Title: Economic Criteria and the Public Interest
CITATION THUMBNAILS PAGE IMAGE ZOOMABLE
Full Citation
STANDARD VIEW MARC VIEW
Permanent Link: http://ufdc.ufl.edu/WL00003195/00001
 Material Information
Title: Economic Criteria and the Public Interest
Physical Description: Book
Language: English
Publisher: The Conservation Foundation
 Subjects
Spatial Coverage: North America -- United States of America -- Florida
 Notes
Abstract: Richard Hamann's Collection - Economic Criteria and the Public Interest
General Note: Box 12, Folder 11 ( Conservation Foundation - Symposium Papers on Water Allocation in Eastern U. S. - 1956 ), Item 48
Funding: Digitized by the Legal Technology Institute in the Levin College of Law at the University of Florida.
 Record Information
Bibliographic ID: WL00003195
Volume ID: VID00001
Source Institution: Levin College of Law, University of Florida
Holding Location: Levin College of Law, University of Florida
Rights Management: All rights reserved by the source institution and holding location.

Full Text




29.


6. Economic Criteria and the Public Interest


The maximization principle is applied in normative economics, first, as

efficiency criterion for limited operations under restrictive assumptions and,

second, as the assumed over-all objective of individuals and groups.

As efficiency criterion, the maximization principle is used, for example,

in finding the optimum output under given cost and revenue functions and also

in determining minimum costs for each output under given production functions

and given price schedules of productive factors, that is, in determining a cost

function. For these purposes the maximization principle is necessary. There

can be no disagreement on the usefulness of such operations. One may call this

application of the maximization principle "efficiency economics" or, more appro-

priately in some cases, "efficiency engineering."

If applied as the assumed over-all objective of individuals and group,

on the other hand, the maximization principle is a construct, a scientific fic-

tion.1/ It is useful in economics, especially in modern western culture, if

employed in connection with another construct--the "firm." Frequent references

in recent economic literature to maxima of individual and social satisfaction

indicate that the maximization principle is more and more applied as a fiction.

A fiction is permissible in science if its character is clearly understood.

A fiction is a deliberate, conscious deviation from reality. A fiction, however,

is not an hypothesis or theory. By itself, a fiction is not intended to be vali-

dated by testing with empirical evidence. But a scientific fiction should be useful

as a stimulus for or as a part of hypotheses and theories which can be tested. That

means the test of a scientific fiction is its conceptual usefulness, its expediency


1/Next to mathematics and law, economics is the discipline in which scientific
fictions are most common. But the natural sciences, especially modern physics,
frequently employ fictions.


~I~ I____*_Y_________Y___111_1_____ __I


I











in understanding, explaining, and predicting reality. A fiction becomes mere

dogma and, therefore, unscientific if its two characteristics--consciousness

of its fictional nature and conceptual usefulness--are obliterated. There are

many examples in the history of science of fictions changing into dogma.

One may wonder whether or not the maximization principle has sometimes

become dogma in economics. There is increasing emphasis on techniques which

facilitate greater numerical accuracy in the determination of optima for the

firm. These same techniques are then used for maximizing social satisfaction

of whole groups with no conceptual gain and at the expense of "assuming away"

essential economic relations; an example of such use was just given (Section 5).

It was suggested above that, under certain conditions, an increase of

aggregate national income may be accepted as a criterion for resource policies.

The Pareto criterion, likewise, is suited only for ascertaining whether or not

an increase of social welfare has occurred but not for determining a maximum.

The criterion "increase of aggregate national income" can be employed

effectively in appraising water policies of more limited scope, for example, in

appraising an individual water development project or in deciding a particular

case of controversy in water allocation. This is the approach of benefit-cost

analysis referred to earlier (Sections 2 and 3). These limitations on the

applicability of this criterion are imposed by a number of theoretical and

practical difficulties some of which can be overcome only by restrictive

assumptions.








31.
The quantities of goods and services making up the national income must be

evaluated (weighted) in order to be aggregated. The weights used--market prices

and unit values derived indirectly from prices and in other ways--are affected by

income distribution and by the host of institutions which influence this distri-

bution. Both value weights and quantities are affected by market form. Policies

to be appraised may change income distribution and market form. Such an appraisal

deals with the future. Over time, individual preferences and technology--both

affecting value weights and quantities of national income--change, and these

changes are uncertain. Again, policies to be appraised affect these changes.

Besides such "structural" changes, there are changes connected with economic fluc-

tuations of various amplitude and duration. These, likewise, are related to the

policies to be appraised. All these problems are of interest for benefit-cost

analysis, input-output studies of the Leontieff type, and other systematic attempts

at a quantitative economic appraisal of policy.

Practical approximations to a solution of some of these difficulties are

possible but only under restrictive assumptions with respect to institutions,

preferences, technology, and time periods. Frequently, these assumptions are not

made explicit when public water development projects are appraised through benefit-

cost analysis and when judicial decisions and arguments before the courts involve

"equity" of water allocation and the interpretation of "reasonable" and "benefi-

cial" water use.

For policies of broader scope, the restrictive assumptions needed for benefit-

cost analysis become too burdensome. In appraising such policies, it is useful to

employ as criteria their effects upon significant conditions which facilitate or

impede an increase of aggregate national income rather than focus on such an increase

itself. This approach to policy criteria relies heavily on economic theory but


I I








32.


less on maximization. This approach is greatly interested in economic history

and in relating one time period to another but not necessarily through increasing

the number of variables and equations in mathematical models. This approach is

especially suited for natural resources policies and has been discussed in detail

elsewhere.i/

The emphasis of this approach is on minimum standards in resource use rather

than on the optimum use; on establishing base levels rather than on locating

peaks; on avoiding dead-end streets and on keeping direction rather than on com-

puting the shortest distance; on mobility and adaptability of productive factors

rather than on their optimum combination; on reducing institutional obstacles to

water development rather than on maximum development; and on provisions in water

law that facilitate changes over time in water allocation rather than on an opti-

mum water allocation at particular times and places.

This approach does not pretend to establish criteria for maximizing social

satisfaction. But it offers effective direction signals for pursuing the public

interest turn by turn.

It becomes apparent now in what sense security and flexibility of water

rights can be regarded as economic criteria and why so much attention was given

to these concepts previously (Sections 2-4). Both relate to significant condi-

tions which facilitate or impede an increase of aggregate national income in

a world of persistent but uncertain change. We saw that the criterion "security"

is as significant for water development as the criterion "flexibility"

-- - - - -- - - - - - -

1/Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V., Resource Conservation: Economics and Policies
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1952), 395p. See especially Chapter 18.











is for water allocation. We also saw that the logical polarity of these criteria

does not necessarily imply that they are "competitive" if applied in an econom-

ically meaningful way. This is a corollary of the economic interdependence of

policies concerned with water development and those concerned with water allo-

cation (Section 5).

What are the conclusions for the relations between economics and law--

taken as two important social science disciplines? Economics cannot define

social optima which the law--as "social engineering"--should aim to realize.

What economics can do, however, is to explain why and how far certain conditions,

which are decisively influenced by the law, facilitate or impede an increase of

aggregate national income. Economics can point out the essential features of

conflict situations and the probable consequences of changes in statutory pro-

visions, judicial decisions, and administrative regulations. Sometimes, these

consequences can be shown in quantitative terms under restrictive assumptions.

More often, the consequences can be indicated merely in terms of direction and

in terms of relative magnitudes and rates of change.

Economics need not be passive in fulfilling this function. Frequently, a

conflict situation can be identified in economic terms before it has arisen in

law as a controversy. After it has arisen as a controversy, the essential

economic features may not be clear to the contestants themselves.

A first, but necessary, step toward implementing such a relation between

economics and law is mutual understanding with respect to the interpretation

and application of key concepts used as economic criteria. In the area of

water law, such concepts are security and flexibility of water rights.


__1_1__111__*__1________U_ 1








34.

To such an understanding, both normative and positive economics can

make a contribution. If a value judgment is permitted, one may add that the

contribution by positive economics has been far greater and that this will

probably hold also in the future. The law, on the other hand, is essentially

a normative discipline. For this reason, doubt was already expressed (Section 1)

that "integration" of law and economics is possible or desirable. But in

spite of--or possibly because of--differences in basic orientation, positive

economics and law have many complementary relations. To explore and to

strengthen these relations will benefit both social science disciplines.




University of Florida Home Page
© 2004 - 2010 University of Florida George A. Smathers Libraries.
All rights reserved.

Acceptable Use, Copyright, and Disclaimer Statement
Last updated October 10, 2010 - - mvs