encouraged to adopt PC regulation in order to
eliminate a myriad of economic distortions that prevail under CB regulation, MPC regulation may
serve only to exacerbate these distortions.
In terms of future research, the analysis reveals that CB regulation can dominate MPC
regulation, but the conditions under which this result holds require further analysis, perhaps along
the lines suggested by Schmalensee (1989). Our findings also question the superiority of PC
79
regulation when the firm believes there is a nonzero probability that the regulator will recontract.
A rigorous treatment of recontracting-induced distortions is a promising area for future research.
In Why Less May Be More Under Price-Cap Regulation, we proved that the firm's
dominant strategy is to adopt a form of PC regulation that entails sharing profits with consumers.
Profit-sharing provides the regulator with a vested interest in the firm's financial well-being. As
a result, the regulator may be induced to choose a lesser degree of competitive entry or a higher
price under sharing than if the firm retains its profits in full. The irony here is that the firm may
object to sharing on grounds that it subverts economic efficiency, a result consistent with our
analysis. only to discover that sharing leads to a higher absolute level of profits.
In this essay, we have demonstrated that profit-sharing is a dominant strategy for the firm
under PC regulation, but the task remains to characterize the optimal sharing rule. Moreover, we
should attempt to resolve the paradox of why, in practice, regulators prefer sharing and the firm
prefers pure price-caps when our results suggest that the opposite should be true.
In Designing Carrier of Last Resort Obligations, we derived optimal pricing policies in
an environment where the incumbent faces a competitive fringe and is constrained by an
asymmetric COLR obligation. We found that the presence of the fringe tends to reduce the
optimal price set by the regulator. When the incumbent bears a nonzero COLR obligation and
the fringe is relatively reliable, the optimal price is further reduced. The optimal price is lower
yet when the fringe is allowed to choose its level of reliability strategically. Our principal finding
reveals that the fringe has incentives to overcapitalize (undercapitalize) in the provision of
reliability when the incumbent's COLR obligation is sufficiently low (high). Here, (COLR)
supply creates its own demand in the sense that the need for a COLR may be validated as a self-
fulfilling prophecy in equilibrium.
80
In terms of future research, it remains to be shown that introducing self-rationing, two-part
tariffs along the lines suggested by Panzar and Sibley (1978) and Weisman (1988) will efficiently
address this overcapitalization (undercapitalization) distortion. A number of other interesting
research topics suggest themselves, such as introducing an endogenous fringe, allowing the firm
to charge differently for default output and an analysis of the welfare effects of substituting a
COLR constraint for a price-cap constraint when the regulator has imperfect information about
the firm's costs.
APPENDIX
CORE WASTE EXAMPLE
Suppose the firm believes the recontracting probability is given by 0(7r) =
[exp{.00077, }-11, where it, [0,1000]. This function satisfies the requisite properties since 0(0)
= 0 and 0(1000) = 1. Also, 0'(0) = .0007 exp{.00077c,} > 0 and 0"(C,) = (.0007)2
expl.00077, } > 0 so that the recontracting probability function is convex. As shown in Table A.
the firm has no incentive to engage in waste at lower core market profit levels, but it does at
higher core market profit levels. The recontracting elasticity (e.) is increasing with 7t, and the
relative shares term (1-4 T)/ T is decreasing with r,. Eventually, a point is reached where the
gain in expected profit from reducing the probability of recontracting dominates the loss in direct
profits of (1-OT). At profit levels in excess of this critical point, the firm has incentives to
engage in pure waste.
TABLE A: Waste is Profitable for the Firm
7t, E[ir,] T eo (1-0 T)/qT u, > 0
100 96.4 0.073 0.5 1.028 < 26.397 no
300 264.9 0.234 0.5 1.110 < 7.547 no
700 478.8 0.632 0.5 1.266 < 2.165 no
882.3 505.1 0.855 0.5 1.341 = 1.341
950 501.1 0.945 0.5 1.369 > 1.116 yes
REFERENCES
Arrow, K. J., "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention." In: The Rate
and Direction of Inventive Activity. Ed.: The National Bureau of Economic Research,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1962.
Baron, D. P., "Design of Regulatory Mechanisms and Institutions," In: The Handbook of
Industrial Organization, Vol. II. Eds.: R. Schmalensee and R. D. Willig, Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1989.
Beesley, M. E. and S. C. Littlechild, "The Regulation of Privatized Monopolies in the United
Kingdom," Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 1989, 454-472.
Besanko, D. and D. E. M. Sappington, "Designing Regulatory Policy with Limited Information,"
In: Fundamentals of Pure and Applied Economics, Vol. 20. New York, NY: Harwood,
1986.
Braeutigam, R. R., "An Analysis of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing in Regulated Industries," The
Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 1980, 182-196.
Braeutigam, R. R. and J. C. Panzar, "Diversification Incentives Under Price-Based and Cost-Based
Regulation," Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 1989, 373-391.
Brennan. T. J., "Regulating By 'Capping' Prices," Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 1989,
133-147.
Cabral, L. M. B. and M. H. Riordan. "Incentives for Cost Reduction Under Price Cap
Regulation," Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 1989, 93-102.
Caillaud, B., R. Guesnerie, P. Rey and J. Tirole, "Government Intervention In Production: A
Review of Recent Contributions," Rand Journal of Economics, 19(1) 1988, 1-26.
Federal Communications Commission, Further Notice of Proposed Rule Making, In the Matter
of Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for Dominant Carriers, CC Docket No. 87-313,
Released May 23, 1988.
Goldberg, V. P., "Regulation and Administered Contracts," The Bell Journal of Economics, 7(2).
1976, 426-448.
Goldberg, V. P., "Protecting the Right to be Served by Public Utilities," Research in Law and
Economics, 1, 1979, 145-156.
Haring, J. R., "The Implications of Asymmetric Regulation for Competition Policy Analysis,"
Federal Communications Commission, Office of Plans and Policy Working Paper No. 14,
Washington, DC, December 1984.
Kahn, A. E., The Economics of Regulation. New York, NY: Wiley, 1971.
Keeler, T. E., Railroads, Freight and Public Policy, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution,
1983.
Metropolitan Fiber Systems, "Petition for Rulemaking in the Matter of Interconnection of
Exchange Access Facilities," Before the Federal Communications Commission,
Washington, DC, November 14, 1989.
Panzar, J. C. and D. S. Sibley, "Public Utility Pricing Under Risk: The Case of Self-Rationing,"
American Economic Review. 68(5), December 1978, 888-895.
Posner, R. A., "Taxation by Regulation." The Bell Journal of Economics, 2, 1971, 22-50.
Posner, R. A., "Theories of Economic Regulation," The Bell Journal of Economics, 5, 1974,
335-58.
Salop, S. C. and D. T. Scheffman, "Raising Rivals' Costs," American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings, 73, May 1983, 267-271.
Sappington, D. E. M. and J. E. Stiglitz, "Information and Regulation," In: Public Regulation:
New Perspectives on Institutions and Policies, Ed.: E.E. Bailey, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1987.
Schmalensee, R., "Good Regulatory Regimes," Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 1989,
417-436.
Southwestern Bell Telephone Company, In the Matter of an Inquiry into Alternatives to Rate of
Return Regulation for Local Exchange Telephone Companies, Arkansas Docket No.
91-204-U, February 10, 1992.
Spulber, D. F., "Capacity Contingent Nonlinear Pricing by Regulated Firms," J.L. Kellogg
Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, Discussion Paper No. 90-23,
Evanston, IL, February, 1990.
Sweeney, G., "Welfare Implications of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing Applied to Partially
Regulated Firms," The Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 1982, 525-533.
Taylor, L. D., Telecommunications Demand: A Survey and Critique, 1993 (Forthcoming).
Vogelsang, I., "Price Cap Regulation of Telecommunications Services: A Long Run Approach,"
The Rand Corporation Report, N-2704-MF, Santa Monica, CA, February, 1988.
84
Weisman. D. L., "Default Capacity Tariffs: Smoothing the Transitional Regulatory Asymmetries
in the Telecommunications Market." Yale Journal on Regulation, 5(1), Winter 1988, 149-
178.
Weisman, D. L.. "Optimal Recontracting, Market Risk and the Regulated Firm in Competitive
Transition," Research in Law and Economics, 12, 1989a, 153-172.
Weisman. D. L., "The Proliferation of Private Networks and its Implications for Regulatory
Reform," Federal Communications Law Journal, 41(3), July 1989b, 331-367.
Weisman, D. L., "Competitive Markets and Carriers of Last Resort," Public Utilities Fortnightly,
July 6, 1989c, 17-24.
Wenders, J. T., The Economics of Telecommunications. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1987.
BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH
Dennis Weisman has accepted the position of assistant professor of economics at Kansas
State University. He is currently director-strategic marketing for Southwestern Bell Corporation
and an affiliated research fellow with the Public Utility Research Center at the University of
Florida. Mr. Weisman has more than ten years experience in the telecommunications industry in
the areas of regulation and business strategy development. He has testified in a number of state
rate proceedings on bypass and competition in the telecommunications industry, and has written
extensively on the economics of regulation with particular emphasis on the telecommunications
industry. His work has appeared in numerous professional economic, business and law journals,
including the Yale Journal on Regulation, The International Journal of Forecasting, Energy
Economics, Research in Law and Economics, The Federal Communications Law Journal and the
Journal of Cost Management. His current research interests include superior regulatory regimes
in theory and practice, the welfare implications of asymmetric regulation and costing principles
for efficient business decisions. Mr. Weisman holds a B.A. in mathematics and economics
Magnaa cum laude in economics) and an M.A. in economics, both from the University of
Colorado. Mr. Weisman is a Ph.D. candidate in the Department of Economics at the University
of Florida, where he expects his degree to be conferred in May of 1993.
I certify that I have read this study and that in my opinion it conforms to acceptable
standards of scholarly presentation and is fully adequate, in spe and quality, as a dissertation
for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. / a
avid E. tMappfgton, Chair
Lanzillotti-McKethan Professor of
Economics
I certify that I have read this study and that in my opinion it conforms to acceptable
standards of scholarly presentation and is fully adequate, in scope and quality, as a dissertation
for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
Sanford V. rg
Florida Public Utilities Professor of
Economics
I certify that I have read this study and that in my opinion it conforms to acceptable
standards of scholarly presentation and is fully adequate, in scope and quality, as a dissertation
for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
Richard E. Romano
Associate Professor of Economics
I certify that I have read this study and that in my opinion it conforms to acceptable
standards of scholarly presentation and is fully adequate, in scope and quality, as a dissertation
for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
Jt A. ost
Assi tarofessor Accounting
This dissertation was submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the Department of Economics
in the College of Business Administration and to the Graduate School and was accepted as partial
fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
May 1993
Dean, Graduate School
UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA
I I I III I 5 II Ill I I
3 1262 08553 8766