<%BANNER%>

Working the PPP! Coordination in Public-Private Partnerships

Permanent Link: http://ufdc.ufl.edu/UFE0043668/00001

Material Information

Title: Working the PPP! Coordination in Public-Private Partnerships
Physical Description: 1 online resource (209 p.)
Language: english
Creator: Garg, Swapnil
Publisher: University of Florida
Place of Publication: Gainesville, Fla.
Publication Date: 2012

Subjects

Subjects / Keywords: construction -- coordination -- highway -- india -- partnership -- ppp -- private -- public
Management -- Dissertations, Academic -- UF
Genre: Business Administration thesis, Ph.D.
bibliography   ( marcgt )
theses   ( marcgt )
government publication (state, provincial, terriorial, dependent)   ( marcgt )
born-digital   ( sobekcm )
Electronic Thesis or Dissertation

Notes

Abstract: In this dissertation, I explore how work is carried out in public-private partnerships. Considering that such partnerships are between public and private agencies whose objective is to construct and operate public infrastructure, they emerge as a distinctive context, making the coordination of work potentially different from the coordination of work in firms and alliances. As such, I propose a model that focuses on how work is carried out through the use of coordination mechanisms by the use of context specific boundary objects and common ground. The antecedents to the use of these mechanisms, it is suggested, lie in the focus of the firm’s business and the experience profile of the coordinating managers. In the context of the Indian highway industry, which has been utilizing PPPs extensively, the proposed theoretical model was tested on a unique sample of 42 highway projects being executed in the PPP mode. While the perceptions of the use of coordination mechanisms were collected by carrying out a primary survey of the managers closely involved with these projects, data on firms and managers were collected from secondary sources. The results suggest that, while a firm’s focus on the technical domain of highway construction is associated with the emphasis placed on the use of both boundary objects and common ground, these effects are amplified when the manager has PPP experience. Further, it is found that while the firm’s focus on PPP has no direct effects on the use of coordination mechanisms, if the manager tasked with the job of coordinating the project has a high firm tenure, the use common ground for coordination is deemphasized. The findings of the study – that a manager’s firm tenure significantly reduces the use of common ground for coordination when the manager’s firm tenure at a highly PPP focused firm is lengthy – are interesting in that they highlight the distinctiveness of PPP working. Also, the evidence provided by this study that managers’ experience profiles can significantly affect how coordination of work is carried out makes this an important first study in the literature studying coordination, highlighting that the quality of human capital (capabilities/experience specific to the highway industry, PPP form, and the firm) affect the management of alliances, i.e., coordination of work performed at the organization’s boundaries.
General Note: In the series University of Florida Digital Collections.
General Note: Includes vita.
Bibliography: Includes bibliographical references.
Source of Description: Description based on online resource; title from PDF title page.
Source of Description: This bibliographic record is available under the Creative Commons CC0 public domain dedication. The University of Florida Libraries, as creator of this bibliographic record, has waived all rights to it worldwide under copyright law, including all related and neighboring rights, to the extent allowed by law.
Statement of Responsibility: by Swapnil Garg.
Thesis: Thesis (Ph.D.)--University of Florida, 2012.
Local: Adviser: Paruchuri, Srikanth.
Electronic Access: RESTRICTED TO UF STUDENTS, STAFF, FACULTY, AND ON-CAMPUS USE UNTIL 2012-11-30

Record Information

Source Institution: UFRGP
Rights Management: Applicable rights reserved.
Classification: lcc - LD1780 2012
System ID: UFE0043668:00001

Permanent Link: http://ufdc.ufl.edu/UFE0043668/00001

Material Information

Title: Working the PPP! Coordination in Public-Private Partnerships
Physical Description: 1 online resource (209 p.)
Language: english
Creator: Garg, Swapnil
Publisher: University of Florida
Place of Publication: Gainesville, Fla.
Publication Date: 2012

Subjects

Subjects / Keywords: construction -- coordination -- highway -- india -- partnership -- ppp -- private -- public
Management -- Dissertations, Academic -- UF
Genre: Business Administration thesis, Ph.D.
bibliography   ( marcgt )
theses   ( marcgt )
government publication (state, provincial, terriorial, dependent)   ( marcgt )
born-digital   ( sobekcm )
Electronic Thesis or Dissertation

Notes

Abstract: In this dissertation, I explore how work is carried out in public-private partnerships. Considering that such partnerships are between public and private agencies whose objective is to construct and operate public infrastructure, they emerge as a distinctive context, making the coordination of work potentially different from the coordination of work in firms and alliances. As such, I propose a model that focuses on how work is carried out through the use of coordination mechanisms by the use of context specific boundary objects and common ground. The antecedents to the use of these mechanisms, it is suggested, lie in the focus of the firm’s business and the experience profile of the coordinating managers. In the context of the Indian highway industry, which has been utilizing PPPs extensively, the proposed theoretical model was tested on a unique sample of 42 highway projects being executed in the PPP mode. While the perceptions of the use of coordination mechanisms were collected by carrying out a primary survey of the managers closely involved with these projects, data on firms and managers were collected from secondary sources. The results suggest that, while a firm’s focus on the technical domain of highway construction is associated with the emphasis placed on the use of both boundary objects and common ground, these effects are amplified when the manager has PPP experience. Further, it is found that while the firm’s focus on PPP has no direct effects on the use of coordination mechanisms, if the manager tasked with the job of coordinating the project has a high firm tenure, the use common ground for coordination is deemphasized. The findings of the study – that a manager’s firm tenure significantly reduces the use of common ground for coordination when the manager’s firm tenure at a highly PPP focused firm is lengthy – are interesting in that they highlight the distinctiveness of PPP working. Also, the evidence provided by this study that managers’ experience profiles can significantly affect how coordination of work is carried out makes this an important first study in the literature studying coordination, highlighting that the quality of human capital (capabilities/experience specific to the highway industry, PPP form, and the firm) affect the management of alliances, i.e., coordination of work performed at the organization’s boundaries.
General Note: In the series University of Florida Digital Collections.
General Note: Includes vita.
Bibliography: Includes bibliographical references.
Source of Description: Description based on online resource; title from PDF title page.
Source of Description: This bibliographic record is available under the Creative Commons CC0 public domain dedication. The University of Florida Libraries, as creator of this bibliographic record, has waived all rights to it worldwide under copyright law, including all related and neighboring rights, to the extent allowed by law.
Statement of Responsibility: by Swapnil Garg.
Thesis: Thesis (Ph.D.)--University of Florida, 2012.
Local: Adviser: Paruchuri, Srikanth.
Electronic Access: RESTRICTED TO UF STUDENTS, STAFF, FACULTY, AND ON-CAMPUS USE UNTIL 2012-11-30

Record Information

Source Institution: UFRGP
Rights Management: Applicable rights reserved.
Classification: lcc - LD1780 2012
System ID: UFE0043668:00001


This item has the following downloads:


Full Text

PAGE 1

1 WORKING THE PPP! COORDINATION IN PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS By SWAPNIL GARG A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA 201 2

PAGE 2

2 201 2 Swapnil Garg

PAGE 3

3 To my wife Archana and my handsome boys Shaaranya and Saarthak

PAGE 4

4 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The pursuit of a mid career Ph.D. especially when done as an international student has its own nuances. It is no longer an individual academic pursuit, but instead an attempt made while standing on the shoulders of many others One faces a multitude of challenges in this undertaking which include think ing like a student ( once again ) adjust ing to a new culture, tak ing care of a family liv ing on a student stipend and -and no small feat -doing all of this simultaneously Identifying eve ryone who has contributed to this journey would make it an unwieldy list ; therefore I am only attempt ing to acknowledge those few without who se efforts th e completion of this dissertation would not have been possible. After coming from a long stin t in the railway industry (I returned to school after almost 20 years) one is n ot only required to shift his paradigms, but his adviser has to painfully live through th is transition as well. I am grateful and indebted to Srikanth Paruchuri for this The Ph D j ourney could not possibly have been undertaken and finally culminated without his continuous guidance, advice, and handholding I remain obliged to him for everything ( and there are lots of things ) that he has helped me with along the way. H e has demonstra ted immense patience and persistence during this long journey, and needless to say, no part of this adventure would have been possible without him. I am also thankful to my other committee members Dr. Henry Tosi, Dr Sanford Berg, and Dr Gwendolyn Lee -who not only agree d to be on the committee, but also time and again spent hours talking to me and helping me understand what I was trying to say. I gratefully acknowledge the guidance provided by Dr Berg in grounding me more b roadly while examining specifics T he support provided by Gwen and Dr Tosi, by

PAGE 5

5 way of devoting their valuable time discussing the dissertation and helping me focus on key elements of my ideas, is greatly appreciated. My mid career Ph D has been the most difficult for my wife a nd children My aspirations uprooted them five years ago and now at the end of this journey I uproot them once again to return to my job. No part of this exercise could have been possible without the subtle permission of my wife Archana who allowed me t o dream and keep moving, while she sp iritedly t ook care of things at home. It all started when I had to leave our beautiful house in India to join the program, leaving a newborn Saarthak and a 20 month old Shaaranya with her to care for alone. She has had her hands more th a n full since then b e it caring for the growing boys, taking care of the house hold chores by herself or even traveling internationally with two toddlers. She herself achieved many firsts during this journey, including lear ning to drive thereby conquering one o f her greatest fears. The boys have also had a chance to experience a new culture and environment, and I am hopeful that they w ill retain many good things from it in addition to growing up from babies to handsome bo ys I would be failing in my duties if I did not acknowledge the crucial role played by my parents and in laws in enabling me to take this journey. While I was attempting to follow in my father s footsteps and earn a higher degree, my mother stood beside m e and assured me that she w ould not let anything get in my way always placed a hand behind me, providing me countless assurances that I could count on them whenever I needed any help. I am lucky to have a large extended family of brothers, aunts, uncles, cousins their families, and a close set of friends ; and I have no hesitation in saying that they

PAGE 6

6 have been of great support to me during this journey by helping me collect data for my research, getting my study leave sanctioned and extended, or just hosting us Puneet P rakash, my school pal, needs a special mention here. He not only played a very important role in my embarking on this venture but has also been a continuous source of guidance and advice. My fellow Ph D students in the department have be e n of great help as my family and I have made this venture enabling us to understand, learn and live in a new culture. I cannot help but mention the important role played by James Van Scotter my office mate throughout the program a nd Marie Ha l vorsen Ganepola m y English teacher s I am thankful for the time that t he y and others have spent, making us feel at home in a new country Lyndsay B rown has also helped me immensely in internalizing the conventions of written English, and the credit for making this dissertation readable wholly goes to her. Finally, I need to thank Indian Railways, the organization for which I work, and which is a second home for me The organization has take n care of me for more th a n 20 years now and has been generous in sanctioning m e leave to pursue a Ph D program and follow my dreams

PAGE 7

7 TABLE OF CONTENTS page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ................................ ................................ ................................ ... 4 LIST OF TABLES ................................ ................................ ................................ ........... 10 LIST OF FIGURES ................................ ................................ ................................ ......... 11 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS ................................ ................................ ............................ 12 ABSTRACT ................................ ................................ ................................ .................... 13 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION ................................ ................................ ................................ ..... 15 Organizations and Coordination ................................ ................................ .............. 15 Plural Forms of Organizations ................................ ................................ ................. 16 Need to study Working of the PPP Form ................................ ................................ 16 Focus of the Dissertation ................................ ................................ ......................... 17 Structure of the Dissertation ................................ ................................ .................... 19 2 LITERATURE REVIEW ON COORDINATION ................................ ........................ 21 Coordination and Alliances ................................ ................................ ...................... 22 Antecedents of Coordination in Alliances ................................ .......................... 23 Alliance task characteristics and coordination ................................ ............ 24 Alliance firms characteristics and coordination ................................ .......... 25 Ex ante control and coordination ................................ ................................ 27 Alliance duration and coordination ................................ .............................. 27 Coordination in Organizations ................................ ................................ .................. 29 Coordination Mechanism Structuring of Work ................................ ................ 33 Coordination Mechanism Use of Purposively Created Boundary Objects ...... 34 Coordination Mechanism Use of Common Ground ................................ ........ 35 Determinants of Use of Coordination Mechanisms ................................ ........... 36 Existing State of Coordination Literature ................................ ................................ 37 Human Interface and Coordination ................................ ................................ .......... 39 3 LITERATURE ON PPPs ................................ ................................ .......................... 47 Review of Literature on PPPs ................................ ................................ .................. 47 Overview of Literature on PPP ................................ ................................ .......... 48 Organizational Literature on PPP and the Gaps Therein ................................ .. 50 Distinctive Aspects of PPPs ................................ ................................ ..................... 52 Government as an Alliance Partner ................................ ................................ .. 52 Delivery of a Public Infrastructure ................................ ................................ ..... 55

PAGE 8

8 The Formation and Structuring of an Indian Highway PPP Project ......................... 61 Formation of PPPs ................................ ................................ ............................ 61 Execution and Management of PPPs ................................ ................................ 63 Structuring of PPPs to Address their Distinctive Aspects ................................ ........ 67 4 THEORY AND HYPOTHESES ................................ ................................ ................ 74 Different Mechanisms of Coordination ................................ ................................ ..... 75 Coordination by Structuring of Work ................................ ................................ 75 Coordination by Use of Boundary Objects ................................ ........................ 76 Coordination by Use of Common Ground ................................ ......................... 76 ................................ ................................ ................ 77 .......................... 80 ........... 82 ............ 85 ................................ 88 ................. 89 ground for coordination .................. 91 ................................ ................................ 93 ............ 94 .................... 95 undary objects .......................... 97 ................................ ... 99 ........... 100 .................... 100 on ground .......................... 102 ................................ .. 103 5 METHODS AND ANALYSIS ................................ ................................ .................. 107 Empirical Context of the Study ................................ ................................ .............. 108 Highway Construction in India ................................ ................................ ......... 108 Private Participation in Indian Highway Sector ................................ ................ 110 Data Collection ................................ ................................ ................................ ...... 113 Sample Universe of Projects ................................ ................................ ........... 113 Preparation of the Survey Questionnaire ................................ ........................ 11 5 Administration of the Survey ................................ ................................ ........... 117 Measurement of the Variables ................................ ................................ ............... 120 ................................ ................................ ............................ 120 ................................ ............................... 122 ................................ ......................... 122 ................................ ................................ .............. 123 ................................ ................................ ..................... 123 Use of Boundary Objects for Coordination ................................ ...................... 124 Use of Common Ground for Coordination ................................ ....................... 125 Amount of Coordination ................................ ................................ ................... 125 Use of Contract for Coordination ................................ ................................ ..... 126

PAGE 9

9 Project Specific Characteristics ................................ ................................ ....... 127 Firm Specific Characteristics ................................ ................................ ........... 129 Discriminate Analysis of the Survey Measures ................................ ...................... 129 6 RESULTS ................................ ................................ ................................ .............. 132 Variables and their Correlations ................................ ................................ ............. 132 Regression Results ................................ ................................ ................................ 134 Antecedents to the Use of Boundary Objects for Coordination ....................... 134 Antecedents to the Use of Common Ground for Coordination ........................ 135 Robustness Check ................................ ................................ .......................... 137 Alternativ e Model ................................ ................................ ................................ ... 137 7 DISCUSSION ................................ ................................ ................................ ........ 153 An Integrative Coordination Perspective ................................ ................................ 154 Contributions to Current Literature ................................ ................................ .. 154 Coordination mechanisms used at organizational interfaces .................... 154 Role of the manager in coordination ................................ ......................... 156 Developing the Coordination Perspective ................................ ....................... 161 Aspects of coordination ................................ ................................ ............. 162 Relating mechanisms and aspects of coordination ................................ ... 165 The PPP Context ................................ ................................ ................................ ... 168 Structuring and Working of PPPs ................................ ................................ .... 169 ................................ ................................ ....................... 170 Role o ................................ ................................ ........ 172 8 CONCLUSIONS ................................ ................................ ................................ .... 176 Summary of Findings ................................ ................................ ............................. 176 Limitations and Future Directions ................................ ................................ .......... 177 Implications for Managers ................................ ................................ ...................... 181 Locat ion in Current Thought and Final Words ................................ ....................... 183 APPENDIX SURVEY FORM ................................ ................................ ....................... 185 LIST OF REFERENCES ................................ ................................ .............................. 191 BIOGRAPH ICAL SKETCH ................................ ................................ ........................... 208

PAGE 10

10 LIST OF TABLES Table page 2 1 Coordination mechanisms discussed in the literature. ................................ ........ 42 3 1 Structuring of PPP to address its distinctive aspects ................................ ........... 73 4 1 Summary of hypothesis ................................ ................................ ..................... 106 5 1 Results of exploratory and confirmatory factor analysis of the coordination survey items ................................ ................................ ................................ ...... 131 6 1 Summary of variables and correlations ................................ ............................. 141 6 2 Antecedents to the use of b oundary objects in PPP projects ............................ 142 6 3 Antecedents to the use of common ground in PPP projects. ............................ 143 6 4 Robustness check ................................ ................................ ............................ 144 6 5 Alternate model results. ................................ ................................ ..................... 145 7 1 Mechanisms and aspects of coordination. ................................ ........................ 175

PAGE 11

11 LIST OF FIGUR ES Figure page 3 1 Structure of a PPP. ................................ ................................ .............................. 72 4 1 Proposed model to study the effect of firm and managers experience on the emphasis placed on mechanisms of coordination. ................................ ............ 105 6 1 experience on use of boundary objects. ................................ ............................ 146 6 2 experience on use of common ground. ................................ ............................. 147 6 3 on use of common ground. ................................ ................................ ................ 148 6 4 The alternate model ................................ ................................ .......................... 149 6 5 Plot of interaction effects in alternate model. ................................ ..................... 150

PAGE 12

12 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS B2B Business to Business BOT Build, Operate, Transfer BOLT Build, Operate, Lease, Transfer DBFO Design, Build, Finance, Operate HSBO Highway Specific Boundary Object IC Independent Consultant IR Indian Railways Government o f India MORTH Ministry of Road Transport and Highways, Government o f India NHAI National Highway Authority of India, G ov ernment o f India OLS Ordinary Least Square PD Project Director PFI Public Finance Initiative PM Project Manager PPP Public P rivate P artnershi p SPV Special Purpose Vehicle SUR Seemingly Unrelated Regression

PAGE 13

13 Abstract of Dissertation Presented to the Graduate School of the University of Florida in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy WORKING THE PPP! COORDINATION IN PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS By Swapnil Garg May 201 2 Chair: Srikanth Paruchuri Major: Business Administration In this dissertation, I explore how work is carried out in p ublic private partnerships. Considering that such partnerships are between public and private agencies whose objective is to construct and operate public infrastructure, they emerge as a distinctive context, making the coordination of work potentially diff erent from the coordination of work in firms and alliances. As such, I propose a model that focuses on how work is carried out through the use of coordination mechanisms by the use of context specific boundary objects and common ground. The antecedents to the use of these mechanisms it is suggested lie in the focus of the firm business and the experience profile of the coordinating managers. In the context of the Indian h ighway i ndustry which has been utilizing PPPs extensively the proposed theoretica l model was tested on a unique sample of 42 highway projects being executed in the PPP mode. While the perceptions o f the use of coordination mechanisms were collected by carrying out a primary survey of the

PAGE 14

14 managers closely involved with these projects, d ata on firms and managers w ere collected from secondary sources. The results suggest that while a firm s focus on the technical domain of highway construction is associated with the emphasis placed on the use of both boundary objects and common ground, these effects are amplified when the manager has PPP on the use of coordination mechanism s if the manager tasked with the job of coordinating the project has a high firm tenure, the use common ground for coordination is deemphasized. The finding s of the study that a reduces the use of common ground for coordination when the manag er s firm tenure at a highly PPP focused firm is lengthy are interesting in that they highlight th e distinctiveness of PPP working Also, the evidence provided by this study that managers experience profiles can significantly affect how coordination of work is carried out makes this a n important first study in th e literature studying coordination highlighting that the quality of human capital ( i.e., capabilities/experience specific to the highway industry, PPP form, and the firm) affect the management of alliances ( i.e., coordination of work performed at the organization s boundaries ).

PAGE 15

15 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION Organizations a nd Coordination Organizations need to coordinate their work to achieve their fundamental purpose, making the study of coordination t he prime focus of organization theorists (Daft & Lengel, 1986; March & Simon, 1958; Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967; Thompson, 1967; Van de Ven, Delbecq, & Koenig, 1976). Here, coordination of hat organizations perform (Gittell, 2002; Malone & Crowston, 1994), and the coordination perspective refers to all of the different modes used to organize work in organizations: differentiation, centralization, formalization, and integration at the system level; along with routinization, discretion, significance determination, and feedback at the sub system level (Sinha & Van de Ven, 2005). Accordingly, organizational studies focusing on coordination seek to study the source of interdependence between work activities, mechanisms deployed to manage interdependence, and the antecedents and consequences of these mechanisms. Th e coordination perspective was central to early organizational studies and led to various different paradigms in organizational theory, s uch as the contingency theory, the configuration perspective, and the complexity perspective (Sinha & Van de Ven, 2005). However, both the gradual change in the nature of work over time (Barley & Kunda, 2001), and the fact that work is being done simultane ously between and within organizational boundaries (Sinha & Van de Ven, 2005), have over time combined to make it increasingly challenging to design, organize, and perform work efficiently and effectively.

PAGE 16

16 Hence, there is a need to study and develop a more comprehensive coordination framework that focuses on these new ways in which work is performed. Plural Forms o f Organizations O rganizations and their different forms are ubiquitous in their presence (Scott, 1998). Moreover, recent times have witnessed the emergence of many plural forms of organizations as larger and larger amounts of work have been organized in some form of an alliance, either viewed as a swollen middle on the continuum of market and hierarchies (Hennart, 1988), or as a swell in the network of organizing work (Gomes Casseres, 1996). At the same time, organizational scholars also recognize that the government plays an important role in determining how organizations work (McEvily Perro ne, & Zaheer, 1999; Owen Smith & Powell, 2004). However, the government has generally been seen as shaping the structure and composition of the organizational field, by creating institutions at different levels of the society and contextualizing the behavi or of organizations (Campbell, 2004; McDermott, Corredoira, & Kruse, 2009; Ring, Bigley, D'Aunno, & Khanna, 2005 ; Thelen, 2004 ) Unique to recent developments is the emergence of p ublic private partnerships (henceforth referred to as PPP) which while bein g plural forms of organizations are an alliance not between private firms, but an alliance between the government and a private firm. Need t o S tudy Work ing of t he PPP Form Specifically acknowledging the emergence of the PPP form of organiz ations a number of theorists have recognized the need for studies that examine how they work For instance, Kale and Singh (2009), reviewing the strategic alliance

PAGE 17

17 literature, viewed PPPs as a new class of alliances, and found that the current strategic allianc e literature has little to say on successfully managing this class. They argued that the objective functions of the partners are different in these alliances, and the partners bring diverse skill sets and organizational cultures, creating very different ch allenges for the management of the organization. They also foresaw a rich alliance research agenda, which focuses on the study of this class of alliances. Similarly, McGahan Mahoney, and Pitelis (2009) argued that while public and private interests are in terdependent, management scholars restrict themselves to the study of private firms, while public policy scholars study only public agencies, such as governmental, multilateral, community, and non profit organizations. The authors also identified that neit her management scholars nor public policy scholars examine the organizations that emerge out of the interdependencies that exist between public agencies and for profit agencies and scholars need to address this gap. These same authors also recognized that large differences exist between private and public interests, and that there is a need to develop new theories of public private interactions, so that organizational and institutional configurations and strategies relevant to this context can be identified Focus o f t h e Dissertation In this dissertation, I propose to study coordination of work in a new form of organization: public private partnerships (PPP). We have little understanding of this new form of work organization (Kale & Singh, 2009; Mahoney et al., 2009), which spans the boundaries of public agencies and private firms. PPPs are different from the for profit strategic alliances studied in organizational theory,

PAGE 18

18 both on account of the public nature of one of the actors i.e., the government, and t Wassenhove, 2006; Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). A t the public private interface, PPPs have emerged as an attractive option for the delivery of public infrastructure the world over, and is gradually taking over functions that have traditionally been performed by the government. With this background, I seek to understand how PPPs work, borrowing insights from literature on coordination in organizations and in alliances. More specifically, the study answers the following research questions: RQ1 What are the antecedents to the use of different mechanisms of work coordination? RQ2 coordination mechanisms? RQ3 How do PPPs coordinate work? What coordination mechanisms do they use and why? The study has been conducted in the context of the Indian highway construction industry, which has in the last decade increased its capacity for constructing and upgrading highways from 5 km of high way per day to 20 km of highway per day. That is, between 2009 and 2015, India proposes to upgrade 7000 km of highway each year (I ndia Infrastructure Research, 2010). An investment of almost 69 billion USD in the development of the Indian highway sector is expected between 2007 and 2012, and a sizeable portion of this ( i.e., 3 4 % ) will come from the private sector. And i ncreasingly, t he PPP mode of highway development has emerged as the dominant mode for private participation in th e sector Such PPP projects are of prime importance to fueling

PAGE 19

19 the infrastructure led growth of India; hence, these projects are approved and monitored for performance at the highest level. For example, all road projects costing more than $200 million are approved and mo nitored by the Cabinet Committee of India, whose chairman is the Prime Minister. As of September 1, 2010, about 250 national highway projects were in the construction phase, 126 of which are being undertaken through the PPP mode. A significant but lesser n umber of projects have also been taken up at the state level. The context of this study lies in the 126 national and 53 state highway construction projects being undertaken through the PPP mode. Structure o f t he Dissertation Chapter 2 carries out a review of relevant literature, which can potentially guide us in understanding how coordination is done in PPPs. Thus, the review summarizes the literature studying coordination in the alliance context, and also identifies the use of different coordination mecha nisms in organizations. With this understanding, the gaps in the coordination literature are summarized. Chapter 3 develops the theoretical context of PPP working, and while discussing the unique aspects of PPP, identifies how PPP are accordingly structure d and managed. The theory development is carried out in Chapter 4 and a theoretical model of PPP working is proposed. While providing an overview of the Indian highway construction industry, which forms the empirical context for this study, Chapter 5 elabo rates on the measures and methods used in carrying out the empirical study Chapter 6 reports the results of the empirical study, and also puts forward some preliminarily findings of an alternate way in which the theoretical model can be conceptualized. Th e primary results of the empirical study are discussed in

PAGE 20

20 Chapter 7. Further, while elaborating on the theme of coordination, Chapter 7 also highlights the importance of identifying the aspects of work in which coordination is carried out, moving beyond th e mechanisms and antecedents of coordination. It also discusses how special purpose vehicles used in PPPs distance the firm from project level working, and this distance significantly affects how work is performed in PPPs. The dissertation ends with Chapte r 8, which highlights the managerial implications of the study, as well as its limitations and future directions The appendix presents the questionnaire used to survey how

PAGE 21

21 CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW ON COORDINATIO N In this dissertation I study the working of PPPs, viewing them as a plural form of an organizational arrangement between private firms and the government. 1 Organizational theorists are guided by what they know about the pure forms while studying plural o rganizational forms, as the study of work in the pure forms leads to a better understanding of how work is performed in the plural forms. For instance, while studying the different ways in which economic activity is organized, Williamson (1985) identified the two pure organizational forms as markets and firm based hierarchies. Accordingly, organizational theorists saw alliances as an intermediate form of economic activity organizing, lying between markets and hierarchies, and sharing attributes with both (H ennart, 1988). Later, while examining the alliance form, Powell (1990) emphasized that alliances should be viewed as a distinctive pure form of organization: the network form. Following this paradigm, PPPs can be viewed as a plural form lying between netwo rks (more specifically strategic alliances) and hierarchies, which implies that the study of PPP working should be guided by what we know about coordination of work in both alliance and organizational contexts. The study of coordination is the prime conce rn for organizational theorists, as the coordination of work is the primary means by which organizations achieve their fundamental purpose (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967; Thompson, 1967). Hence, an extensive body of literature exists in this field, and a numbe r of !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 The terms organization and firm are used differently from here on. While the term organization is used in a generic way, and refers to all possible arrangements wherein work is performed, the term firm specifically refers to a hierarchical arrangement in which work is performed.

PAGE 22

22 reviews of the literature exist, the most recent conducted by Okhuysen and Bechky (2009). As I delved into this rich literature, it emerged that literature studying coordination in alliances highlights the importance of coordination, and seeks to iden tify the antecedents and consequences of the extent to which firms coordinate in their alliances. On the other hand, the literature studying coordination in organizations seeks to identify the different mechanisms that are used to bring about coordination. With the focus of this study on PPPs, this review is guided by coordination literature in both the alliance and organizational contexts. However, the review is selective and emphasizes the different foci of these literatures. While reviewing the alliance literature, the focus is on how coordination is conceptualized and on the antecedents of coordination. On the other hand, organizational literature is reviewed with the objective of identifying the different mechanisms of coordination. The review will sum marize the current state of the literature on the use of mechanisms of coordination, identifying their antecedents, and pinpointing the gaps therein. Coordination and A lliances between ac A lliances witness higher levels of coordination challenges as here firms interdependently perform and manage task activities (Child & Faulkner, 1998; de Rond & Bouchikhi, 2004; Harrigan, 1985). The coord ination challenges that firms face while working in alliances are determined both by the characteristics of the firms performing the tasks (Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967), and also by how the task is interdependently

PAGE 23

23 performed (Thompson, 1967). Thus, alliance sc holars study the factors leading to coordination challenges and the extent to which firms coordinate work in alliances. The empirical setting contextualizes how the degree of coordination in alliances is conceptualized 2 For example, White and Lui (2005) studied coordination in contractual alliances between architects and general contractors in the Hong Kong construction industry, and the context led them to conceptualize coordination in terms of the amount of time and ef fort that the partners spend together to coordinate work. On the other hand, Carson, Madhok, Varman, and John (2003), in their study of inter firm R&D collaborations, conceptualized coordination as the relative distribution of work between the coordinating agencies in terms of dollar value, value added, hours worked, and amount of research and development work. In contrast, Gulati & Sytch (2007), while studying the long term procurement relationships of US auto manufacturers, conceptualized coordination as the degree to which the partners coordinate in the ten joint actions that they perform together. Antecedents of C oordination in A lliances Alliance literature identifies the determinants of coordination challenges to lie in task characteristics, firm chara cteristics, ex ante control, and alliance characteristics. This literature is reviewed to identify both the antecedents and !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 2 This contextualization is not a concern here, as the extent of coordination is a one dimensional construct. In the various ways that coordination has been conceptualized in alliance settings, it fully serves to capture the exten t to which firms coordinate in the alliance.

PAGE 24

24 the mechanisms by which these antecedents affect the extent to which firms coordinate in the alliance. Alliance task characteristi cs and coordination As the characteristics of the alliance task mold the interdependence of the firms, the task determines the degree to which coordination challenges arise and firms coordinate (Bensaou & Venkatraman, 1995; Gerwin, 2004; Sobrero & Schrade r, 1998; Srikanth & Puranam, 201 0 ). Task characteristics, conceptualized in terms of asset specificity, complexity, and interdependence, have been found to determine the degree to which firms coordinate When the asset specificity of the alliance task is high, the investments made by firms in the alliance lead to a hostage situation for the firm. Consequently, firms work towards protecting their alliance specific investments, and alliances witness higher levels of coordination; empirical evidence supports this argument. In long term purchase relationships, the asset specificity of the task is found to be positively associated with both the extent to which the purchaser and the supplier take joint actions (Gulati & Sytch, 2007; Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1 998), and the extent to which they make joint decisions (Subramani & Venkatraman, 2003). Similarly, in the context of long term contractual alliances in the construction industry, the asset specificity of the task is found to be positively associated with the amount of time and effort spent by partners in coordinating the alliance (White & Lui, 2005). A complex task is characterized with a higher level of task interdependence, and requires a higher amount of coordination for its accomplishment (Thompson, 1967; Tushman & Nadler, 1978). In a study of long term purchase relat ionships,

PAGE 25

25 Gulati and Sytch (2007) find that task interdependence increases the propensity of alliance firms to take joint actions. Also, White and Lui (2005) find the increase in the value of the task increase s the time and effort firms spend on coordinati on, as higher value tasks are more complex, and complex tasks require more coordination. More recently, Srikanth & Puranam (201 0 ) studied coordination in the context of outsourcing with similar findings. They found that the use of coordination mechanisms such as task modularity, the amount of ongoing communication, and the use of tacit coordination mechanisms reduce the negative impact of task interdependence on the performance of the outsourcing activity. Alliance firms characteristics and coordinatio n Firms vary in their ability to coordinate the alliance task (Gerwin, 2004). In manage software deliveries leads to a higher level of joint action by the partners (Schreiner, Kale, & Corsten, 2009). expertise in the task, but also from its ability to work with others. This ability to work with others comes from prior experience. Experience in managing alliances reduces the time and effort firms need to coordinate in alliance (White & Lui, 2005), and also lowers the costs that the firm incurs in coordinating subsequent alliances (Lorenzoni & Lipparini, 1999). Also, the capability of a firm in managing al liances has been found to improve both alliance and firm performance (Heimeriks & Duysters, 2007; Kale, Dyer, & Singh, 2002). The alliance capability

PAGE 26

26 of a firm lies in the Alliance Function, the dedicated function that firms create for managing their allia nces (Dyer, Kale, & Singh, 2001). Besides the capability of individual firms in the alliance, the differences and complementarities between the coordinating firms also affect coordination (Harrigan, 1985). While firm level differences in goals and procedu res increase coordination challenges, and require partners to spend more time and effort in coordinating alliance activities (White & Lui, 2005), the firm level complementarities increase the propensity of firms to take joint action (Schreiner, Kale, & Cor sten, 2009). On the other hand, the lack of differences between firms in an alliance (i.e., sameness) leads to a reduction in coordination challenges (Harrigan, 1985). As similar firms in an alliance possess a common language, this enables communication be tween them, reducing coordination challenges (Heath & Staudenmayer, 2000; Simon, 19 45 ). Also, similarities in alliance forming firms enable them to bond with one another and take joint actions (Schreiner, Kale, & Corsten, 2009; Zaheer & Venkatraman, 1995). Specifically, in a survey of 250 managers of the software services industry, Schreiner, Kale, and Corsten (2009) found that the ability of a firm to bond with its partners leads to joint action by them. Similarly, Zaheer and Venkataraman (1995) in an emp irical study of service relationships between insurance firms and their agents in the US property and casualty insurance industry, found reciprocal investments by firms to be highly correlated with joint actions taken by them. They argued in support of the se e ffects as reciprocal investment reflects the mutual commitment of the partners and enables economic bonding between the alliance firms

PAGE 27

27 Ex ante control and coordination Coordination has performance implications in alliance contexts (Gerwin, 2004; Sch ilke & Goerzen, 2010). Hence, in pursuit of superior performance, managers attempt to design alliances that promote coordination between partners (Vlaar, Van Den Bosch, & Volberda, 2007). Thus, the design of ex ante controls, such as contracts and equity s tructures, is an important antecedent of coordination in alliances. For instance, in the context of long term vertical purchase agreements, an increase in the completeness of the contract has been found to lead to an increase in the extent of coordination (Mesquita & Brush, 2008). Similarly, as in sequential alliances, coordination manifests as joint sense making by the alliance partners; narrowly scoped and very specific contracts have been found to limit joint sense making by the partners, while broadly s coped and less specific contracts have been found to encourage it (Faems, Janssens, Madhok, & Van Looy, 2008). Other than contracts, the level of equity contributed by the firms in the alliance also serves as an ex ante control leads to a higher firm emb eddedness and enables both richer communication and closer working between the alliance partners. Accordingly, an increase in the level of equity invested by the firms in the alliance has been found to increase coordination between alliance firms, measure d as the speed of knowledge transfer between the partners (Oxley & Wada, 2009). Alliance duration and coordination As working together in an alliance for an extended time increases the allenges are

PAGE 28

28 likely to decrease with an increase in alliance duration (Gerwin, 2004). However, there is weak empirical evidence to support this argument. Alliance duration has been found to be an insignificant predictor of coordination in terms of time and effort spent in coordinating (White & Lui, 2005), and a marginal predictor of coordination in terms of joint actions taken (Gulati & Sytch, 2007; Subramani & Venkatraman, 2003; Schreiner, Kale, & Corsten, 2009; Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1998). While th e previously reviewed studies highlight the importance of coordination in the alliance context, and identify the antecedents of coordination to lie in task, firm, and alliance characteristics, they have little to say about how coordination gets done ( i.e., the mechanisms of coordination that firms use ) While a recent s tudy by Srikanth & Puranam (2010 ) examines the use of mechanisms of coordination in the context of business process off shoring, it primarily considers how the negative performance of task in terdependence is molded differently by the use of different coordination mechanisms, and does not explore the antecedents to the use of different coordination mechanisms. The importance of studying how coordination is carried out in alliances becomes all the more important when we recognize that the seminal studies in organizational theory (i.e., Lawrence & Lorsch (1967), Thompson (1967), and Van de Ven, Delbecq, & Koenig (1976)), which have guided the study of coordination in both alliances and organizati ons, took great pains to identify and differentiate among the various coordination mechanisms that firms can use, and

PAGE 29

29 implications. A l ack of studies focusing on how coordination is do ne in alliances is a significant gap in the alliance literature, one which this dissertation seeks to address this gap. To be able to study how coordination is carried out in alliances, we need to be better informed about all the possible mechanisms of co ordination that can be used. The organizational literature that has emerged in the last four decades has studied the different mechanisms of coordination; hence it can guide such a study. Accordingly, the organizational coordination literature is reviewed next, with a narrow focus on studies that seek to identify the different ways in which firms coordinate work. Coordination in O rganizations The formal study of coordination began shortly after the appearance of railroads, and the emergence of large scale manufacturing (Scott & Davis, 2007). However, early studies focused on the design of work to bring about coordination, 1962). The later studies conducted in the early twentieth century focused on the design of organizations to bring about coordination, and sought to study how the uncertainties rooted in task, technology, and environment could be addressed by designing and structuring organizations (Okhuysen & Bechky, 200 9 ). The d esignability of work and organizations is the central assumption in both these streams of literature, and they emphasize that deliberate attempts are required in both planning and executi o n to coordinate the work activity However, scholars contributing to this early stream of literature also recognized that coordination had an emergent dimension (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ). For instance,

PAGE 30

30 organizations formalize their work to different degrees (Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967), rely on mutual adjustments (Thompson, 1 967), use lateral relations (Galbraith, 1973) and use ad h oc mechanisms (Donaldson, 2001) to coordinate their work. As it is difficult for scholars to measure these informal and emergent dimensions, while the early research used them as catch all categorie s, in the last two of decades organ izational research has be e n using innovative methods to conceptualize and measure these dimensions (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ). However, recent studies of the emergent ways of coordination continue to be guided by the semi nal studies by Lawrence and Lorsch (1967) and Thompson (1967). These authors were the first to recognize that coordination could be carried out in many different ways. Whereas Lawrence and Lorsch (1967) argued that coordination of work can be carried out b y both hierarchies and integrating teams, Thompson (1967) identified three conceptua lly distinct ways by which coordination is achieved: structuring of work, planning, and mutual adjustment. While guided by these seminal studies, scholars have further iden tified many different ways of coordination: group, personal, and impersonal modes (Van de Ven, Delbecq, & Koenig, 1976), formal and informal modes (Fang & Zou, 2010; Gulati, Lawrence, & Puranam, 2005; Jansen, Tempelaar, Van Den Bosch, & Volberda, 2009; Mar tinez & Jarillo, 1989) or programmed and non programmed modes (Argote, 1982). Table 2 1 lists the different coordination mechanisms that have been studied in this extensive literature. The different ways in which the mechanisms of coordination have been e xamined creates a conceptual problem in our ability to aggregate their findings

PAGE 31

31 (Grandori, 1997 a, b ). For example, it is unclear whether the use of groups for coordination (Van de Ven, Delbecq, & Koenig, 1976) is an informal / formal mechanism of coordinati on or whether it is a programmed / non programmed mechanism of coordination. One of the reasons for this conceptual problem is to study is driven by the context of the empirical studies. For instance, Ar gote (1982) was studying the working of hospital emergency units under conditions of uncertainty and hence chose to study the differences in the dominant ways that these units coordinated their work. Most relevant to the context studied, she chose to stud y the antecedents and consequences of programmed and non programmed modes of work coordination. On the other hand, Van de Ven, Delbecq, and Koenig (1976) stud ied the antecedents and consequences of the group, personal, and impersonal mechanisms of coordina tion, as these modes of coordination were most relevant in the context of state employment security agencies, whose working they were studying. Further, Jansen, Tempelaar, Van Den Bosch, and Volberda (2009) identified coordination mechanisms like senior ma nagement team rewards, senior management team integration, and cross functional interfaces, as being most relevant to their context, given their examination of how structural differentiation in organizations related with organizational ambidexterity in a c ross industry sample of firms. While such empirical studies are very valuable, we face difficulties in aggregating their findings. Two recent studies make considerable headway in our ability to aggregate these findings. Srikanth & Puranam (201 0 ) identify three distinct and generic

PAGE 32

32 coordination strategies: (a) redesign of task and use of standardized procedures, (b) creation of reciprocal predictability through e xtensive opportunities for communication, and (c) reliance on common ground. Similarly, Okhuysen & Bechky (20 09 ) identify different mechanism of coordination, but emphasize that these coordination mechanisms coordinate work by bring ing about the integrating conditions of (a) accountability, (b) predictability, and (c) common understanding Hence, whi le a consensus emerges among researchers o n the underlying theoretical ways in which the different coordination mechanisms work generic strategies or integrating conditions there still exists a lack of consensus on how to categorize the different mechanisms of coordination. For instance, while Okhuysen & Bechky (20 09 ) identify the coordination mechanism s as plans and rules, objects and representations, roles, routines, and proximity, Srikanth & Puranam (201 0 ) identify these as modularity, ongoing c ommunication, and the use of tacit coordination mechanisms. However, the recognition that coordination is differently achieved by mechanisms that (a) structure the work, (b) use purposively created boundary objects, and (c) rely on common ground is common to the ways in which they identify coordination mechanisms In Table 2 1 this three fold categorization has been used to categorize the different coordination mechanisms studied in the literature reviewed. The three distinct categories of mechanisms of coo rdination identified above are discussed next along with the distinctive ways in which they bring about coordination. 3 !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 3 Coordination of work serves two distinct purposes ( i.e., it structures and it mobilizes work elements (McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003) ) S tructuring refers to development, maintenance, and modification of t he system (McEvily, Perrone,

PAGE 33

33 Coordination M echanism S tructur ing of W ork The important role of both the design of work and the design of organizations in bringing about coordination has long been recognized (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ). Despite the change in the nature of work, blurring of organ izational boundaries, and the emerge nce of plural forms of organizations, such structuring mechanisms continue to be of importance and overtime many new ways of structuring have also been identified. For instance, both work and organizations can be designed using modules (Baldwin & Clark, 2000; Sanchez & Mahoney, 199 4 ), work output can be standardized (Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Glouberman & Mintzberg, 2001), and formal contracts can be used to coordinate work (Faems, Janssens, Madhok, & Van Looy, 2008; Reuer & Arino, 2007). With a focus o n deliberate design, the coordination mechanisms emphasizing structuring are primarily ex ante and formal in nature. The structuring of the work task serves to reduce coordination challenges by reducing the interdependence in the agencies performing the ta sk (Baldwin & Clark, 2000). It also enables coordination by putting in place an elaborate incentive alignment that not only specifies who has to do what ( i.e., the roles and responsibilities of agencies involved ) but also specifies the benefits and punish ments coordinating agencies receive for fulfilling or not fulfilling their duties (Deshpande & Zaltman, 1992; Mom, Van den Bosch, & Volberda, 2010; Poppo & !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!! & Zaheer, 2003) such that structur ing design s the coordination mechanism to facilitate the exercise of the appropriate coordination processes (Thompson, 1967: pg 64) On the other hand, mobilization refers to aggregating the w orking procedures for implementing the process of converting resources into finalized activities performed by interdependent actors (McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003)

PAGE 34

34 Zenger, 2002). Thus they bring about consensus between the coordinating agencies in regards to their expectations and responsibilities. When firms come together to work, the structuring of the work and of the organization both refer to the formal contract that firms sign to form an alliance. It is the formal contract that brings about an alignment of in centives between the different alliance firms, distributes the work among the firms in the alliance, and defines the specific roles and responsibilities of the firms. Hence, the contract brings about consensus on expectations and responsibilities, laying t he ground for firms to coordinate work. However, not only can the contracts be structured in many different ways, they also vary in their complexity levels and vary in the clauses they contain (Reuer & Arino, 2007) C ontractual clauses can also be enforced to varying degrees ( i.e., rigidly or flexibly (Faems, Janssens, Madhok & Van Looy, 2008) ) affecting the coordination of work. Coordination M echanism U se of P urposively C reated B oundary O bjects While structuring refers to the use of ex ante mechanisms of coordination, during the emergent phase when the work is repetitively performed, the coordinating agencies enact purposive objects to bring about coordination. These refer to the use of rules, pr ocedures, databases, routines, and practices, all of which are specific and purposively enacted objects, existing at the interface where coordination is carried out. The use of a railway timetable to operate railroads in a coordinated fashion can be viewed as a classic example of the use of such a purposively created boundary object for coordination (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ).

PAGE 35

35 The use of purposive boundary objects serves to address the coordination challenges brought about due to the limited cognitive abili ty of individuals carrying out coordination (Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005; Simon, 1945). Use of such objects helps to mitigate cognitive challenges by providing access to knowledge as well as, providing a viable mechanism for sharing knowledge, reduci ng uncertainty and storing knowledge (Becker, 2004), and at the same time bringing about agreements, predictability, and common understanding between the coordinating agencies (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ). In the alliance context, where the coordinating agen cies are two distinct firms, it is the set of mutually agreed and adopted boundary objects, such as plans, schedules, performance targets etc., which bring about coordination. The use on boundary objects in a lliances var ies, a s not only does a large vari ety of objects that can be used exists but the way in which they get adapted and adopted for use may also vary Coordination M echanism U se of C ommon G round While structuring is ex ante and the use of boundary objects emergent, both are purposive and d eliberate attempts by firms to bring about coordination. Along with these, the coordinating firms can also emphasize common ground between them and use tacit coordination mechanisms to bring about coordination (Srikanth & Puranam, 20 10 ). Common ground refe rs to knowledge that is shared and is known to be shared (Clark 1996). It emphasizes the use of spontaneous mechanisms to carry out coordination. An instantiation of common ground lies in the emphasis placed on trust to coordinate work (McEvily, Perrone, and Zaheer, 2003). Trust enables work to be

PAGE 36

36 performed jointly as it makes existing links thicker by adding additional layers It also makes reciprocity possible even when temporary inequity exists in the exchange, and reduces instances of redundancy by es tablishing specialized roles (McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003). Trust also guards against opportunistic behavior, reinforces identification, and enables commitment on the part of the coordinating partners (McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003; Puranam & Vanne ste, 2009). In the alliance context, as two or more organizations come together for work, the manifestation and use of common ground is not spontaneous on account of differences between the organizations. Common ground has to be recognized, created, and made use of in these contexts (Srikanth & Puranam, 201 0 ). Determinants of U se of Coordination M echanisms Guided by the seminal studies on coordination by Lawrence & Lorsch (1967) and Thompson (1967), organizational studies view coordination challenges as emerging primarily due to the interdependence in tasks performed jointly by two or more different agencies. Accordingly, the few coordination studies that seek to st udy how firms differentially use coordination mechanisms find their antecedents in task characteristics. For example, while studying coordination of work by a large employment security firm, Van De Ven, Delbecq, and Koenig (1976) found that the antecedents to the use of different coordination mechanisms lie in the degree of uncertainty, interdependence, and complexity of the work task. More specifically, it was found that the use of coordination mechanisms that emphasize mutual adjustments, like horizontal communication and group meetings, tends to get emphasized with an increase in task

PAGE 37

37 uncertainty This increased emphasis comes about in lieu of the use of more formal coordination mechanisms, like hierarchy and impersonal programming. Also, an increase in t he size of the coordinating firm was found to increase the use of impersonal means of coordination, as firms address the increase in complexity o r size with the use of formalized and programmed mechanisms. At the same time, an increase in task interdepende nce was found to increase the use of all the different mechanism of coordination. Around the same time, Argote (1982) studied coordination in hospital emergency units, but did not find any significant e ffects of task input uncertainty on the adoption of di fferent coordination mechanisms (i.e., programmed or non programmed). Existing S tate of C oordination L iterature The above review highlights the difference in p erspective with which the alliance and organizational literatures have been study ing coordination While early organizational studies (like Van De Ven, Delbecq, and Koenig (1976) and Argote (1982)) differentiate d between the different mechanisms used for coordination, no such studies exist in the context of alliances Alliance studies are narrowly foc used on studying the extent to which firms coordinate in the alliance work Further, while the study of coordination in organization al context s seeks to identify why firms use different mechanisms to coordinate work, alliance studies examine the reasons be hind the variance in the extent to which firms coordinate work in alliances While the study of the different mechanisms of coordination in the alliance context is a large gap in the alliance literature, even the study of different mechanisms of coordinati on in organization s is dated ( i.e., the last such study

PAGE 38

38 was by Argote in 1982 ) I n the last few decades the nature of work has changed considerably (Barley & Kunda, 2001; Sinha & Van de Van, 2005), hence our understanding of how firms and alliances coordinate their work is out of date (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ) While c oordination refers to the interdependent working of two or more agencies, coordination is carried out at the interface where the agencies interact. Besides recognizing the im portance of the degree of agency involvement at the interface (Gulati & Sytch, 2007; Tsai, 2002) it is important to recognize that t he interface also mold s and guide s how coordination is done (Wren, 1967) However, t h e interface can be viewed from many di fferent perspectives that differ in their focus on its structural, technical, and human elements (Wren, 1967). B oth the alliance and organizational literatures identify the antecedents of coordination in task and organ izational characteristics However, of late organizational scholars have observed that a more comprehensive understanding of the work context is only possible if one takes a more meso approach and account s for how managers mold organ izational working ( Howard Grenville 2005) From a coordinati on perspective, the manager provides the human interface at which coordination is carried out when firms work interdependently T he manager operationalizes the firm level variables that affect coordination at the micro level In this dissertation, I study how the human interface that is the manager, affects the it is well known that managers play a n very important role in how work is carried out by molding and

PAGE 39

39 guiding it (Mintzberg, 1984), only a few studies could be identified that sought to study the role of managers in managing alliances. While these studies take the managerial practice view are prescriptive in nature, and lack theoretical or empirical grounding, they are next reviewed to summarize what we know on the subject. Human I nterface and C oordination The a lliance manager is the human interface at which coordination of work gets done. Whil e managing the interdependence of the task, the alliance manager lies outside firm boundaries, making his actions and behaviors less constrained by the parent firm in comparison to managers who are located within 98). The acti ons of alliance managers leave lasting effects on the alliance, very similar to how entrepreneurs and early firm managers leave an imprinting e ffect o n the as they can establish traditions and ideologies without facing compet in g views (Stinchcombe, 1965). The significant effect of these managers on alliance working makes it important to identify the antecedents of their actions and behavioral choices. While they are manage rs can also be seen as being located between firms. This makes the alliance manager a linchpin in the alliance management process (Spekman, Isabella, MacAvoy, & Forbes, 199 6 ). The manager is responsible to the alliance that justifies his/her existence, is required to fulfill roles and responsibilities across multiple dimensions, and must shoulder an extra set of responsibilities beyond those of an organizational manager (Child & Faulkner, 1998). Thus, the alliance manager is required to play the role of a m ediator, advocate, strategic

PAGE 40

40 sponsor, and networker, while also playing the conventional roles of a visionary, manager, and facilitator required of an organizational manager (Spekman, Isabella, MacAvoy, & Forbes, 199 6 ). To fulfill this extra set of roles and responsibilities, the alliance manager requires a unique set of competencies that lie in different domains, and these are (a) functional competencies : education, experience, and domain knowledge; (b) earned competencies: credibility and respect, along with extensive networks; and (c) interpersonal competencies: social skills, communication skills, process and cross cultural skills and competencies and tact (Spekman, Isabella, & MacAvoy, 2000). At a more conceptual level, these competencies constitute t he alliance mindset which is comprised of various abilities, including, an ability to think in terms of patterns, connections and relationships; to never stop learning from experience; an ability to think about the world differently; to consider multiple points of view simultaneously and an affinity for complexity (Spekman, Isabella & MacAvoy, 2000). Besides experience in multicultural and technical domains, looking beyond competencies, Child and Faulkner (1998) have identified a set of personality traits that an alliance manager needs to possess ( i.e., open mindedness, flexibility, self confidence, sensitivity to others, and a drive to achieve ) While a few of the identified qualities of the alliance managers are physiological traits with which managers are born, managers can earn m any of them, like education, experience, domain knowledge, social networks, credibility, communication and social skills. This makes the study of how managers earned

PAGE 41

41 competencies affect coordination important from the managerial intervention perspective, as firms can select alliance managers depending upon the coordination needs of the alliance Fu rther managers can also be trained and the relevant important competencies nurtured enabl ing them to function as able alli ance managers. No empirical studies exist examining the e qualities on alliance work (MacAvoy, Robert, Theodore, Lynn, & Thomas, 1998). The few relevant studies summarized above emphasize the importance of the role played by the alliance manager, but are primarily prescriptive, and while they contribute in building a managerial practice view, they do not contribute to the theory of work coordination. This study attempts to address this gap in the literature by providing an empiri cal study linking the alliance manager, as the human interface of coordination, with the extent of use of different mechanisms of coordination, in the alliance way of organizing work.

PAGE 42

4 2 Table 2 1 Coordination mechanisms discussed in the literature Labels used Definition or usage in the studies Citations Coordination by structuring Standardizing work and its output Standardization of the work tasks, both the steps and the output Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Glouberman & Mintzberg, 2001; Malone & Crowston, 1994; Martinez & Jarillo, 1989 Modularization of task Division of task into manageable modules. Baldwin & Clark (2000) Standardization of roles and responsibilities of managers Struc turing of the organizational framework Deshpande & Zaltman, 1982; Mom, Van den Bosch & Volberda, 2010; Poppo & Zenger, 2002 Departmentalization Confinement of task elements to predetermined domains (departments), such that the members of departments are isolated from interdepartmental interactions Fang & Zou, 2009 Mintzberg, 1979 Thompson, 1967 Formal Hierarchy / Authority Vertical Channel Authority Formal Hierarchical (Centralization) Top Management Segregation of the organization into distinct organizational levels, where vertical chain of commands are used to work Van De Ven, Delbecq & Koenig, 1976; Argote, 1982; Sherman & Keller, 2010; Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005; Litterer, 1965; Thompson, 1 967 Barnard, 1938 Matrix Organization A particular structural arrangement in which the two forms (departmentalization and hierarchy) operate with balanced priority and authority on a relatively permanent basis Burns, 1989; Sherman & Keller, 2010 Liaison Cross functional interfaces Boundary Spanners / Integration Manager/ Care Coordinators A structural unit that interfaces between distinct organizational subsystems Jansen, Tempelaar, Van den Bosch & Volberda, 2009; Sherman & Keller, 2010; Thom pson, 1967; Ito & Peterson, 1986; Daft & Lengel, 1986; Gittell, 2002; Van De Ven, Delbecq & Koenig, 1976

PAGE 43

43 Table 2 1. Continued Labels used Definition or usage in the studies Citations Coordination by structuring Teams (Temporary or semi permanent) Integrating teams / Cross unit teams A structural configuration in which individuals (from different levels in hierarchies and departments) are grouped together for achieving a specific purpose Martinez & Jarillo, 1989; Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967; Sherman & Keller, 2010; Thompson, 1967 Degree of Formalized Structure, Participation Emergent structure in terms of span of supervisory control and number of levels Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967 Centralization of Decision Making Discretion, Unit Member Autonomy The practice view on how hierarchy manifests itself Aiken & Hage, 1968; Martinez & Jarillo,1989; Mom, Van den Bosch & Volberda, 2010 Ito & Peterson, 1986 Coordination by use of boundary objects Rules & regulations Use of rules for monitoring and controlling the tasks Daft & Lengel,1986; Van De Ven, Delbecq & Koenig,1976; Argote,1982; Schreiner, Kale & Corsten, 2009 Planning Establishment of objects (plans and schedules) that monitor and control the activities of the different units Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Daft & Lengel, 1986; Martinez & Jarillo, 1989 Monitoring Feedback Review of performance and monitoring of how the procedures and rules are followed Van De Ven & Walker, 1984; Reuer, Zollo & Singh, 2002; Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005 Clinical pathway routines Use of specific objects (routines) to guide the decision making while carrying out work Gittell, 2002

PAGE 44

44 Table 2 1. Continued Labels used Definition or usage in the studies Citations Coordination by use of boundary objects Operating Procedures; Program Decisions; Plans; Programming Use of specific objects (procedures, plans) that guides the decision making while carrying out work Van De Ven, Delbecq & Koenig, 1976; Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005; Thompson, 1967; Sherman & Keller, 2010 Shared databases Use of specific objects (databases) that enable sharing of information between the participants Sherman & Keller, 2010 Common Technical Grammar, Common database Common reference database or information exchange language Argyres, 1999 Administrative and Control Systems Use of specific objects (administrative and control systems) that enable monitoring and control Litterer, 1965 Centralized Communication (Mediated by supervisor) Nomination of a central object (supervisor) to mediate and monitor the ex change of all information Tushman, 1979 Formal Information Systems Use of specific objects (information systems) that enable sharing and exchange of information Daft & Lengel, 1986 Impersonal Direct Contact: Electronic/ Paper reports Use of Information exchange protocols. Sherman & Keller, 2010 Display, Representation and Assembly practice Specific practices and routines that enable exchange of knowledge Kellogg, Orlikowski & Yates, 2006

PAGE 45

45 Table 2 1. Continued Labels used Definition or usage in the studies Citations Coordination by use of common ground Relational Coordination Shared goals, shared Knowledge and mutual respect, such that frequent, timely, accurate and problem solving communication can take place Gittell, 2002 Communication Peer to peer Communication Phone/ email/ Individual meetings Communication between directly concerned individuals, without regard to the established channels. Both comes about on account of common ground, and further leads t o generation of common ground Malone & Crowston, 1994; Martinez & Jarillo 1989; March & Simon, 1958; Tushman, 1978; 1979; Aiken & Hage, 1968; Keller, 1994; Van De Ven & Walker, 1984 Tushman, 1979 Sherman & Keller, 2010; Daft & Lengel, 1986 Voluntary Activities Informal Lateral Relations autonomous concerns Litterer, 1965 Tsai, 2002 Standardizing Norms Establishment of common values, beliefs and expectations Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Glouberman & Mintzberg, 2001 Connectedness Degree to which employees are networked with one another at various levels of hierarchy in their organization in terms of personal contacts Jansen, Tempelaar, van den Bosch & Volberda, 2009; Mom, Van den Bosch & Volberda, 2010 Network closure, Lack of structural holes A network structural configuration such that members get connected together through multiple pathways, enabling trust to manifest Gulati, 1995

PAGE 46

46 Table 2 1. Continued Labels used Definition or usage in the studies Citations Coordination by use of common ground Standardizing skills and knowledge Bringing in commonality between acting partners to reduced chances of conflict between them Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Glouberman & Mintzberg, 2001 Shared Characteristics, Shared Experiences, Norms, precedent, culture The emergence of commonness among the parties Malone & Crowston, 1994; Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005 Mutual Adjustment Adaptation People or units adjusting to each other during their work processes, as a way to accommodate the other Barki & Pinsonneault, 2005; Glouberman & Mintzberg, 2001 Gulati, Lawrence & Puranam, 2005; Thompson, 1967; Argote, 1982

PAGE 47

47 CHAPTER 3 LITERATURE ON PPPS In this dissertation I study coordination in the context of PPPs. While PPPs are popular, have achieved an iconic status, have a long history and have been studied in a diverse literature, they are a unique context in which work is conducted (Hodge, Greve & Boardman, 2011; Kale & Singh, 2009). To explore the distinctive aspects of the unique PPP context, this chapter briefly reviews the diverse literature studying PPPs, identifies the aspects which make PPP working distinctive, and describes the generic p rocess of PPP formation and its structuring in the specific context of Indian highway construction. Review of L iterature on PPPs PPPs are increasingly being used to carry out activities that were previously conducted purely in the public domain (Delmon, 20 10). They enable the government to access precious financial, managerial, and technical resources, provide the private enterprise an opportunity to contribute financially, tec hnically, and managerially to a domain where it can work more efficiently and effectively (Hart, 2003; Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). These distinct and attractive features of PPPs have motivated governments across the globe to deploy them in the delivery of public infrastructures (Delmon, 2010). Consequently, PPPs have emerged as the preferred mode for developing infrastructures, such as roads, airports, railroads, and seaports, and even to run schools, hospitals, and water supply systems (Delmon, 2010), which have traditional ly been the sole bastion of the government.

PAGE 48

48 The pervasive use of PPPs can be gauged by the fact that in the past 15 years, Europe has witnessed over 1000 PPP contracts involving investments of almost 200 billion Euro s ( Frederi c Goldsmith & Valila, 2007), and 57% of all project expenditure s in UK w ere made though the PPP mode over the seven year period of 2001 2008 (IFSL Research, 2008). Concurrent with this growth in the use of PPPs has been an increase in academic, managerial and research interest in PPPs. S cholars in economics, finance, public policy, construction management, and public administration disciplines have started to study PPPs, providing valuable perspectives on PPPs ( Henisz & Levitt, 20 09 ; Hodge & Greve, 201 0 ) As this literature is vast and fragmented (Hodge & Greve, 2007) a complete review i s impossible The objective of the overview provided here is to identify the foc i of the different streams of literature and a scertain how they contribute to the study of PPP working. Overview of L iterature on PPP The different disciplines have differing focus when they study PPPs. For instance, economic scholars view PPPs as changing the boundary between public and private ownership (Hart, 2003; Shleifer, 1998). Hence, t hey see the use of PPPs as a viable option in the case of market failure and as an alternative to total privatization (Savas, 2000). With this view, the economics literature studies the rationale behind the emergence of PPPs (Shleifer, 1998; Mahalingam, 20 10); the features of the regulatory environment that enables or prevent s the emergence of PPPs (Davidsson, 2010; Koppenjan & Enserink, 2009); the basis for risk sharing between the private and public partners (for e.g., Marques & Berg, 2010 2011 forthcom ing ; Thomas, Kalidindi & Ananthanarayanan, 2003; Choi,

PAGE 49

49 Chung, & Lee, 2010); the scope of work and ownership distribution in PPPs (Chen & Chiu, 2010); and the contract formulation and renegotiation aspects of PPP design (for e.g., Martimort & Pouyet, 2008; Guasch, Laffont & Straub, 200 7; 2008 ). In contrast, the finance literature focuses on how private finances are deployed for the delivery of public infrastructure. More specifically, this literature examines the important role played by money markets in fin ancing PPPs under the dynamic conditions of the changing money markets and the changing perceptions of risks that lie at the project, industry, and national levels (Heald & Georgiou, 2011). While studying the changing role of the government, political scie ntists are beginning to recognize the plural forms of organizations that exist beyond the market and government dichotomy. Accordingly, polycentric organization ha s been recognized as an effective mode of organization in the public domain. In polycentric o rganizations, organizations work towards a common purpose while tightly integrated with one another, but follow t heir own narrow objectives (Ostrom, Tiebout, and Warren, 1961). PPPs are one such instantiation of a polycentric organization. Here, the govern ment and the private firm work to achieve their own objective functions, while fulfilling a common objective purpose of delivering a public infrastructure. There is also an increasing recognition in this literature that the assumptions about a rational man ager need to be relaxed to accommodate the important role that trust and learning play in the management of organizations in the public domain (Ostrom, 2009).

PAGE 50

50 Organizational L iterature on PPP and the G aps T herein From the organizational perspective, PPPs are a kind of an alliance (Kale & Singh, 2009; Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006; Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). While there is an extensive amount of research studying the structure, design, and working of alliances, this research is limited to the stu dy of alliances between for profit organizations ( i.e., B2B alliances ) (Mahoney, McGahan, & Pitelis, 2009), and only a few studi es have attempted to study PPPs in which the government is a partner. However, these few existing studies also lie in the econo mics paradigm as they explore the antecedents that lead to the formation of PPPs and how they are structured. For instance, combining transaction cost economics with externalities theory, Rangan, Swamii, & Van Wassenhove (2006) proposed a set of condition s under which PPPs emerge for the exploitation of economic opportunity. These conditions were identified as: existence of industry specific competencies simultaneously with significant positive externalities, presence of high uncertainty for the private ac tors, and presence of high governance costs for the private actors in terms of contracting, coordinating, and enforcing. Similarly, McDermott, Corredoira, & Kruse (2009) took an institutional perspective, and studied how government support institutions cre ated out of PPPs serve as a catalyst in upgrading emerging markets. Focusing on the governance of PPP s Rufin & Rivera Santos (2010) compare PPPs with B2B alliance s along five distinct dimensions of governance: use of equity, use of contract, scope of the work, nonequity hostage situations, and use of trust (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). Examining a case each of a PPP and a B2B alliance, they found that significant differences exist between them

PAGE 51

51 along each of the five dimensions identified above. More recently, Kivleniece & QuŽlin (forthcoming) identify two ideal kinds of public private ties governance ( i.e., autonomous and integrative ) hey argue that, while on one hand the choice of the governance form is determined by the partnership rationales lying in the reduction of environmental uncertainty, compensation for market externalities, and access to idiosyncratic resources, on the other hand the choice of the governance mechanism affects the value captured by the partnership. While a significant amount of economic activity is undertaken at the public private interface, research studying how organizations work i n this interface is missing from the literature (Mahoney, McGahan, & Pitelis, 2009; Wang & Bunn, 2 004). E valuation of the implementation and managerial issues involved with the delivery of public services at the public private interface are very important and are also missing from the literature (Bult Spiering & Dewulf, 2006). Thus, we possess little u nderstanding of how PPPs work once they have been formed, and a number of recent calls have been made enticing organizational scholars to study PPPs and their working (for instance Kale & Singh, 2009; Rangan, Swamii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006; Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010; and S trategic Management Society, 2011). More specifically, we have little understanding of the coordination mechanisms used in the management of PPPs, and what determines their usage. These omissions from the literature relate to the managem ent of the partnership between the public and private actors, and are of prime importance in the

PAGE 52

52 implementation stage, when the PPP mode of project execution has been decided upon, when the private firm to be contracted has been identified, and when the co ntract for carrying out the work has been signed Distinctive A spects of PPPs PPPs are alliances in which government and private firms come together to deliver a public infrastructure (Rivera Santos & Rufin 2010). Government is philosophically and legally different from private firms (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 20 02 ) and possesses a set of organizational skills and culture very different from those of a private firm (Kale & Singh, 2009; Mahoney, McGahan, & Pitelis 2009). Likewise, public infrastructures are ve ry different from private goods as they possess qualities of non rivalrousness of use and non excludability from use (Samu elson 1954), qualities that private goods lack. Both the presence of a government in the alliance and the delivery of public infrast ructure make PPPs different from for profit alliances in how they are structured, governed, and worked (Kale & Singh, 2009). Government as an A lliance P artner The participation of the government in the alliance makes PPPs different from for profit allianc es, as the government has objectives very different from the objectives of for profit firms (Kale & Singh, 2009), its source of sustenance is different from that of private firms (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010), it possesses a unique level of authority, legi timacy, and credibility (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 200 2 ), and the risk aptitude of government managers is very different (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 2002).

PAGE 53

53 While private firms exist to maximize private benefits, the objective function of the government is to maximize public benefits (Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). Hence, unlike private firms, government is not structured to operate on a commercial basis or to maintain profit and loss accounts, such that the pursuit of profits by the government which is the objective of a private firm, is often looked upon with suspicion (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). These differences between the government and private firms mold the ways in which they behave, for instance in their purchase behaviors (Wang & Bunn, 200 4). In B2B procurements, while private organizations emphasize profit maximization and seek cost or differentiation advantages (Porter, 1985), the government works towards preventing favoritism, promoting public policy, and ensuring that the lars get the best value (Wang & Bunn, 2004). While the government sustains itself by taxing the public, private firms rely on voluntary money market exchanges for their source of funds. As government funds come from the general public, they have to be spen t in an unbiased manner and the government is required to be responsive to the needs of a larger set of stakeholders, who may have directly or indirectly contributed taxes (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). In contrast, as the funds of a private firm come fro m the few people who have voluntarily decided to invest the firm works primarily in the interest of these investors to provide them with high returns on their investments. Further, as taxation is compulsory, the public that provides the tax funds to the go vernment possesses no short term controls over them. While electoral politics does provide the public a control over the actions of the government as

PAGE 54

54 elections are sporadic, the public has a dis tributive view, and the public has a short memory, the contro ls exercised by the public have a diluted impact. On the other hand, the shareholders of a private firm possess a more immediate control ccess to funds by continuously monitoring the The reliance on tax funds also subjects the government to many transparency requirements, like adherence to additional disclosure procedures and following due proce ss and fairness standards (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). T hese requirements typically exceed the requirements imposed on private firms (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 2002). At the same time, the government also possesses a monopoly o n making and enforcing laws. T his provides it with an asymmetrically high amount of authority (Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). Further, the explicit public spirited objective of the government also gives it a high amount of credibility and legitimacy (Rangan, Samii, & Van Wasse nhove, 2006). P rivate firms cannot credibility and legitimacy levels. No matter how intensely the private firm believes in public welfare, demonstrate s its commitments to corporate social responsibilities, and acts to defe nd public interests; in the mind of the public it remain s associated with its primary objective of profit maximization. Also, the managers of the government are required to maintain a high level of transparency as they are subject to intense scrutiny by t he press and other public functionaries e.g.,

PAGE 55

55 ebrary, 2003; Pirson & Malhotra, 2010). Further, with guaranteed employment public managers do not often see the upside of risk taking, but are instead preoccu pied with the downside that risk taking implies. This makes public managers increasingly risk averse and also slow in decision making (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 2002). Conversely, in the interest of protecting the privately owned assets and business secrets o f the firms, managers of private firms take higher levels of risks and maintain discreteness in their dealings. Delivery of a Public I nfrastructure The objective of PPPs is to deliver a public infrastructure. Hence, the characteristics of a public infrast ructure make the management of interdependence between alliance partners, in the PPP context, different from how B2B alliances are worked (Mahoney, McGahan, & Pitelis 2009). More specifically, highway public infrastructure has six attributes: high sunk cos ts, non tradability of output, non rivalness on consumption, possibility of price exclusion, and bestowing externalities on society (http://infrastructure.gov.in). Public infrastructure is a public good, as it possesses both non rivalrousness of use and no n excludability from use (Samu elson 1954). However, over time the two fold categorization of private and public goods has been further refined with the identification of two more kinds of goods that is toll (club) goods and common pool resources (Ostrom, 2005). In this refined categorization, toll goods, like private clubs, highways, and day care centers, are those that possess a high potential of excludability of use but possess little rivalrousness to use. In contrast, common pool resources, like forest s, ground water, and irrigation systems etc., possess high levels of rivalrou s ness of use but low level of

PAGE 56

56 excludability of use. Toll highways are toll goods as per this categorization. They are excludable in use; the benefits that they bring are restricte d to the toll paying public. They also possess non rivalrou s ness of use; an addition of an extra vehicle on the highway does not adversely affect the benefits experienced by current users of the road (Rangan, Swamii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). Toll highway s besides being toll goods are also a natural monopoly. Highway users do not have a viable alternative to buy highway services from other sources, and for all practical purposes there are no other sellers competing ; realistic alternatives do not exist. Further, in the projects that we are studying, the government even signs a non competitive clause in the contract agreement. As per this clause, the government guarantees the private firm that it will use its legislative powers t o ensure that no alternate highway will be constructed for the validity of the contract ed period of time, and also assures the private firm that its monopoly rights to collect tolls from the project will not be diluted. Hence, in PPPs the government tempor arily transfers its monopoly rights over the public infrastructure to the private firm. This temporary transfer of monopoly rights to a private firm is a source of fear in the mind of the public, as possibilities of misuse exist. Delivery uncertainty on pa rt of the private firm, perception of undue alignment between the local government agency and private firm against public interests, and the occasional protests against PPP projects provide evidence that the government is exposed to the opportunism of the private firm in PPPs (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). The contract signed between the government and private firm exists to maintain

PAGE 57

57 checks and balances and ensure that such a misuse of monopolistic rights does not arise. However, contracts are inherently in complete leaving space for manipulation. Such opportunities for misuse of monopoly rights abound during the execution phase when new challenges emerge in the project and are addressed by reinterpreting contract clauses, reworking contract clauses (often very difficult), or by negotiations out of the contract space. Highways possess both positive and negative externalities. As a positive externality, the investments made in the highway may benefit the society more th a n it costs the society to build it. For instance, the public highway built through a PPP not only benefits the toll paying users, but it also indirectly benefits other sectors of the society by opening up new opportunities for economic development. As these opportunities cannot be fully envis io ned earlier, the society would not have accounted for these benefits while planning the project, and this makes the m externalities. When such externalities emerge out of investments by the government it is understandable, however when they emerge out of in vestments by private firms in PPPs, the private firm sees these benefits as a result of its actions and would like to appropriate a share of these benefits that the project brings about. However, both the quantification of positive externalities bestowed b y the highway and the share of these that the private firm wants to appropriate are ambiguous. Similarly, highways also possess negative externalities. That is, the returns experienced by the society come at a cost larger than the investments made by the society in the highway project. Under the assumption that both the producers

PAGE 58

58 and users of public goods attempt to externalize costs to the extent possible, negative externalities tend to be at their highest level when the actions of the producers and users are unconstrained (Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). Such a situation arises in PPP highways, where the producer of the highways ( i.e., the private firm ) is distinct from its users ( i.e., the toll paying public ) Also their actions are unconstrained as on the one hand the government forsakes its rights to the private firm, while on the other hand road users see tolls as an unnecessary financial burden. While increased intervention, such as a control of the private firm s actions and legal enforcemen t on users to pay the tolls, can serve to control the negative externalities, it comes at a cost and these costs increase with an increase in intervention. While there exists a theoretically optimal minimum cost scenario that achieves a balance in the cos ts arising out of interventions and the externalities that they address, the basic nature of the public good makes quantification of negative externalities difficult, such that this optimal cost scenario often cannot be determined (Rangan, Samii, & Van Was senhove, 2006). In sum, while both positive and negative externalities exist in highway infrastructures executed through the PPP mode, these are often difficult to quantify. Notwithstanding, PPPs need to adapt their working to address both positive and neg ative externalities that exist in the project. I nvestments in public highways are lumpy, indivisible, illiquid, and capital intensive. They are also difficult to value in the intermediate and final stages as they involve numerous taxation and pricing rules and often possess embedded

PAGE 59

59 options (Dixit, Pindyck, & Davis, 1994). Such an investment, which involves large front end commitments, leads to a hostage situation for both the government and the private firm in the PPP project (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010) PPP contracts are long term contracts, and in practice the period of the concession agreement lies between 5 and 99 years. All of this underscores the need for the project agencies to work keep track of the life cycle cost s of the project. That is, the v arious different project agencies need to work in the project while ensuring that is their long term interest in the project are always protected. PPPs have been typically viewed as alliances, however a paradox exists on account of the characteristics of p ublic infrastructures that they deliver. The alliance mode of economic opportunity realization is a preferred choice as it inherently provides structural flexibility (Porter & Fuller, 1986). That is, the firm has the flexibility to exit or modify the allia nce (Young Ybarra & Wiersema, 1999). However, PPPs provide no such flexibility in existing models, and the government and private firms are hostage s to the partnership (Rufin & Rivera in its financial bankruptcy or opting to take a heavy financial beating, as evaluation of the project cost at the intermediate stages is difficult (Dixit, Pindyck, & Davis, 1994). Also, both the government and the private firm possess significant tangible and intangible asset specificity binding them to the project (Young Ybarra & Wiersema, 1999). That is, the government has a commitment to the public to deliver a highway, and going back on this commitment puts it in an inconvenient political situation. Als o, the private firm has lumpy indivisible

PAGE 60

60 investments in the projects that make it difficult for the firm to easily exit the project. At the same time, as highways are a public infrastructure options for the government to completely exit from them do not exist O ptions to modify the alliance lie in changing the contractual clauses or changing the scope, both of which are very difficult in PPPs. Firstly, the government, which is a partner in the alliance, has to maintain a high level of procedural transpare ncy and follow an extensive and drawn out change procedure, making it difficult to effect e ven minor modifications to contract clauses. This makes the contractual clauses unduly binding n ot only in spirit but also in their language. Secondly, as the PPP co ntractual clauses have evolved out of a decade of governments experience with PPPs, they have strong institutional support. Hence, any attempts at changing them not only require the change to be argued with very sound and convincing logic, but the need for changing them must also be communicated to and accepted by a diverse set of project participants. Hence PPPs while being alliances do not provide flexibility of exit or modification, one of the primary advantages of B2B alliances. Partnerships are formed when the agencies joining in partnership are able to bring a complementary set of resources and capabilities (Kale & Singh, 2009). In the context of delivery of public infrastructure, like highways, the private firm brings to the project a superior set of technical and managerial skills, an efficient delivery process of construction projects, and significant financial muscle to invest in the project (Hart, 2003, Rangan, Swamii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). The government, on the other hand, brings credib ility and legitimacy to the

PAGE 61

61 project and stands guarantee for the project risks (Rangan, Swamii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006). While these are complementary in nature, the government and the private firm also bring their differences to the project. D ifferences i n their organizational cultures, paradigms, and ways of working, result in c hallenges in bringing the ir complementary capabilities together i n the project to pursue a common objective. The F ormation and S tructuring of a n Indian Highway PPP P roject The mai nstream adoption of the PPP mode for public infrastructure upgradation can be attributed to the success of the Public Finance Initiative (PFI) of the United Kingdom (Delmon, 2010). With its successful PPP experience, the government of the United Kingdom ha s significantly contributed to building up the worldwide knowledge base on PPPs and has liberally shared its experiences with the world community. G uided by this knowledge and the experience of not just the UK government but also other national government s, the Indian Specifically in the Indian highway sector, this has resulted in the evolution of a standardized process for formation and structuring of PPP projects, which has widesprea d institutional support. This section describes this standardized process with the objective of gaining insights into the working of PPPs in the Indian highway construction sector. Formation of PPPs The formation of PPPs is a multiple stage process. In the first stage, the government identifies the highways that require upgradation based on user demands and political considerations. The services of a consultant are then

PAGE 62

62 requisitioned to carry out a Detailed Project Feasibility (DPR) study of the project. Wh ile carrying out the DPR study, the consultant: studies the traffic and civil engineering requirements of the project ; timelines, resource requirements, traffic projections, and environmental impact; and evaluates the various scenarios of project implementation. Based on this study, the consultant prepares detailed financial and technical specifications of the project. This study forms the basis on which the government decides the mode of project execution (i.e., PPP or arms length contract), nature of the project (i.e., DBFO, BOT, BOLT or other), and the cost revenue allocation and sharing arrangements to be used (i.e., toll, positive grant, negative grant or annuity). In the second stage, the government invites bids fr om private firms to undertake the project. The private firms base their financial and technical bids on the project specifications provided in the DPR and their prior experience in the construction domain. The government evaluates the bids across different financial and technical parameters and selects the firm for carrying out the project who se bid provides maximum value to the public. A letter of intent is then Before it c an start work on the project, the private firm is required to seek financ ial backing from the money markets and achieve financial closure for the project. Furthermore, the private firm is required to create a project specific organization, distinct from it self, called the special purpose vehicle (SPV). After h aving achieved financial closure for the project and having created the SPV, the

PAGE 63

63 firm approaches the government to sign the long term concession agreement for the project. The government signs this agr eement not with the firm, but with the SPV, which is tasked with upgradation, operations, and final transfer of the highway back to the government at the end of the contract period. Execution and M anagement of PPPs The SPV has complete financial and managerial control over the project, and locates all the project activities within it. While from an accounting perspective the SPV is simply an escrow account, from an organizational perspective it is a distinct entity, possessing: an entity with the regi strar of companies, a balance sheet, a distinctive set of managers on its payroll, a distinct set of roles and responsibilities, an organizational structure, and its own stream of revenues and expenses. While the lifespan of an SPV is the contract period, it can be split into two distinct phases: the construction period (i.e., the initial 2 3 year period), in which the highway is upgraded to the DPR specifications; and the concession period (i.e., the post construction 5 99 year period), in which the highw ay is maintained to the specification s given in the DPR and finally transferred back to the government (Hart, 2003). This research focuses on the construction period of the ct stakeholders is of prime importance. Also, the execution of work in the construction period lays the ground for a smooth working of the project during the concession period. During the construction period, the SPV has multiple roles to play and interact s with a diversified set of project stakeholders. To ensure that the project

PAGE 64

64 meets its cost, time, and quality objectives, the SPV has to: manage inflow of funds to finance the construction activities; ensure that land and permissions are available in time to start construction; manage the civil construction activities; monitor the quality of the project; and ensure the flow of manpower, machinery, design expertise, and other resources to the project. For this, the SPV has to interact with a broad spectrum of project stakeholders, which include the equity owning private firms, project debt financers, project designers, government agencies, local bodies, specialized consultants, civil contractors, and machinery and plant suppliers. The multiple roles that the SPV has to play and the large numbers of interfaces that it has to manage with the large number of project agencies, gives rise to a large number of coordination challenges and makes the SPV the central coordinating agency in the project. While a large n umber of agencies are involved with the SPV, the coordination of work in the SPV is primarily handled by the Project Manager (PM) whom the equity holding private firm assigns to the project. It is the PM who is finally responsible for ensuring that the pro ject meets its time schedules, budgets, technical specification s and quality objectives. The PM heads the SPV and holds the final authority over the project. Highways being public infrastructure not only require access to public land to construct the highway but also numerous government clearances in order to work For instance, forest departments clearances are required to remove trees in the right of way and local municipal authorities clearances are required to dislocat e water pipelines and electri city distribution networks

PAGE 65

65 ( Bandyopadhyay, Swaminathan, & Rohatgi, 2008 ). Since in PPPs the government partners with a p rivate firm for delivery of public infrastructure, the government sets up a local office and posts a Project Director (PD) to liaison wi th the project This local office e nable s the project by provision ing the right of way and clearances at the local level. In the Indian highway context, the delay incurred by the government in handing over right of way to the SPV has been found to be one o f the primary elements that adversely affect the pace of the work, and ha s been identified as one of the most important situations that require s frequent interactions. This makes the PD one of the main coordinating partners of the PM in the project. Constr uction projects by their very nature are complex requiring thousands of activities to be planned and executed, and this complexity increases in the case of highway projects that are subject to many stakeholder and geo technical risks. For instance, highwa ys pass through villages, cities and towns, and the local population may require changes in highway alignments to protect religious structures in the way. Also, in some places the soil conditions and other geo technical characteristics may change suddenly requiring the contractor to rework the design of the highway. To accommodate these changes the construction contractor is seldom able to follow the detailed specifications as laid out in the DPR, in letter or in spirit, and deviations from project specifi cations need to be made. Whenever such deviations occur, the contract terms need to be revisited and the concerns resolved, while giving due consideration to their financial implications. In PPPs, these issues can emerge as a source of dispute between

PAGE 66

66 the private firm and the government, and lead to arbitration and legal battles that delay the project. The resolution of these issues on a continuous basis is of prime importance for the success of these projects (Iyer, Chaphalkar & Joshi, 2008). Hence, the ne ed for a permanent neutral intermediary exists. In PPP projects, this permanent intermediary role is attributed to a third party agency called the Independent Consultant (IC), which is appointed jointly by the government and the private firm. 1 e involves: verifying and assuring that the project is done as per the DPR; allowing, guiding, and certifying any changes made to the project; and serving as the first level for dispute resolution. The important role of the IC makes it a n important agency, with whom the PM has to coordinate the project work on an ongoing basis. The coordination of work has both structuring and emergent aspects (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 200 3 ). While the SPV emerges as the central body tasked with structuring coordination in PPP projects, the emergent coordination of work in the PPP context is carried out between the PM, PD, and IC. This study focuses on the construction stage of highway upgradation and construction PPP projects in India, all of whi ch are structured using SPVs. Hence the projects studied are similarly structured. This enables us !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 As per the most recent practice of the appointment ing an IC in the Indian highway se ctor, the government provides the names of five eligible ICs to the SPV to rank its first three choices. The government then selects the consultant out of the three consultants shortlisted by the private firm. Also, while the government pays the consultant for the work performed 50% of this money is compensated by the SPV, making the IC obliged equally to the government and the SPV. This arrangement of sharing cost coupled with an appointment process by joint consultation, is aimed at ensuring that the IC works in an unbiased manner in its assigned job

PAGE 67

67 to shift focus from structuring to emergent aspects of coordination, and this study seeks to investigate the emergent aspects of coordination among the key p roject participants, more specifically how the PM coordinates the PPP working with the PD and the IC. Structuring of PPPs to A ddress their D istinctive A spects In contrast to B2B alliances, the presence of the government and the delivery of a public infras tructure pose some unique challenges to the management of PPPs (Kale & Singh, 2009). While comparing the governance of PPPs and B2B alliances, Rufin & Rivera Santos (2010) found them to be different in their structuring ( i.e., equity participation and scop e of work ) and also in their emergent aspects ( i.e., use of trust, creation of hostage situations ) and stakeholder involvement. Hence, the distinctiveness of PPPs lies in both their structuring and their emergent aspects. The distinct aspects of PPP structuring lie in the specification of a common objective function, the containment of PPP working within the SPV, and the use of ICs. While Chapter 4 examines how the distinct emergent aspects are addressed in PPPs, the distinct structuring aspects are d iscussed next The difference in the objective functions of the private firm and the government can be partially mitigated by the specification of a common objective function, like globally sustainable value creation (Mahoney, McGahan, & Pitelis 2009). Thi s provides a common platform for public private interactions and also a unifying concept. As PPPs are formed with the primary objective of upgrading and maintaining an infrastructure, this objective provides the unifying concept in pursuit of which the pri vate firm and the government can work together, despite

PAGE 68

68 their many differences. While stipulating the conceptual unifying framework, the common objective function s of the PPP becomes formalized and specified by the contract signed for executing the project This contract serves not only to restrain the asymmetric authority of the government by providing compensation to the private firm in the case of unilateral decisions by the government, but it also restrains the private firm from engaging in the sole pur suit of profit. Further, the objective also lays down a common platform for the different agencies to work together in delivering a piece of public infrastructure despite the different areas of expertise and worldviews that the diverse agencies bring to t he project. The distinct organizational identity of the SPV separates both the government and the private firm from the project. This separation structures the PPP such that the differences between the government and the private firm can be kept at bay and ensures that their risk profiles do not affect one another. That is, the government is not exposed to the broad business risks that the private firm faces in the other businesses that it manages, besides the focal project. Similarly, the private firm is i nsulated from the general working of the government, and the many political, economic, and financial activities that the government is involved with in its different roles. The distinct identity of the SPV and the manner in which it separates the project f rom its dominant stakeholders ( i.e., the government and the private firm ) ensures that the dominant paradigms of these stakeholders do not come in the way of achieving the common objective of the project. More specifically, this separation ensures that th

PAGE 69

69 public welfare role Hence, the e s profit pursuits can be restrained fro m significantly affecting the project. At the same time, the SPV also insulates the project from exposure to the risk profile of the government and the private firms. Along with creating the separation, the SPV also localizes the sources of revenue, expens es, and controls in the project. On the one hand, it restricts the base of tax collection ( i.e., the toll charges ) to those who use the infrastructure, and ensure that the tax paying public (toll paying public) is who gains from it. On the other hand, it ensures that toll revenue collected from the infrastructure is first performed in the project. At th e same time, the accountal of revenues and expenses of the project at the SPV level ensures that the project revenues are first used to fulfill the project s needs, before appropriating the surplus as profit to the parent private firm. The IC which is a p ermanent intermediary in the project between the private firm and government, also plays an important role in structuring PPPs. The IC is tasked with balancing the different risk aptitudes of private and government managers, handling the positive and negat ive externalities, providing flexibility to the project in adapting to its specific contexts, balancing the differences in expertise between them, and helping to monitor the project to ensure that monopolistic rights are not misused. For the private firm, the IC

PAGE 70

70 protects it from the asymmetric powers of the government, and makes the government managers accountable for their actions. For instance, the inability of the government to provid e the right of way for the highway construction work to start results i n both resource wastage of the contractor and delay in the project. The IC in this case studies the specific instance to work out the financial implication s of the event, and to what extent the government needs to compensate the project for the same. In ad dition, the IC provides the government with expertise in the highway domain, and assists it in monitoring the project. A s the IC can work out the financial and technical implications of project changes it brings in flexibility in working of PPPs by interp reting the difficult to change contractual clauses Further, the IC ensure s the quality of the project during the execution stages thereby e nsur ing smooth handoff of the project from the SPV to the government at the end of concession period. It also serves as the locally available and first stage dispute resolution machinery for the project. In PPPs, information asymmetry exists between the principal (i.e., the government ) and the agent (i.e., the private firm ) (Laffont &Tirole, 1993). From a structuring perspective, this information asymmetry can be addressed by bringing in competition for the market (Davidsson, 201 0 ) or by putting in place high pow ered schemes that provide an incentive for the private firm to be efficient (Laffont & Tirole, 1993) I nformation asymmetry can also be addressed by the use of organ i zational forms which are distinct from their members (Koschmann, Kuhn, & Pfarrer, Forthco ming). O rganizational forms like SPVs not only enable a display of collective agency by the different agencies coordinating to perform the

PAGE 71

71 work, but they also build a capacity to achieve outcomes that are beyond what the individual organizations can achiev e (Koschmann, Kuhn, & Pfar r er, Forthcoming). In the structuring of PPPs, both the SPV and IC can be seen as instantiations of such collective agency and high powered schemes, respectively, which serve to address the distinct aspects of PPPs. However, each of these is a structuring mechanism that lay s the ground for coordination in the project. From an emergent perspective they guide the coordination of the PPP task, but by themselves do not carry out coordination of the work. Chapter 4 studies the emergent aspects of PPP working, specifically identifying how the focus of the private firm s primary line of business and the experience profile of the manager molds the working of PPPs, while recognizing that PPPs accomplish their work by carrying out coordination.

PAGE 72

72 Figure 3 1 S tructure of a PPP Coordination by the special purpose vehicle (SPV)

PAGE 73

73 Table 3 1 Structuring of PPP to address its distinctive aspects Aspect Common objective SPV IC Government as an alliance partner Different o bjective function Unifying concept Common platform Create distance Manage disputes Technical expertise Different source of sustenance Quantify Create distance and localize Manage on behalf of government Asymmetric a uthority, credibility, and legitimacy Contract Create distance First level mediator Risk averse government managers Common platform Restrict exposure Intermediary Delivery of public infrastructure Toll good and monopoly Unifying concept Localize Monitor private firm Positive and negative externalities Localize Ascertain and quantify them Lumpy, indivisible, and long term investments SPV life as investment life Provide unbiased assessment Difference in e xpertise Individual contracts Compensate for government s lack of expertise

PAGE 74

74 CHAPTER 4 THEORY AND HYPOTHESE S As the coordination of work in organizations can be carried out with many different mechanisms, heterogeneity exists in the working of firms even when they seek to accomplish similar tasks. Accordingly, when one is exploring firm heterogeneity, a need to identify and study the antecedents of the use of different mechanisms of coordination exists. While the organizational literature has identified these antecedents to lie primarily in task characteristics, this study argues that these antecedents could also lie as well as the experience prof ile of the managers whom the firm deploys. In order to study how work is coordinated at the boundaries of a firm, a conceptual model is suggested, and a number of hypotheses proposed. This chapter first discusses the different mechanisms that a firm can us e for coordination at its interface, and then puts forward four main hypotheses. These hypotheses argue that two different kinds of focus ( i.e., focus on the highway sector and focus on the PPP way of working ) which are relevant in the context of PPP high way construction projects, potentially influence the emphasis placed on the use of different coordination mechanisms. Building on this perspective, it is argued that the managers deployed by the firm to carry out coordination at its interface are likely to mold the emphasis placed on the use of coordination mechanisms. Accordingly, as different kinds of managerial experience may affect the use of coordination mechanisms, twelve hypotheses are proposed, arguing for the moderating e focus.

PAGE 75

75 Different M echanisms of C oordination Different streams of literature conceptualize a firm either as a bundle of contracts, a bundle of routines, or a bundle of social relations. These distinct conceptualizations attribute the diversity in how firms coordinate their work to different reasons. For instance, transaction cost economics literature views the firm as a bundle of transactions man aged by contracts (Coase, 1937), and attributes the heterogeneity in Organization routines literature views the firm as bundle of routines and procedures (Nelson & Win ter, 1982), with the firm primar il y concerned with optimally managing them. Here, the diversity among firms is attributed to the difference in how they manage and deploy routines in order to coordinate their work. Social relations literature views the firm as a bundle (or network) of relationships, with firms managing these relationships in many diverse ways. Thus, the three streams of literature emphasize theoretical ly different mechanisms by which firms coordinate their work That is, the use of contractu al structuring, the use of boundary objects to deploy routines and procedures, and the use of common ground in relationships. However, this study of coordination refers to the work that firms perform both within and at their boundaries, with organization a nd alliance literatures, respectively, focusing on each. Coordination by Structuring of Work Whenever two or more agencies come together to perform work, their objectives for cooperation are unlikely to be the same. In such circumstances, the firms make use of ex ante and formal structuring mechanisms, like contracts, to bring about consensus between the agencies regarding their expectations and their responsibilities. The contract align s the objectives of the agencies involved, and guide the coordinatio n of

PAGE 76

76 work both in the present and the future. With this perspective, formal structuring mechanisms such as contractual documentation, employment contracts, or organizational structures emerge as important mechanisms to bring about coordination by achieving authority, formalization, and/or centralization. Coordination by U se of B oundary O bjects specific objects. These objects manifest over time as the need for them is identifie d; then they are adapted to the context, and finally implemented. These objects serve to mitigate the cognitive challenges that managers face in accessing, sharing, and storing at the same time bringing about agreement, predictability, and common understanding between the agencies coordinating the work (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ). Timetabling, scheduling, adoption of procedures, and deployment of formal information systems are some such objects that firms enact and deploy to accomplish work at their boundaries, and we refer to them as purposive enacted boundary objects for coordination. As the enactment of these boundary objects takes place in a specific context which itself is lik ely to mold what they are, specific to the present context of highway construction, I refer to these as highway specific boundary objects (HSBOs) Coordination by U se of C ommon G round Along with using coordination mechanisms, like contracts and structures that are ex ante and the enactment of purposive boundary objects for coordination, firms may create common ground between the coordinating agencies. Common ground makes way for tacit and spontaneous coordination mechanisms to manifest, as and when the ne ed arises, recognizing that economic transactions occur in a social context In order

PAGE 77

77 to bring about coordination common ground relies on the use of: social relationships, trust, common knowledge, shared characteristics, social norms, cultural and informa l interactions, prior relations, and mutual adjustments. Common ground addresses coordination challenges through mutual adaptation and adjustment of the agencies to based enactments and the use of boundary objects for achieving coordination, with no ex ante specifications. However, while common ground allows for the use of spontaneous mechanisms of coordination, the development of common ground itself is not spontaneous, and firms working together must recognize th e need for it, work towards creating it, and finally deploy it. F ocus and C oordination ante, but then also guides the actions a firm takes in organizing and coordinating its work. Empirically, in cross ante choice to form an alliance or not (Gulati, 1995), and also t he specific design of alliances ( i.e., joint venture or licensing contracts (Anand & Khanna, 20 00) ) At the been found to affect the management and governance of its alliances by molding the post formation dynamics in alliances, such as changes in board composi tions, alterations in contracts, and changes in monitoring mechanisms (Reuer, Zollo, & Singh, experience of a firm can be conceptualized in many different ways. That is, a diversification experience can be viewed as experience in related and unrelated domains (Palich, Cardinal, & Miller, 2000), its innovation experience can be seen as experience with exploratory or exploitative innovation (Hoang & Rothaermel, 2010), and

PAGE 78

78 its alliance experience can be viewed as partner specific or as general collaborative experience (Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002). The identification and measurement of the different kinds of experience becomes all the more important, as the different kinds of a simplifying alternative on the focal line of business. The focus of a firm on its product and its business portfolio has been recognized as the central issue f aced by every firm ( Rivkin & Siggelkow, focus is of prime importance for it to withsta nd competition, Fulghieri & Sevilir (2009) have found the focus of venture capital firms to be a key antecedent to the performance of entrepreneurial startups they fund, Huckman & Zinner (2008) have found the focus of biopharmaceutical firms to affect oper ational performance, and, more broadly, the its performance (Palich, Cardinal, & Miller, 2000). a deeper understanding of how the activity is carried out (Skinner, 1974). A source of some these advantages is t he specialization and division of labor that focus brings the f ocus frees up

PAGE 79

79 ma nagers from the operation of activities unrelated to the core business, and enables them to focus on the core business to which their managerial skills are more suited (M a hlotra, & McLeod 1997). It also reduces the ambiguity the firm faces as it is expose d to a lesser variety or ways in which work can be done (Skinner, 1974), and helps to bring about clarity in how the focal activity is to be performed (Taylor, 1911; Smith, 1776). A focus reduces the efficiency losses for the firm, as the firm is no longer required to transfer its core business competencies to widely varying markets where they may not be the most efficient ( Montgomery & Wernerfelt, 1988). In the context of venture capital firms and the entrepreneurial startups that they fund, the focus of such firms on the business activity of the startup enables the parent venture capital firm to add more value to the startup. It also limits the competition that the entrepreneurial firm faces for the limited resources of the venture capital, and reduces th e ability of the (Fulghieri & Sevilir, 2009). focus can be challenging, as firms can focus around product lines, process technologies, or geographic or customer groups (Hayes, Pisano, Upton, & Wheelwright, 2005; Huckman & Zinner, 2008). However, specific to the context of interest, these multiple dimensions may overlap substantially, such that f ocus along two or more dimensions may become indistinguishable (Huckman & Zinner, 2008; Ketokivi & Jokinen, 2006). Regrading domain), and on the PPP way of working (organizational domain). These two kinds of focus entail very different

PAGE 80

80 approaches to work prior experience comes from highway construction) enables the firm to develop a common and uniform (highway sector specific) understanding between the firm and the project, allows it to specialize in the construction of highways and creates a unique set of sector working (i.e., the extent to which prior experience comes from PPP projects) enables the firm to develop a deeper understanding of how to form and attributed to the firm, and utilizes work practices that can be easily shared with other project agencies and which are high in tra nsparency, all of which are specific and unique to the PPP way of working. H ighway F ocus and U se of C oordination M echanisms Highway construction is a unique construction domain in a number of ways. Firstly, highway construction involves numerous repetitions of a relatively small set of tasks. Accordingly, it requires the use of linear scheduling and planning tools, in which the project resources need to be optimized for continuous usage. Linear s cheduling has its own unique challenges and while s tandardized software solutions implement ing linear scheduling are available, they are not widely adopted in the highway construction industry 1 network scheduling techniques (i.e., PERT and CPM methods) to schedule a complex network of task anteceden ts and preceden ts to optimize the use of project resources !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 Th is claim is based on personal communication with two professors of construction management at the U niversity of Florida who focus their research on highway construction, and a highway planning professional.

PAGE 81

81 This scheduling can get very complex, necessitating the use of complex scheduling algorithms. Hence, almost all large scale con struction projects adopt one or another r eadily available standard software packages which implement these algorithms Secondly, highway projects, while involving numerous agencies, are also exposed to a large number of environmental uncertainties as they are longitudinally laid out. T he construction activity is required to be carried out over long lengths of highways, which pass through urban, suburban, and rural landscape s. This exposes the project to the actions of a diverse set of public agencies that need to contribute crucial project resources, like permanent and temporary rights of way. In order to secure these crucial resources for the project, the firm is required t o liaison with a diverse set of public agencies, like local population, town, and district administrations, as well as the primary government client. However, it is important to note that the uniqueness of highway projects does not arise out of the c omplex ity of concurrently working with a large number of agencies, which is a common feature of almost all large construction projects, but rather from the public nature of the external agencies Thirdly, when constructing a highway the government (client) cont racts with the private firm (contractor) using arms length contracts wherein the private firm constructs the highway on public land 2 The involvement of the government makes the coordination challenges in this context unique, as the government is philosop hically and legally different from private firm s (Schaeffer & Loveridge, 200 2 ): it work s towards a different set of objectives (Kale & Singh, 2009; Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006), it work s using a different set of rules and regulations (Mahoney, Mc Gahan, & !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 2 In the Indian highway sector 99% of the highways are owned by the government (India Infrastructure Research, 2010)

PAGE 82

82 Pitelis 2009; Wang & Bunn, 2004), and it possess es a different organizational culture and set of skills (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010). L astly, contracts with public agencies are one off contracts, in which each highway project is competitively bid out by the public agency. I ndividual bids are evaluated based on their own merit, with little financial consideration of similar prior relationships or consideration of difficult to quantify aspects, like trust and social relations. At the same time, as c ontracts between private firms and public agencies are one off, short term, and arms length contracts, they provide little scope for a shadow of the past or a shadow of the future to manifest (Henisz & Levitt, 2009) On the other hand, the strategic allian ce literature, while studying alliances among private firms, emphasizes that the use of trust, social relations, and common understanding enables firms to more partners (Gulati, 1995). This literature also argues that transactional efficiency comes about both due to both the shadow of the past (Blau, 1964; Granovett er 1985, Gulati, 1995) and the shadow of the future (Axlerod, 198 1 ; Ring & Van de Ven, 1992; Parkhe, 1993; Poppo, Zhou, & Ryu, 2008). In the absence of standardized and widely accepted tools to schedule and plan projects in the highway domain, firms focusing on highway construction tend to develo p firm specific templates for carrying out scheduling and planning, like customized spreadsheet based linear scheduling charts. Further, in an attempt to address the complexity involved in concurrently working with a large contingent of external stakehol ders, as well as the uncertainties that they bring in, firms focusing on highway construction develop a unique set of monitoring practices for coordinating the work

PAGE 83

83 using tools like periodic abnormality reports, meeting formats, dispute resolution registe rs, etc. While the amount of experience the firm has in handling highway projects determines the degree to which these highway specific practices are developed and standardized (i.e., HSBOs are developed and standardized) the adoption of the practices (li ke HSBOs) lies in the recognition of the benefits that come from their usage. recognition. In the case of a firm with a high focus in the highway sector, HSBOs are embedde d in firm level routines and are used during the coordination of work with others (Nelson & Winter, 1982; Baum & Ingram, 1998; Argote, 1996) However, to work on a new and distinct project outside of its boundaries (like highway projects) the firm needs t o transfer th e firm level routines and the HSBOs embedded in them to the focal highway project setting (Szulanski, 1996). While the experience of the firm increases the embeddedness of the HSBOs in and e nabl es their a utonomous an d mindless application in the project (Ashforth & Fried, 1988; Becker, 2004; Nelson, 1994), it is the focus of the firm which allows it to unambiguous ly decide on them for adoption. On the other hand, a firm with a low focus on the highway sector derives o nly a small part of its experience from working therein, and a larger part from its construction activities in more conventional construction sectors, like office complexes, townships, power plants, shopping centers, etc. Unlike the highway sector, these s ectors do not involve a linearly laid out construction site highway sector dilutes its expertise in the sector, as the founding managers do not

PAGE 84

84 possess expertise in the diversified portfolio, and such diversification comes about at the behest of the subsequently appointed cor porate managers (Klepper, 2002). The dilution of expertise also comes about since the corporate managers of the firm do not appreciate the unique aspects of the focal line of business (Lu & Beamish, 2001, 2004), as well as because diversification allows th ese corporate managers to use skills that may not be the most suitable for use in the focal sector ( M a hlotra, & McLeod 1997 ). Hence, managers located in firms with less highway focus tend to reduce emphasis on the use of HSBOs. Further, when a firm manage s a large number of business lines, its coordination costs increase, and in an attempt to reduce these costs, corporate managers attempt to aggregate diverse activities by emphasizing the use of common monitoring, control, and coordination systems across i ts business lines and shunning the use of context specific objects While this aggregation may decrease coordination challenges at the corporate level, it increases the m in individual business lines, as the common system that has evolved is a compromised one, which aims to satisfy multiple needs of the different business lines at the same time. For instance, the management of a construction firm often attempts to integrate the planning and monitoring of all its construction business lines using standardize d enterprise project management tools commonly deployed in the construction industry, like Enterprise Microsoft Project ¨ or Primavera ¨ enterprise systems. These systems shift the focus of project management from individual projects to the management of pro ject portfolios. However, this aggregation to the level of project portfolios is not suitable for the highway sector, as it requires linear scheduling, while these systems use network scheduling techniques. Consequently, the actions of

PAGE 85

85 the corporate manage rs, which are targeted towards integrating the planning and monitoring of different construction business lines, compels the highway line of the develop new interface s to its linear scheduling practices and HSBOs increasing inefficiencies. In a highway project, firms work closely with other organizations (i.e., National or State highway public authority and technical consultants) that s pecialize in highway constructio n and understand HSBOs Accordingly even b eyond efficiency consideration, highway projects require the firm to use H SBOs to a ddress the legitimacy and institutional pressures brought about by the highway specialized agencies with whom the firm is required to coordinate work. enhances causal ambiguity about the use of while working on the project, and forces the use of coordination practices that may not be the most appro priate for the context. Consequently, in the case of a firm with a low focus on highway business, the set of practices and boundary objects used for the coordination of work with other project agencies is likely to be a compromise between the requirements of the multi business focused corporate entity and the highway specific organizations, with whom the project work requires coordination. Hence, I hypothesize, the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work in the project, is positive. Highway s are a public infrastructure and it is the responsibility of the government to provide the public with a good public transport infrastructure. Hence, traditionally the

PAGE 86

86 upgradation of highway s has been taken up by outsourcing the construction activities to private firms using short te rm arms length contracts w herein the private firm work s as a contractor to the government. These contracts between the government and private firms limit the risk exposure of the private firm by provid ing a clear division of roles and responsibilities Fu rther, such arms length contracts provide an elaborate set of dispute resolution mechanisms and also provide for arbitration and legal remedies for conflict resolution, if conflicts arise. As such contracts have evolved out of decades of government outsour cing of highway construction to private firms the government has accumulated experience in handling them and such contracts have become more and more complete with time. A t the same time, private firms also gain experience in managing public contracts wi th the government and reduce their e xposure to the construction projects risk s With this increased experience in managing risks at both the government and private firm level s the use of common ground for coordination of project work gets deemphasized. T he government in general, is required to maintain a high level of transparency and fairness while bidding out public contracts (Wang & Bunn, 2004). Hence, public contracts allow little opportunity for a shadow of past or a shadow of the future to manifest More specifically, the evaluation of bids for awarding public contracts like highway construction contracts, cannot take into account unquantifiable aspects, like trust, social relations, or prior partner specific experience, (Axlerod, 198 1 ; Gulati, 1995; Parkhe, 1993; Poppo, Zhou, & Ryu, 2008). Consequently, highway construction focused firms find little benefit s coming from invest ments in building common ground with the government at the project level. At the same time, the significant dif ferences between

PAGE 87

87 private firms and the government makes the generation of common ground between them very time consuming and effort intensive (Kale & Singh, 2009; McGahan, Mahoney, & Pitelis 2009; Schaeffer & Loveridge, 200 2 ; Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhov e, 2006; Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010; Wang & Bunn, 2004). Besides the above arguments, in less developed institutional environments (e.g., developing economies), the presence of common ground between two agencies that transact using a well specified and s eemingly complete arms length contract can lead to a compromise of the contractual obligations of the parties and result in counterproductive results ( Rui de Jong, & ten Heuvelhof, 20 08 ). On the other hand, a construction firm with less of a highway focu s is guided by the practices that it adopt s more widely in the construction sector wherein the clients are not the government but other private firms. In contrast to short term contracts between government and private firms, short term contracts between p rivate firms provide a rich ground for both the shadow of the past and the shadow of the future (from one contract to another) to manifest and play an important role in guiding work (Henisz & Levitt, 2009) For example, a prior relationship between the cli ent and the supplier in the construction industry lays the foundation for common ground to emerge in the current project. Furthermore, good coordination in the present project increases the Such considerations make firms with low highway focus emphasize the use of common ground for coordination, guided by their experience in carrying out construction for private firms.

PAGE 88

88 the highway sector reduces the em phasis that it places on the use of common ground for coordination, leading to the second hypothesis the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination wit h other agencies in carrying out work in the project is negative. F ocus and U se of C oordination M echanisms The PPP focus of a construction firm exposes it to the unique aspects of PPP projects, like bundling of project risks (Chen & Chiu, 2010) and the use of SPVs for working the project. As the private firm has to make large front end investments in PPP projects, and these investments have long pay back periods, the bundling of risks increases the risk exposure of the private firm. For instance in PPP projects the construction firm shoulders risks which span a number of domains and go beyond the typical construction project risks, like design fault risks, cost and schedule over run risk s and project completion risks, to also include PPP specif ic risks, like fiscal risks, residual value risk s and bidding or opportunistic renegotiation risks (Checherita & Gifford, 200 8 ). The risk exposure of a PPP focused firm is in sharp contrast to the risk exposure of construction firms that work as contracto r s in typical construction projects. In the later, t he construction firm only shoulders the construction risks of the project, and that too for a relatively short duration of the construction period, which span s 2 3 years in contrast to the 5 99 years of r isk exposure in PPP projects. In PPP projects the work is executed by the SPV, which is a dedicated organization created for the project and distinct from the private firm. SPVs possess unique characteristics, such as having ownership rights over public a ssets and

PAGE 89

89 monopolistic rights for revenue collection from public, and a different kind of working, as the efficiency gains in both project construction and operation are required to be shared with the government. The unique aspects of PPP projects affect h ow firms coordinate their work, as the bundling of risks affects the motivations with which the private firm approaches the project and how the SPV localizes the joint actions taken by the various project agencies. Hence, firms that focus on PPP projects build a long term focus, become adapt at shouldering a larger bundle of project risks, and possess the unique expertise of working in an SPV. To work in an SPV, which lie s outside the firm boundary, and to shoulder a larger bundle of risks over the project s long life, firms need to use coordination mechanisms that can create and leave a trail. Further, in contrast to general construction projects in which the private firm can pocket all the returns coming from efficient operations, in PPP projects the rate of returns of the private firm are often contracted to lie in a pre determined range. The government keeps a tab on the rate of return achieved by the private firm, and t he concession period of the PPP may be varied up or down to ensure that the returns lie in the contracted range. This level of monitoring by the government is only possible if the coordination mechanisms of work leave an explicit trail behind them. In PPP s, firms are required to coordinate with a large and diverse set of stakeholders, who hold significant stakes in the project and come from many different domains. To enable this coordination, the mechanisms used should facilitate and ease communication amo ng the various project stakeholders. For instance, both the financial institutions that lend money to the project, and the consultants who monitor the project

PAGE 90

90 on the behalf of the government, require transparent access to complete project information. At t he same time, the SPV needs to maintain transparency in its actions as it temporarily possess monopolistic rights over a public infrastructure, and the public needs to be continuously assured that the monopolistic rights it holds are not being misused. Th e use of HSBOs as coordination mechanisms not only brings transparency in working, but their real world manifestation s like project schedules, meeting logs, issue registers, etc. are very valuable in creating a permanent trail of work. Hence, to work in a transparent way and to create a trail of the work, firms with a focus on the PPP way of working lay a higher emphasis on the use of HSBOs for coordination. In contrast, when the construction firm has less focus on PPP projects, it is primarily involved in construction projects as a contractor and its actions are guided by its prior experience. In such projects the client shoulders the majority of the project risks, and only the construction risks like design fault risks, cost and schedule over run risk s and project completion risks are delegated to the contractor. As the construction firm is not exposed to risks arising from the activities of other project stakeholders, the need for trail leaving coordination mechanisms does not exist. Also, in such pro jects the construction firm gets involved with the daily operating activities in the project and solely enjoys the returns from efficiency gains ; consequently it possess both the incentive and the ability to keep its working practices (i.e., its own develo ped set of HSBOs) private to itself as a source of sustainable competitive advantage. This makes the firm de emphasize the use of coordination mechanisms that would leave a trail behind ( i.e., HSBOs ) and which would increase transparency with others. More over, in the interest

PAGE 91

91 transparency inducing mechanism s would be discouraged. the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work in the project, is positive. The bundling of risks in and the long term nature of PPP proje cts requires firms working such p rojects to develop a long term commitment to it (Fulghieri & Sevilir, 2009) Consequently, despite the need of a significant amount of effort and time on the part of the firm to develop common ground in the PPP project, co mmon ground is viewed as a source of continued positive returns for the firm over the life of the project. A firm which has worked PPP projects previously, is not only inclined to develop common ground in the project but would also und erstand how, when, a nd where to make time and effort investments to build common ground. The long term nature of PPP projects exposes the project to macroeconomic and financial market movements How such movements would affect the project cannot be fully envisaged ex ante an d addressed in the concession agreements, exposing the construction firm to them and their associated risks, and increase the interdependence among the project agencies. As higher task interdependence can be better managed by the use of spontaneous mechani sms of coordination (Thompson, 1967), and the use of these mechanism s require s the presence of a common ground between the agencies, a firm with a high PPP focus is more likely to emphasize the use of common ground for coordination. In contrast, when a fi rm is less focused on PPP projects, it is guided in its actions by the generic practices of the construction industry, wherein the firm primarily deals

PAGE 92

92 with short term arms length contracts like outsourcing contracts Typically, investments in time and re sources to build and sustain common ground within the project are relatively less important in outsourcing contracts in comparison to long term agreements like PPP contracts 3 Further more due to the involvement of the construction firm with different forms of organizing work the commitment of the firm headquarters to the way of organizing work in the context of the focal project gets diluted (Fulghieri & Sevilir, 2009). This dilution reduces the corporate priority placed on the coordination of the wor k in the focal project, and hence the availability of resources for development of common ground in the project gets constrained. For example, to develop a common ground at the project level, a significant amount of social interaction would be required at both the project and the corporate levels. While social interactions at the project level are spontaneous and exist on account of localization of coordination at the SPV level, social interactions at the corporate level ha ve to be deliberately invoked. How ever, social interaction at the corporate level suffers, as the corporate managers of such firms are less likely to participate in the project s interactions, due to their lack of understanding of the unique PPP context, dilution of commitment to the focal PPP project, and competing requirements of managerial attention from the other lines of business. the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other a gencies in carrying out work in the project, is positive. !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 3 It is argued that a difference exists between a ground when the contracts are short, but possess both a shadow of the future and a has long term contracts. This is in line with t he suggestions of Puranam & Vanneste (2009) and Poppo, Zhou, & Ryu (2008) to disentangle the effects of ex ante trust and ex post trust.

PAGE 93

93 C oordination the strategic choices that he makes on behalf of the firm, and hence molds th working (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 200 8 ). The literature further finds that the For instance, managers with high international experience have been found t o enable firms to enter new foreign markets, since they possess a broader understanding of the global marketplace (Chen & Stucker, 1997). Managers with high experience in position (i.e., tenure) have been found to bring strategic rigidity to ions, as they tend to follow discernible patterns over time and commit the firm to its status quo (Henderson, Miller, & Hambrick, 2006). Similarly, as the industry experience of a manager inserts him into a social setting, wherein the actions, contexts, an d outcomes are subject to shared interpretations with others in the industry, the manager takes actions which display his commitment to the industr practices (Burrell, Morgan, & Morgan, 1979; Hambrick, Geletkanycz, & Fredrickson, 1993). In the context And these are, i) the ii) the iii) the ma distinct kinds of experience lie at different layers of the social system (i.e., industry, organizational form, and firm), they embed the manager in his work context to different ext en ts behavior (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 200 8 ). For example, experience in the highway sector makes the manager rely on industry conventions and industry specific

PAGE 94

94 bodi es of knowledge (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 200 8 ), inserts him/her into the so as to share perceptions with other managers in the industry (Burrell, Morgan, & Morgan, 1979), and molds his/her social construction of realit y specific to the highway industry (Hambrick, Geletkanycz, & Fredrickson, 1993). Similarly, managers possessing experience with the PPP working are exposed to the unique aspects of PPP projects, which have been identified earlier as governance based on pub lic contracts, involvement with public infrastructures, dealing with public agencies, and handling a large bundle of risks with a long term focus. Likewise, tenure with the disce rnible pattern over time (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 2009), brings him more autonomy and power (Miller, 1991), makes him the master of his work (Hambrick & Fukutomi, 1991), affects the sources of his information, and makes him develop a commitment E xperience and U se of B oundary O bjects for C oordination carrying out coordination in the project, it is the manager at the helm who has to implement them. As this implementation requires that these practices be transferred from the firm to the project s context, the manager is required to select the boundary objects for use, adapt them to the new context, and finally decide th e extent to which they are made use of in work (Howard Grenville, 2005). However, this transfer of practice is not likely to be easy, as practices of work are sticky (Szulanski, 1996). This stickiness comes from the characteristics of the sourc ing context from whe nce the practices are borrowed, the characteristics of the rec eiving context where the practices a re deployed, and also from the inherent ambiguity of the extent to which the practice is

PAGE 95

95 likely to be relevant in the new setting (Szulanski, 1996). T plays an important role in how the manager tackles this stickiness of the se practices and molds the choice he makes in transferring the practices from the firm to the project context. A s individuals approach boundary objects with different intentions and orientations (Edmondson, Bohmer, & Pisano, 2001; Howard Grenville, 2005), we expect the placed on using boundary objects for coordinating work. to better understand their use, be more aware of the ways in which they can be adapted for use, and to possess a superior judgment of their usefulness to the project. Also, as the highway experience of the manager exposes him to industry conventions and industry specific bodies of knowle dge, he becomes adept routines to deploy industry specific practices (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 200 8 ). This makes the manager supplement the effects of the boundary objects for coordination and hence strengthen the primary relationship On the other hand, a manager with less experience in the highway sector does not fully appreciate the use of industry specific boundary objects (which have been made highway focus ) as he does not fully understand the unique aspects of the highway sector. In other words, the manager lacks a complete understanding of how the highway specific boundary objects made available by the firm

PAGE 96

96 address the large number of uncertainties associated with highway projects, increase the efficiency of working, and negotiate the legitimacy and institutional pressures while working with highly specialized highway agencies. Accordingly, a manager with low highway ex effects Hence, we expect the positive link between the experience, as the manager i s more comfortable in deploying the highway specific high er focus on the highway sector. the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger PPP projects are a relatively recent phenomenon for the Indian hig hway industry. Hence, managers with more highway experience have primarily earned their experience while working in non PPP projects, which are governed by arms length contracts 4 Such managers are unlikely to fully appreciate the need for transparency in a or the use of coordination mechanism s that leave a trail behind, which are essential for working in PPP projects. This lack of appreciation on the part of the manager primarily comes from the larger share of his/her experience in workin g arms length contracts with pocket all efficiency gains from the project. While coordinating PPP projects, the PPP focus of the firm makes available a set of transpare ncy bringing and trail leaving boundary objects for use, whereas the !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 4 In our sample the average PPP experience of managers is 4.54 years, whereas the average highway experience of manag ers is 12.60 years.

PAGE 97

97 manager with more highway experience sees their usage as unproductive and harmful on account of contradictory assumptions while the firm with increa sed PPP focus creates more and more HSBOs for use in the project, the manager finds them to be unsuitable for use in the project. More specifically, the manager avoids the use of transparency bringing mechanism s and even while deploying firm emphasized HS BOs strips them of their transparency aspects. On the other hand, a manager with less highway experience is unlikely to see the use of to emphasize their usage in the greater highway experience weakens the positive e ffects of the Hypothesis 3b: The positive relationship betw the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become weaker with an boundary objects A manager with greater PPP experience is exposed to the unique aspects of PPP projects, and understands the need for using transparency and trail leaving objects in coordinating them. While a firm with a large highway focus does not recogn ize these unique aspects, it does possess a set of highway specific boundary objects (HSBOs), which it uses when dealing with the government in arms length contracts. Hence, while the firm emphasizes the use of these boundary objects to achieve efficiency through specialization, the manager with PPP experience complements these affects with different intentions and orientations. The manager with a more PPP experience sees

PAGE 98

98 them as mechanisms that increase transparency and leave work trails, which as per his experience are important for coordinating PPP projects. Further, the high PPP experience of the manager makes him better equipped to choose the most unambiguous repository of highway specific practices. In effect, the manager compensate s and molds the firm s use o f boundary objects such that those used enable better documentation of the project, bring higher transparency, and leave reliable trials behind. Hence, we can expect a manager with a extensive PPP experience to increase the emphasis placed on the use of HS BOs which have been unambiguously made highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordi nation with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger When a manager with greater PPP experience works for a firm with a high PPP focus, both the unique aspects of PPP project working are similar and complement each others, such that each emphasize s the other i n the use of boundary objects That is, while the firm with a PPP focus calls attention to the use of transparency bringing trail leaving a nd communication enabling HSBOs, the manager recognizes th ese unique roles of H SBOs and emphasizes their use for coordination of work And we can expect the emphasis and underscoring of the use of HSBOs by the manager to increase as the manager gains exper ience with the PPP form. the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination

PAGE 99

99 with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger with an increase in t bringing strategic rigidity to actions he takes on its behalf (Henderson, Miller, & Hambrick, 2006), hence a manager s firm tenure can be expected to reinforce dominant paradigm. More specifically, when a manger has a high tenure with a firm that has a high focus on the highway sector, the manager enhances the positive e ffects of the HSBOs for coordination, recognizing that their use bring s of working, identifies with the firm, and also of boundary objects to use. On the other hand, managers with low firm tenure are less specific routines, such that the complementing e ffects would no t exist. the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger with an increase in the manag A manager working for a firm with a the use of boundary objects as bringing about transparency with the other project agencies. However, if the manager has a high tenure with the firm he finds it to be an undesirable situation. In PPP projects the firm takes up most of the project risks, makes significant front end investments, and is committed to the project over its long concession period, hence the need for transparency with other project age ncies seems unwarranted to a manager who identifies with the firm on account of his high tenure.

PAGE 100

100 Hence, the manager with a high firm tenure is uncomfortable in sharing complete project information and laying out his cards in the open, where even the compet itors are likely to see them. Accordingly, such a manager would work to reduce the emphasis that the firm places on the use of boundary objects for coordination. On the other hand, a manager with l ow firm tenure is unlikely to possess such commitments to the firm, and will instead objects for work in the project, boosting the already positive effects. the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of HSBOs for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become weaker with an E xperience and U se of C ommon G round for C oordination Different kinds of m anager experience embed the ma nager in different layers of the social system (i.e., industry level, organizational form level and firm level). This embeddedness differently molds his intentions and orientations and consequently affects the actions he takes (Feldman & Pentland, 2003; H oward Grenville, 2005; Sewell, 1992; Zaheer, McEvily & Perrone, 1998). Hence, it is expected that the earlier hypothesized relationships between the s focus of experience and the use of common ground for coordinating work would be moderated differently by the different kinds of experience that the manager possesses. social setting This molds th social construction of reality to the industr social setting where in he shares his perceptions with other managers in the industry (Burrell, Morgan, & Morgan, 1979; Hambrick, Geletkanycz, & Fredrickson, 1993).

PAGE 101

101 Further, working for an extend ed time in a specific sector allows the manager to develop an extensive set of professional contacts and a network of social relations hips in the sector. A s a result, t he manager possess es a shared understanding and common ground with other managers in the sector. The recognition of the unique aspects of public contracts and also the differences between the private firms and public agencies makes the firm with a highway focus reduce its efforts to cultivate and use common ground for coordination. However, a manager with extensive highway experience brings in the valuable resource of social capital ( i.e., shared understanding, common knowledge, and common perceptions with other sector managers ) for use by the firm in the project. Hence, while operationalizin g the firm s intentions while working o n the project the manager gets guided by both the requirement at the firm level to make investments to develop common ground and also the social capital that he possesses and brings with him. More specifically, t he creation of common ground requires the capabilities to create common grou nd and purposive investments and while ground. Accordingly, the negative e ffects of a common ground is likely to be weakened by the presence of a manager with more experience in the highway sector. On the other hand, a manager with less highway experience is unable to bring this reducin g investments in the creation or use of common ground at the project level. Hence, such a

PAGE 102

102 manager would not only not be able to compensate would also e the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become s highway experience. A firm with high PPP focus understand s the importance of common ground in the project and also how common ground would enable it t o negotiate the uncertainties and risks that characterize long term PPP projects. This causes the firm to emphasize the use of common ground and work to create it. In contrast to the earlier case, t he complements the a mplifies the already positive e ffects of the A manager with less h ighway experience does not possess the required social capital of personal contacts ; he is not in a position to complement the positive e ffects of the H the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger P experience enables him to understand the unique aspects of PPP working. More specifically, the manager recognizes that while being located he is required to manage the project in the presence of significant ma croeconomic risks, while maintaining a long term orientation. This humbles the managers who recognize that it would be easier to negotiat e the unforeseen situations arising out of environmental uncertainty with the active participation of everyone in the project, and hence makes them see the benefits of

PAGE 103

103 common ground (Krishna, Martin, and Noorderhaven, 2006). Similar to the previous argument for Hypothesis 6a, such a manager compensates for the highway focused intentions to invest in buildin g of common ground, and the manager actively attempts to build common ground and weaken the negative e highway focus on the emphasis of common ground for coordination. n the highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become The f the in the domain of PPPs, complement the e ffects of one another. While the firm brings in a clear set of intentions and the recognition that the use of common ground at the project level is necessary to negotiate project risk s the manager contributes by better und erstanding the intentions of the firm, working towards achieving those intentions, and also supplementing the with his expertise in managing PPP project risks. form and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger uniquely locates him in the social system at the firm level affecting his cognitions (Katz, 1982). Firm tenure makes the manager identify with the 2009). Also, the information primarily relying on the intra firm personnel networks for information (Miller, 1991). Accordingly, a manager with long tenure with a firm having a highway focus is only exposed to the firm

PAGE 104

104 on managing such projects, and the intra firm networks that only provide information about highway working. This makes the manager a reflection of the firm, and the manager has cap abilities very similar to those of the firm (Kanter, 197 7 ). Hence, an increase in the him/her to complement the negative e ffects of the negative e ffects stronger highway sector and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out work, will become stronger with an increase in the manage T he PPP mode of delivery for infrastructure projects is only a decade old in the Indian highway industry and has gained importan ce in the last five years Hence, recognition of the unique aspects of PPP s such as the bundling of risks and need for long term focus, has only now started to emerge. Accordingly, a long er firm tenure of the manager at the firm not only implies that the manager has been witness to changes as the firm has adapted itself to the PPP mode but also that the manager i s likely to have been a part of this adaptation As a result, the manager better understand s the firm e ffect s Given that one of the primary aspects of the PPP way of working is the recognition of the ro le of common ground in managing PPP project risks, and consequently the firm s investments in building common ground in the project, the complements and boost s the positive e ffects of the coordination. the PPP form and the emphasis it places on the use of common ground for coordination with other agencies in carrying out w ork, will become stronger

PAGE 105

105 Figure 4 1 Proposed model to study the e ffect of firm and managers experience on the emphasis placed on mechanisms of coordination.

PAGE 106

106 Table 4 1 Summary of hypothe sis Sl. No. Main effects Moderation Hypothesized E ffects Argued rationale Hypotheses about emphasis on highway specific boundary objects 1a highway sector (+)* Lack of ambiguity about use of practices 3a experience (+) Strengthen Knows practices well 4a (+) Strengthen Better select the appropriate practices for use 5a (+) Strengthen 2a focus on PPP working (+) Transparency & fairness requirements to manage distinct aspects of PPP projects 3b h ighway experience ( ) Weaken Lack of understanding PPP context 4b (+) Strengthen Recognition of risk bundling in PPPs 5b ( ) Weaken Hypotheses about emphasis on common ground 1b highway sector ( ) Completeness of arms length contracts, distinctiveness of government public contracts 6a h ighway experience ( + ) Weaken Readily available individual social capital 7a ( + )* Weaken R ecognition of PPP requirements 8a ( ) Strengthen 2b focus on PPP working (+) To manage external uncertainties of the project long term nature of PPPs 6b h ighway experience (+) Strengthen Readily available individual social capital 7b (+) Strengthen R ecognition of PPP requirements 8b (+) ( )* Strengthen N ote : The hypothe ses found significant in the empirical results have been starred and the sign found indicated above.

PAGE 107

107 CHAPTER 5 METHODS AND ANALYSIS The unit of analysis for the study lies at the individual project level, and the sample universe of projects is comprised of the 179 Indian highway projects in the construction phase that are being constructed through the PPP mode. These project ; hence this chapter starts with an overview of this context, and highlights the important increasing privat e investments in this sector through the PPP mode of project execution. The data collection for the study faced some unique challenges in preparation of the survey questionnaire, in specification of the sample universe of projects to be targeted for data c ollection, and in administration of the survey. These unique challenges are discussed in the chapter, after the overview of the empirical context of the study. The variables studied were measured using multiple methods. While the survey questionnaire provi ded measures of how coordination is carried out in the projects, the experience profiles of the responsible project managers was were constructed from data shared on a governm ent website. The last part of the chapter reports on the discriminant validity of the different measures coming from the survey, after a detailed description of the operationalization and measurement of the variables used in the study.

PAGE 108

108 Empirical C ontext of the S tudy Infrastructure is important for growth, and more so for countries wanting to achieve fast paced development (Estache & Fay, 2007). India has set itself a target of 9% annual economic growth for the next five years, and to achieve this growth it envis ions doubling its investments in the infrastructure sector. To illustrate, investments in Indian infrastructure are expected to double from 500 billion USD between 2007 2012 to about 1 trillion USD between 2012 2017. Furthermore, a large percentage of this infrastructure investment will be made in the highway sector, and about a third of this investment will be made by the private sector (Press Information Bureau of India, 2011) Most of this private sector investment will come in the form of equity or debt capital in PPP highway projects, which are the context of this study. Highway C onstruction in India Infrastructure is an umbrella term, and there is a lack of agreement among consensus exists, and the highway sector is unanimously viewed as a key infrastructure sector, being the second largest infrastructure sector next to power generation, and a growing one (http://infrastructure.gov.in). In absolute terms the investments made in the highway sector in India were 144,892 crore Indian rupees (about 31.5 billion USD) between 2002 2 007, and are expected to more than double reach ing 314,152 crore Indian rupees (about 69 billion USD) between 2007 2012. In terms of percentages, while 16.63% of the total infrastructure investment in the country was made on roads and bridges during the p eriod of 2002 2007, 15.28% of the total infrastructure investment is

PAGE 109

109 expected to flow to this sector during the period of 2007 2012 (Planning Commission, Government of India, 2008). The continued growth of the sector is also evident from the fact that whil e the sector was upgrading 5 km of road per day in 2002 2007, it has upgraded 11 km of road per day in 2010 2011, and is building a capacity to upgrade 20 km of road per day (Dash, D.K., 2011 October 17) At the national level, the National Highway Authori ty of India (NHAI) handles road development. This authority was formed in February 1995, after the operationalization of the National Highways Authority of India Act of 1988. This authority is responsible for the development, maintenance, and management of all national highways, that is, those that are under the direct management of the central government. Since its inception, this authority has completed over 200 highway projects, and as of September 1, 2010 it was executing another 230 highway projects. W hile upgrading, construction, and maintenance of national highways has been entrusted to NHAI, state governments are responsible for these activities at economic development, many states have also started their own highway improvement programs. These state level programs are executed by state level road authorities, which have been formed with mandates similar to the one of NHAI As of September 1, 2010, another 200 road upgra de projects are under execution at the state level; however, these projects are invariably smaller in size th a n the national level projects.

PAGE 110

110 While the Indian highway sector has been witnessing phenomenal growth, time and cost over runs plague the Indian hi ghway construction sector, and in October 2010, 143 highway projects in India were identified as facing severe project delivery issues (Dash, D.K., 2010 October 10). Here, project delivery refers to the output of the construction phase of the project. Whil e few studies of the Indian highway sector exist, previous reports on the construction industry in India have found that the industry is prone to such problems, and these problems are not new to the highway sector (Dash, D.K., 2010 October 10; Bandyopadhya y, Swaminathan, & Rohatgi, 2008) In an attempt to identify the key determinants of project success, Jha & Iyer (2006; 2007) surveyed managers of the Indian construction industry in two stages. In the first stage of their study, they found the primary deter minants of construction project success to be coordination between the project agencies, and the commitment and competence of the managers. In the second stage of their study, they found these determinants of project performance to be differently associate d with the four primary facets of a construction project s performance: timely delivery, quality of output, safety of the project, and completion within financial budgets (Duncan, 2003). Private P articipation in Indian H ighway S ector India has a vast netwo rk of about 3.3 million km public roads, the second largest in the world after the road network of the United States of America. Whereas traditionally roads have been constructed, managed, and operated by the government, in the last few decades the private sector has been playing an increasing role in both highway construction and operation in India. Not only has

PAGE 111

111 construction activity moved from the public to the private sector, but the private sector has also been investing in highways, with the emergence of PPP as a viable and attractive option for the development of transport infrastructures with private participation (Bult Spiering & Dewulf, 2006; Davidson, 2010). While about 5% of the investment in roads and bridges came from the private sector during t he five year period of 2002 2007, (i.e., 7004 crore Indian rupees or about 1.5 billion USD), it is expected that almost 3 4 % of the total investment in the sector will come from the private sector between 2007 2012 (i.e., 106792 crore Indian rupees or about 23.5 billion USD). With an increase in the use of PPPs for infrastructure provisioning, many different kinds of PPPs have emerged. As PPPs involve the sharing of risks and responsibilities between the government and the private firm, different kinds of PP Ps reflect the degree to which the private firms take over the risks from the government. For instance, in PPPs structured as BOT (Build, Operate, & Transfer), the private firm only assumes the risks of construction and operati ng the infrastructure, while in PPPs structured as DBOLT (Design, Build, Operate, Lease, & Transfer) the private firm also assumes design and leasing risks associated with the infrastructure ( Boeing Singh & Kalidindi, 2006; Delmon, 2010). While the Indian government has been experime nting with these different kinds of PPPs, the highway sector has been predominantly using the BOFT (Build, Operate, Finance, and Transfer) kind of PPP, and is now moving towards DBOFT, in which the design responsibilities are attributed to the private firm s (India Infrastructure Research, 2010).

PAGE 112

112 Highway projects differ in their traffic projections, and whereas some are expected to be lucrative with respect to toll revenues others are unlikely to breakeven based on toll revenues. These project differences m anifest as differences in how the government positively or negatively compensates the private firm, and PPP highway projects get categorized as toll based, positive grant, or negative grant. PPP projects in which the up front investments and projected retu rns are balanced get categorized as toll based projects Herein the private firm upgrades the highway, operates it, and collects the toll revenues for the contracted period to compensate itself for the initial investments. For projects in which t he project ed toll collections fall short of the initially required financial investments, the government is required to compensate the private firms for undertaking the project. This compensation by the government comes in the form of viability gap funding (VGF), an d such projects get categorized as negative grant projects In contrast, if the projected toll collections from the project exceed the investments required of the private firm, the firm is required to compensate the government by sharing the toll revenues or giving a lump sum amount to the government at the start of the project, making these positive grant projects At the same time, if these negative or positive grants are provided in lump sum at the start of the project the projects are categorized as grant projects. In contrast, if these grants are made on an annual or biannual basis, the projects are categorized as annuity projects The Indian highway sector uses all of these different kinds of PPP projects.

PAGE 113

113 Data C ollection Sample U niverse of P rojects The universe of projects for this study consists of all hi ghway PPP projects in India at the national and state levels that are in the construction stage. To construct this sample universe we compiled a list of highway PPP projects that ha d been undertaken in India as of Sept 2010, being guided by the online dat abase of PPP projects in India maintained by Ministry of Finance, Government of India ( i.e., www.pppindia.nic.in ) 376 of the 703 PPP projects in this database are highway upgradation projects. While some of the p rojects on this list of 376 had been completed, others were in different stages of execution, and some had not even started. To maintain homogeneity in the sample of projects studied, it was decided to only study projects that were in various stages of con struction. The construction stage is the most important stage of an infrastructure upgradation projects and coordination is of prime importance during this stage (Iyer & Jha, 2005; 2006). In particular, it is during this stage that coordination challenges continuously emerge and the different project participants need to interact frequently to handle them ( Boeing Singh & Kalidindi, 2006; Delmon, 2010). Therefore, the next step in the creation of the sample universe for study involved identification of proj ects at the construction stage As both the beginning and the end of the construction stage can be ambiguous (Duncan, 2003), a clear logic was required to establish a cut in and cut out date for including projects in the sample universe. The signing date o f the concession agreement was chosen as the cut in date for a project to be included in the study sample. This choice made the

PAGE 114

114 inclusion criterion for the projects unambiguous, as the signing date of the concession agreement is sacrosanct, has legal valid ation, and is widely known. In the context studied, the private firm awarded the project by the g overnment is allowed six months to achieve financial closure, and the concession agreement is signed only when financial closure has been achieved. Hence, with the knowledge that the firm will need to soon begin construction work, the firm initiates resource mobilization for the project, creates the SPV for the PPPs working, and starts project planning long b efore the actual signing of the concession agreement, but no physical work begins un til the agreement is signed. Hence, full fledged coordination in the project can be expected to start with the signing of the concession agreement. The cut off date for project inclusion was set as one year from the date of co mmercial operation. As in the case of the concession agreement date, this date is unambiguous and widely known as it signifies the end of the defect liability period of the project. The defect liability period is an essential part of the construction stag e, and during this period the managers of the different project agencies continue to interact and finish the leftover work in the project. While the intensity of interactions between the project managers fades out as time elapses after the start of commerc ial operation, we can expect the use of the same coordination mechanism during this period that were established during the construction phase. Further, as the managers are still handling the same project, we do not expect them to bring in any retrospecti ve bias, which would have come

PAGE 115

115 in if too large a time would have appeared if too great a time had been al lowed to elapse between the event and research observation (Hinkin, 1998). With the establishment of these cut in and cut off dates, the reduced sample of projects consists of PPP highway projects in India (both at the central government and state government levels) that were at any stage between financial closure and one year p ast the date of commercial operation as of September 1, 2010. Of the 376 PPP highway and road projects identified earlier, 179 were identified to be in the construction stage, with 126 at the national level and 53 at the state level. Preparation of the S ur vey Q uestionnaire The managers who coordinate the work in a project are the best source of information about the mechanisms of coordination used in the project. Hence, a survey questionnaire was used to measure the emphasis that managers placed on the use of different mechanisms of coordination (i.e., use of boundary objects and common ground). The PPP context is very unique, and no prior studies could be identified that had sought to examine coordination in this context forcing us to create our own survey questionnaire for use in the study. The recommendations made by Hinkin (1998) directed the steps that we took for preparing the survey questionnaire. The literature studying coordination in alliances and in organizations guided our identi fication of the survey items to be used in the questionnaire. For this, prior studies were surveyed and a comprehensive list of survey items that measured coordination was compiled. The items in this list were then analyzed to identify the mechanisms of coordination that they measured. This identification

PAGE 116

116 led to the categorization of the items into the three distinct dimensions ( i.e., structuring of work, use of boundary objects, and use of common ground ) This theoretical exercise led to a preliminary list of survey items to be used in the survey questionnaire. After ensuring that the survey items captured all of the different aspects of work in which coordination needs to be carried out, these items were written out and the first draft of the survey questionnaire prepared To validate this draft questionnaire, and to ensure that it had theoretical validity in measuring the proposed constructs, fellow graduate students were requested to comment on the dimensions of coordination that the questions sought to capture, and thei r responses were used to reword the questions, as necessary With this preliminary validation, the questions were next contextualized to the construction industry, and more specifically to the Indian highway construction industry and the working of PPPs. T h is contextualization led to significant changes in the wording of the questions. For instance, to bring clarity in the questions, the use of theoretical constructs was substituted with their and scheduling are the primary way s in which boundary objects are used in highw s meaning in the construction context, examples were provided. For instance, while asking the

PAGE 117

117 respondents whether the planning and scheduling was agreed to by the different agencies, an example was provided which explained the survey item as necessary as the earlier identified mechanisms of coordination are theoretical constructs, and their usage in the instrument would have been a source of ambiguity to managers in the field. To ensure that the contextualized items in the questionnaire were clear, unambiguous, cognitively easy to answer, and addressed the o bjectives of the research, industry professionals and academicians from a wide range of disciplines were requested to comment on them (Hinkin, 1998). Some of those who obliged to our request were: management faculty and graduate students who have significa nt experience in implementing organizational behavior surveys; two post doctoral fellows, one each from India and Portugal, who had experience in both the industry and academics, and had previously administered surveys for their research; PhD candidates in the area of construction management; academicians in India with a specialization in construction management and who had previously surveyed managers in the Indian construction industry ; and Indian highway industry experts. Their suggestions and recommen dations were accommodated in the final revised draft of the questionnaire administered, which is included as an appendix. Administration of the S urvey With both the survey questionnaire and the universe of projects to be sampled ready, the next step involv ed identification of the survey subjects: the key managers responsible for executing these projects and who had knowledge

PAGE 118

118 of how the project was being coordinated. For this, a two pronged approach was adopted. First, the corporate offices of the construct ion and consulting firms involved with PPP projects in India were contacted. After briefing the corporate officers of the nature of the study, they were requested to share the contact details of managers working at the project level. Secondly, the field le vel officers of NHAI and the state highway authorities (PD) were contacted. They were not only requested to fill out the survey questionnaire for the projects in their and obtained, a snowballing method was adopted to identify other managers who could possibly be contacted to fill out the survey questionnaire. A survey of field managers is a difficult task as managers have to take time from their fieldwork to fill out the survey questionnaire and they also need to come out of their work domains and daily routines to read, understand, and respond to the survey items. In the Indian constructio n industry, this task becomes even more difficult as the industry is recognized for its lack of emphasis on structured data analysis and use of systematic tools (Mahalingam, 2005). Further, these managers who are invariably engineers, are not accustomed t o answering survey questions or filling out survey questionnaires, and question the survey methodology of data collection (Jha & Iyer, 2006 a b ). To add to this, the sector has recently witnessed a number of political and ethical controversies, including corruption allegations at various levels. This made managers reluctant to participate in the study, or to willingly part with project information, as they

PAGE 119

119 were unclear on how the information provided by them would be used, and feared that the information provided may be shared with the press, vigilance, audit, or with their competitors, to their personal disadvantage. Mahalingam (2005) and Rui, de Jong, & ten Heuvelhof (2008) who have conducted research in the transport sectors in India and China, respect ively, have also reported similar difficulties in getting access to respondents. To address these challenges, the respondents were required to be convinced of the genuine and academic nature of the study, along with the confidentiality of their responses. The respondents were made comfortable with participat ing in the study by providing a letter of support from the university, emphasizing confidentiality and its academic nature. Further, t he background of the researcher ( i.e., Indian government service ) enabled the respondents to feel comfortable in answering the survey items. At the same time, besides verbal assurances to the respondents that their responses would be kept confidential, the survey questionnaire was modified such that the respondents wer e neither required to provide their signatures, name, nor a ny other identification information Also, to make the task of filling out the survey questionnaire as easy as possible for the respondents, the questionnaire was made available in various formats: web form, Adobe Acrobat ¨ document, and Microsoft Word ¨ document, with the respondents free to chose the format they were most comfortable with. The managers were contacted using telephone calls, short messaging service s emails, and postal letters, and in variably 3 to 4 attempts were required to be made before the questionnaire was filled out and returned. The managers

PAGE 120

120 were not compensated in any manner for participating in the study. After an extensive 3 month data collection effort, 56 survey responses f rom 45 distinct projects were collected. However, after accounting for missing data in the information is available on only 42 projects, and these have been used in the empi rical study. Due to the use of the snowballing method to identify likely respondents, we very soon lost count of the people to whom the survey was forwarded, hence the response rate cannot be calculated. However, we can calculate the coverage of the survey by considering the universe of projects that were targeted. This coverage rate comes to 25.5%, as responses were received from 45 of the 176 projects that constituted our sample universe. Measurement of the V ariables E xperience The main hypothesis (i.e., Hypothesis 1a, 1b, 2a, & 2b) in the theoretical model proposed in Chapter 4 argue s business on the use of coordination mechanisms. In the context of highway construction using the PPP mode, two distinct kinds of firm focus are relevant ( a focus on the organizational domain in the PPP way of working ) Data from secondary sources has been used to construct these variables. Very recent ly (in March 2011), the NHAI changed its bidding process for highway projects, and instead of carrying out technical evaluation of the bidding firms each time a project is to be taken up, decided to prequalify construction

PAGE 121

121 firms active in the Indian highwa y sector. To qualify for bidding in future highway projects, construction firms were requested to provide complete details of their current financial profile and the last five years of construction experience in specified formats. The data provided by the individual firms was then crosschecked by government personnel and the finalized formats compiled and shared on the NHAI website in May 2011. The measures of a based on this authenticated data of a As firms may possess construction experience in many different domains, the nature of the construction project specifies the kind of experience the firm has. Distinguishing among the different kinds of projects in which the firms claimed experience, they w ere categorized based on the mandate given by the Planning Commission of India (www.pppindia.nic.in) As per this categorization, the technical experience of a firm is to be assessed in terms of (a) project experience in BOT projects in the focal sector (b ) project experience in BOT projects in the core sector (c) construction experience in the focal sector and (d) construction experience in the core sector. Specific to the context of highway PPP projects, this categorization has evolved as, while ensurin g no double counting of projects: Category 1. E xperience in eligible projects 1 in the highway sector 2 which have been undertaken as a PPP project s where output or services are made to a public sector entity or for providing non discriminatory access to users. !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 Eligible projects are those infrastructure projects that constitute a natural monopoly such as airport s port s highway s or power plant s Further, only those projects are considered in which the capital cost is more th a n Rs 100 crore, the firm is own s a minimum of 26% of the project, and the project has been under taken in the last 5 years. 2 The h ighway sector is defined more broadly to include highways, expressways, bridges, tunnels, and airfields.

PAGE 122

122 Category 2. Project experience in eligible projects in the c ore sector 3 Category 3. Construction experience in projects in highway sector. Category 4. Construction experience in projects in core sector. ch the focal sector is a dominant line of business for the firm, and is reflected by the proportion of its is ghway domain to the total construction experience of the firm. More specifically, it was computed as a ratio of the sum of the capital values of projects in category 1 and category 3, divided by the sum of the capital value of all the construction projects executed by the firm (categor ies 1 4 combined ). working in projects is the dominant line of business for the firm, and is reflected by the proportion of total revenue that it receives from undertaking PPP projects. experience coming from the PPP projects to the total construction experience of the firm. More specifically, it was computed as the ratio of the sum of the capital values of projects in category 1 and category 2, divided by the sum of the capital !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 3 The c ore sector includes a broad er set of infrastructure, such as power plants telecom, ports, airports, railways, metro rail, industrial parks and estates, logistics parks, pipelines, irrigation, water supply, sewerage, and real e state development.

PAGE 123

123 value of all the construction projects executed by the firm (category 1 4 combined ). The firm focus variables are ratio variables, and it is essential that the model using ratio variables should have the denominator as a control in the model (Wiseman, 2009). Hence, the sum of the capital value of all the construction projects executed by the firm ( c atego r ies 1 4 combined ), which is the denominator in both of the focus variables, was used as control in the model. E xperience The survey questionnaire used to capture the use of coordination mechanisms also collected a de mographic and experience profile of the respondent. However, to ensure that we had a higher response rate, the respondents were not restricted to projects managers (PM), but instead included other managers who were closely associated with the project s wor king ( i.e., public managers (PD) and consultant team leaders (IC) ) Hence, the demographic information reported in the survey questionnaires did not always provide the experience profile of the project manager. Consequently, we had to once again contact th e firms and collect the experience profile of the project manager For the projects in which the survey had been filled out by the project managers, this second phase of data on the reported exactly the same data as reported in the earlier survey, assuring us that

PAGE 124

124 no problems existed in managers recalling and reporting their own experience profiles 4 The proposed model seeks to study the e ffects of three distinct kinds of manager ial experiences ( i.e., highway experience, PPP exp erience, and firm tenure ) Hence, when managers were contacted they were requested to indicate: the number of years (and number of projects) that they have been associated with the highway sector, in any role; the number of years (and number of projects) t hat they have been associated with PPP projects; and their firm tenure or the year that they had last joined the firm. This information was used to create Use of B oundary O bjects for C oordination T he boundary objects for coordination at the firm boundary are comprise d of schedules and plans prepared by mutual consultation (Fang & Zou, 2009) along with operational targets, rules, and procedures which are jointly prepared (Fang & Zou, 2009; Luo, 20 08; Schreiner, Kale, & Corsten, 2009). In the context of highway project coordination, five survey items were used to measure the of the extent of use of these boundary objects in the coordination of work among the managers of the clie nt (PD), private firm (PM), and consultant (IC). Specifically, the survey responses were recorded using a five point Likert scale, with the scale being not at all, low, moderate, high and very high. The items measured the degree to which scheduling and pla nning has been done in consultation with other project agencies, has been agreed upon by !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 4 In a few cases, the managers respon sible for the projects could not be identified. Here, the experience information of these managers was collected from people who had known them personally.

PAGE 125

125 different agencies, has specified operational targets, has specified operational rules and procedures, and has specified the involvement of the different agencies. The se are items 19 to 23 in the survey questionnaire presented in the appendix. The responses to two of these items correlated with the other three items at less then 0.4, hence they were discarded to improve the reliability of the subsequent measure to be us Use of C ommon G round for C oordination A set of five survey items measured the emphasis that the managers (PD, PM, and IC) placed on the use of common ground for coordination. The responses were recorded on the same scale used for measuring the use of boundary objects. The items measured the degree to which shared understanding, cultural similarities (Gulati, Lawrence, & Puranam, 2005; Luo, 2008), and shared identity and informal norms (Malone & Crowston, 1994) exist in the project and the extent to which problems are treated as joint rather than individual (Gulati & Sytch, 2007). These are items 36 to 40 in the survey Amount of C oor dination Different projects work with different levels of coordination, that is some homogeneity in the projects studied while studying the antecedents to the use of different coord ination mechanisms, the total level of existing coordination in the project must necessarily be controlled. Primarily guided by the measures of coordination used by Schilke & Goerzen (2010) and Mohr & Spekman (1994), a set of three survey questions

PAGE 126

126 was use d to access the amount to which coordination existed in the project. These survey questions asked the survey participant to indicate the extent to which the partners in the alliance coordinated in a smooth and cordial manner, and coordinated in making chan ges to the project to accommodate project level uncertainty. These were the first three questions asked and are items 1 3 in the Use of C ontract for C oordination PPPs are contractually governed alliances. Aft er a decade of experience in PPP highway upgradation, the Indian government has reached a high level of maturity in drafting long term concession agreements for governing such alliances and a model concession agreement has been drafted. This model agreeme nt is used as a template for drafting project specific contracts. Consequently, while the project specific contracts differ in the technical parameters arising out of highway alignment and geographic location, the arbitration clauses, role and responsibilities (Reuer & Arino, 2007; Sampson, 2004). Contracts while providing a financial and legal framework for the project, play an important role in facilitating joint problem solving and guiding the interaction between the transacting parties, moreso in non spot market transaction s like alliances (Argyres & Mayer, 2007). They define roles and responsibilities, decision and control rights, communication patterns, contingency planning, a nd dispute resolution mechanisms (Argyres & Mayer, 2007). Further, these mold the actions that partners take while coordinating. Accordingly, while

PAGE 127

127 the concession contracts are similar, based on the same model concession agreement, the manner in which they are used in the project can significantly vary. For example, the contract clauses governing the project may be rigidly or flexibly enforced while working on the project (Faems, et al, 2008), making the project level working different, despite the use of s imilar contracts governing them. To account for the project level differences that come from a difference in emphasis on different contractual clauses, the emphasis on the use of contract s for coordination has been measured and used as a control in the ana lysis. This measure refers to items 4 6 in the survey questionnaire. One of these items was 0.86). Project S pecific C haracteristics Projects differ in their core characteristics and these characteristics can mold the way coordination is done. For instance, the size of a project increases its complexity level, such that larger projects require more time and effort to coordinate (White & Lui, 2005). This makes it is essential to c ontrol for project specific characteristics while studying our research question. Project characteristics along several dimensions have been compiled during the data collection effort. These include the cost of the project, the length of the highway being built, the quality of the detailed project report (DPR), the extent of land acquisition at start of the project, the stage of project progress, the nature of the concession agreement (i.e., positive or negative grant, toll or annuity), debt rating of the S PV, the number of years of concession, the kind of concession

PAGE 128

128 agreement, the date of signing of concession agreement, the initial date of completion, and the nature of involvement of the parent private firm in the project. Also, a subjective list of the ke y problems faced by the projects surveyed has been compiled. Relevant to the study of coordination, the empirical analysis controls for the two most important of these variables. These were identified as the proportion of land acquired at the beginning of the project and the quality of the detailed project report (DPR). The availability of land is one of the biggest hurdles in the upgradation of highways in India ( Bandyopadhyay, Swaminathan, & Rohatgi, 2008 ). The extent to which land is acquired and made av ailable to the SPV at the start of the project determines the degree of interdependence among the different project agencies. Hence, the need to control for the percentage of land acquisition at the start of the project. A single item survey measure was us ed to measure this variable. The quality of the DPR signifies the degree to which the project s uncertainties have been identified and documented ex ante, enabling project managers to plan for them in advance. A DPR of poor quality leaves too many technica l and project issues unaddressed, increasing the interdependence between the project agencies as they need to address these issues jointly during project execution. A single item survey measure was used to capture the perception of the survey respondent a bout the quality of the DPR, using a five point Likert scale with 1 as bad and 5 a s high quality.

PAGE 129

129 Firm S pecific C haracteristics potentially affect the way in which the firm carries out c oordination (Robson, Katsikeas, & Bello, 2008). Larger firms have specialized corporate systems and structures in place to provide project support, while smaller firms need to share their corporate resources, thereby reducing the benefits of specialization to the projects. The net value of the firm, as reported by the firm to the NHAI for prequalification, was available for use as a control variable. However, this was model wo uld have resulted in very high col linearity between independent variables, and thus was not used in the model. Discriminate A nalysis of the S urvey M easures placed on the use of diffe rent coordination mechanisms were captured at the same time using the survey instrument. While the different measures had good reliabilities (the lowest being 0.79, against the generally accepted cutoff limit of 0.7 (Nunnally, 1978)), it is also essential to ensure convergent and discriminate validity of the different measures. G uided by Lichtenthaler, Ernst, & Hoegl (2010) and Srikanth & Puranam (201 0 ), who had also show validity of the survey measures they used, we first carried out an exploratory factor analysis (with orthogonal rotation) and later a confirmatory factor analysis. The exploratory factor analysis was conducted by forcing a theory driven four factor solution. The results a re tabulated in Table 5 1. The variables were found to cleanly load on their respective constructs.

PAGE 130

130 In the confirmatory factor analysis, all four constructs were entered as endogenous variables and their respective items as observed variables. The four factors have significant factor loading, as indicated by t va lues significantly more than 1.96. The four factor model (RMSEA=0.07, CFI=0.77) was also far superior to the single factor model (RMSEA =0.18, CFI = 0.22). With the greatest common variance between the estimated factors being only 0.31, the large composite reliabilities indicate strong discriminate validity, supporting the findings of the exploratory factor analysis (Hair, Black, Babin, Anderson, & Tatham, 2006).

PAGE 131

131 Table 5 1 Results of exploratory and confirmatory factor analysis of the coordination survey i tems Construct Item Mean SD Factor loading T value Variance extracted Construct reliability Amount of coordination Use of contract Use of boundary objects Amount of coordination 0.80 A1 3.56 0.82 1 .00 0.78 A2 3.43 0.79 0.92 5.29 0.74 A3 3.13 0.99 1.00 4.78 0.50 Use of contract 0.86 0.18 C1 4 .00 0.87 1.00 0.83 C2 4.04 0.80 0.89 4.59 0.85 Use of boundary objects 0.80 0.25 0.23 P1 3.18 1.06 1.00 0.42 P2 3.26 1.05 1.28 4.68 0.78 P3 3.48 0.99 0.84 3.87 0.49 Use of common ground 0.90 0.31 0.30 0.28 S1 3.36 1.04 1.0 0 0.59 S2 3.23 0.99 0.88 5.60 0.54 S3 3.45 0.99 1.07 7.16 0.78 S4 3.28 0.95 1.01 6.89 0.79 S5 3.35 1.15 1.02 5.67 0.40 Note: The whole set of survey responses (52 complete responses from the 56 total responses received) have been used to create this table.

PAGE 132

132 CHAPTER 6 RESULTS The theoretical model proposed in Chapter 4 was tested using two separate ordinar y least square (OLS) regressions, one for each of the dependent variables ( i.e., use of boundary objects and use of common ground for coordination ) The first part of this chapter reports the results and the robustness checks that were carried out. In the second part of the chapter, an alternate theoretical model is proposed. The small sample size and the inability to use more robust testing procedures prevented us from extensively testing this alternative model, and only the preliminary results of this mod el are being presented. Variables and their C orrelations Table 6 1 summarizes the means, standard deviations, minimum, and maximum values of the studied variables. All of the studied variables were found to span the full range of possible values and possess large standard deviations. For instance, the projects in the sample used the different coordination mechanisms to different degrees. That is, while in some projects no c oordination was reported, in others coordination existed to the full level, with the standard deviations of the different survey measures of coordination lying between 0.75 and 0.87. Similarly, the firms studied also varied in their focus. While some firms focused completely on the highways sector, some focused only on PPP projects, and still others had no or negligible prior experience in the highways sector or PPP working and were new entrants in the domain of PPP highway construction. Table 6 1 also rep orts the correlations between the studied variables and their significance levels. While moderate correlations ( i.e., 0.30 at a significance level less

PAGE 133

133 then 0.05 ) were found between the different survey measures measuring coordination, they are unlikely to be of concern in the empirical analysis as two distinct OLS regressions were run. The highest correlation found was 0.51 between the use of contracts and the use of boundary objects for coordination, and the other correlations lay in the range of 0.37 to 0.50. As the se measures refer to use of different dimensions of the same construct ( i.e., coordination ) such high correlations are expected. However, viewing these high correlations in the light of the exploratory and confirmatory analysis of the variabl es presented in Table 5 1, said correlations are unlikely to be a source of concern. The other set of significant and high correlations were found between the quality of the DPR and the use of coordination mechanisms, and these were all negative lying bet ween 0.48 and 0.28. The quality of the DPR signifies the degree to which the project s uncertainties have been identified and documented ex ante, such that project managers can plan for them in advance. A DPR of poor quality leaves many technical and proje ct issues unaddressed which increases interdependence between the project agencies, as now the y have to come together to address these issues jointly during project execution. The high and negative value of the correlations found supports the above argume nt. More specifically, the results show that an increase in the quality of the DPR is negatively associated with coordination done in the project. This can also be viewed as a confirmation of the seminal argument by Thompson (1967) that higher interdepende nce requires higher coordination, while lower interdependence requires lesser coordination.

PAGE 134

134 s was also found to have high correlations with the different survey measures of coordination mechanisms. However, it is only significant ly correlated with the use of boundary objects, use of contracts, and total amount of coordination, and not with the use of common ground. This pattern of correlations lends support to the arguments in Chapter 4, where it was argued that firms with a highw ay focus are more used to using their own set of highway specific boundary objects and are guided in their work by their larger exposure to work being governed by short term arms length contracts, wherein common ground has little role to play. Regression R esults Antecedents to the U se of B oundary O bjects for C oordination Table 6 2 reports the results of the OLS regression testing the antecedents to the the highway secto r makes it emphasize the use of boundary objects, as the firm not only possesses a unique and specialized set of boundary objects to be used for coordination, but there also exists an unambiguity in their use due to the presence of an agreement between the project and corporate levels on what, how, and where they are = 0.72, s.e = 0.41 in Model II). However Hypothesis 2a, which argued for similar positive e ffects of the PPP working, is unsup 0.13, s.e.= 0.37 in Model II). Six hypotheses were made arguing for the effects of different kinds of manager ial experience on the use of boundary objects (i.e., Hypothesis 3a, 4a, 5a, 6a, 7a, and 8a). However, we only found support for one of 0.12 in Model V). These results support Hypothesis 4a. This hypothesis argued that

PAGE 135

135 managers with a high amount of PPP experience emp hasize the use of boundary mechanism to bring in transparency in working and create a trail of the work. The argument is primarily about how a es for the out in Figure 6.1. The plot shows that managers with high PPP experience are able to increase the emphasis on the use of boundary objects, whereas managers wi th low PPP experience are unable to bring about any such compensatory effects. The interaction e ffects are not only significant but they also improve the overall R square of the model from 0.52 (Model III) to 0.63 (Model V). Further, the interaction e ffects remain significant in the different variations of the model tested ( i.e., Model X, XI & XII ) Antecedents to the U se of C ommon G round for C oordination Table 6 3 reports the results of the OLS regression testing the antecedents of the use of common g round for coordination. In this case, no direct e ffects of the on the use of common ground were found. That is, main Hypothesis 1b and 2b did not 0.08, s.e.= 0.28, s.e.= 0.40, respectively in Model II). While n o main e ffects of manager ial experience were hypothesized, the results reported in Table 6 3 show that the effects on the use of common ground for coordination, although the effects are small 0.08, s.e .= 0.04 in Model III). Again, six hypotheses about the interactions of the the experience were tested (i.e., Hypothesis 3b, 4b, 5b, 6b, 7b, and 8b). Two of these

PAGE 136

136 experience were found to positively interact to affect the use of common ground for 0.14 in Model V). The results are plotted in Figure 6 2. The plots shows that with a higher PPP experience managers ten d to emphasize the use of common ground for coordination when located in a firm with a greater highway focus, whereas these amplification e ffects do not exist when the managers possess low PPP experience. These results support Hypothesis 6a, wherein it was argued that the understanding how work is done in PPP projects, such that the manager with greater PPP experience reduce the negative e ffects of the gro und. The plot supports the argument. Secondly, the = 0.13, s.e.= 0.06). Surprisingly, and contrary to our expectations as per Hypothesis 8b these interactions were found to be negative This negative interaction e ffect is not only significant at the 0.05 levels, but its significance level and sign is consistent across the various empirical models. These results are plotted in Figure 6 3 Hypothesis 8b has argued that managers with high firm tenure in a PPP focused firm complement the Figure 6 4 however, show that managers with high firm tenure decrease the emphasis placed on use of common ground, and th e e ffects get more pronounced as they work in firms with a stronger PPP focus. On the other hand, managers with low firm tenure tend to boost the use of common ground as the PPP focus of the firm increases. Possible explanations for these results are discu ssed in detail in Chapter 7.

PAGE 137

137 These interactions independently improve the models R squared from 0.52 (Model III) to 0.58 (Model V & Model IX), and together they improve the R Squared to 0.68 (Model XI). Also, the e ffects stand significant in various variat ions of the Model tested i.e, Model X, XI, & XII. Robustness C heck While testing for the e ffects of manager and firm experience on the use of the different mechanisms of coordination, no attempts have been made to compare and contrast between the usages of the different coordination mechanism s Hence, two separate regressions were run with different dependent variables ( i.e., use of boundary objects and common ground ) while studying their antecedents. However, both of the dependent variables belong to the domain of coordination, and it becomes important to study the degree to which the variances explained by the two separate equations may overlap, and whether the results found would stand when both the equations are simultaneously estimated. Hence, we run a simultaneous unrelated regression (SUR) with both the dependent variables. These results are presented in Table 6 4. The results of this simultaneous regression show that the effects found earlier remain significant while simultaneously estimating the ant ecedents of the two mechanisms of coordination. Moreover, in some cases the level of significance increase. This assures us that the antecedents of coordination identified above explained unique variances in the dependent variables. Alternative M odel T his study has sought to highlight the role played by manager and firm characteristics in managing alliances and coordinating work performed at the interface between organizations, underscoring the role of the quality of human capital

PAGE 138

138 (capabilities/experien ce specific to the highway industry, PPP form, and the firm). However, while empirically testing the hypothesis, the existing amount of coordination was used as a statistical control This was motivated by the recognition that different projects achieve di fferent levels of coordination, and by controlling for the existing amount of coordination we would be able to bring in homogeneity in the studied sample, such that the effects of other meaningful variables which may a ffect the studied relationship may be separated out. However, an alternate conceptualization is also possible. The different mechanisms of coordination (use of boundary objects and common ground) can be viewed as the distinct coordination mechanism s through experience bring about coordination in the project That is, i t can be argued that the variation in the extent to which coordination is achieved may exist on account of the use of the different coordination mechanisms. 1 More specifically, this alternate conceptualization argues that while the firm focus and manager experience interact to bring about coordination, the coordination that they achieve may come about by two alternate pathways that is by the use of boundary objects or by the use of common ground. This alternate conceptualization makes the different mechanism s of coordination mediate the relationships between the independent variables ( firm focus and manager experience variables ) and the extent to which the project is coordinated. Th is conce ptual model is presented in Figure 6 5 !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 While making this contention, we are still far from arguing that higher coordination is any kind o f a performance measure, as projects may require different levels of coordination, and different kinds of coordination mechanisms may lead to a different performance, and this relationship would be highly contingent on the task and environment characterist ics

PAGE 139

139 Testing this first s tage moderation mediation model requires that the standard errors of the first stage interacting variables be estimated (Edwards & L ambert, 2007). The small sample size (42) in this study restrict s us from carrying out such an analysis and test ing th e alternate conceptualization. However, some preliminary analysis of this model is in order and is presented in Table 6 5. The table presents the results of OLS regression with amount of coordination ( extent o which coordination is achieved) as the dependent variable. These results, though preliminary in nature, are quite interesting and need elaboration. Firstly, the different mechanisms of coordination are associated with different level s of coordinat ion achieved. It is interesting to note that while the use of common ground is significantly associated with the extent of coordination in the project across all models tested the use of boundary objects is only significant in some cases. At the same tim e, the use of contract s for coordination is only significant when the other mechanisms of coordination (boundary objects and common ground) are not present in the model. Hence, it appears that the different coordination mechanism s may be sharing different portions of their variance with the total amount of coordination emphasizing their discriminate validity Secondly, the key variable that was earlier found to affect the use of boundary objects for coordination (the interaction term of the the coordination (Models III, VIII, X & XI). In contrast, the experience variable that predicts the use of common ground for coordination does not signif icantly affect the amount of coordination in the project The plots of the interaction e ffects of the firm focus and the

PAGE 140

140 as per the alternate model are p resented in Figure 6 6 The interaction e ffe cts emerge as very strong, and can be interpreted in the following manner : the e ffects of the highway focus on the extent of coordination achieved PPP experience, such that the s le ads to lesser coordination if the manager has greater PPP experience, but it leads to increased coordination if the manager has l esser PPP experience. T hese results once again underscore the importance of recognizing that firm and manager experiences inter act in their effects on coordination. Secondly, these results identify the uniqueness of the PPP context by indicating that the managers with prior experience in PPP working (i.e distance between the firm and t he project and therewith underemphasize the need for coordination at the project level. These results are consistent across the different models, with or without the mechanisms of coordination in the model (Model VIII and Model X, plotted in Figure 6 5a & Figure 6 5b). The above results can also be interpreted to indicate that while the interaction e ffects of the the mediated by the use of boundary objects, the interaction e ffects of the f experience and the ground. A Sobel test was conducted to check for this mediation (Baron & Kenny, 1986). M ediation by use of common ground was found to be significant at the 0.05 level, wh ereas mediation by the use of the boundary object variable was significant at the 0.10 level.

PAGE 141

141 Table 6 1 Summary of variables and correlations Item Measure Mean S.D. Min Max 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 1 Use of Boundary Objects Survey item 3.34 0.82 1.67 5.00 2 Use of Common Ground Survey item 3.21 0.87 1.00 4.80 0.39 0.01 3 Total A mount of C oordination Survey item 3.29 0.75 1.33 4.67 0.42 0.48 0.01 0.00 4 Use of Contracts Survey item 3.92 0.81 1.50 5.00 0.51 0.50 0.37 0.00 0.00 0.01 5 Quality of DPR Survey item 3.31 1.00 1.00 5.00 (0.46) (0.48) (0.28) (0.31) 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.04 6 Land A cquisition S tatus Percent 0.47 0.30 0.00 1.00 (0.23) (0.10) 0.07 (0.24) 0.18 0.15 0.54 0.67 0.13 0.26 7 Firm s C onstruction E xperience Value 11.97 15.77 0.15 93.14 (0.02) (0.13) (0.06) (0.16) 0.09 (0.08) 0.92 0.43 0.69 0.32 0.55 0.63 8 Firm F ocus on H ighway s Ratio 0.65 0.32 0.09 1.00 0.41 0.23 0.34 0.41 (0.18) 0.18 (0.24) 0.01 0.14 0.03 0.01 0.25 0.26 0.12 9 Firm Fo cus on PPP s Ratio 0.66 0.33 0.00 1.00 0.03 (0.07) 0.28 (0.03) 0.15 0.23 0.05 0.35 0.87 0.64 0.07 0.84 0.35 0.15 0.74 0.02 10 Manager's H ighway E xperience Years 12.33 6.58 1.00 30.00 0.13 0.25 0.23 0.30 (0.07) (0.04) (0.06) 0.35 0.06 0.42 0.12 0.13 0.05 0.67 0.82 0.72 0.02 0.72 11 Manager's PPP E xperience Years 4.56 3.16 0.00 14.00 0.05 (0.17) 0.11 (0.14) (0.07) 0.03 (0.10) 0.17 0.05 0.39 0.75 0.27 0.48 0.38 0.67 0.86 0.51 0.29 0.74 0.01 12 Mana ger's F irm T enure Years 5.75 6.25 0.50 24.00 0.17 (0.06) (0.13) (0.04) 0.09 (0.18) (0.14) 0.00 (0.18) (0.09) 0.02 0.28 0.72 0.41 0.82 0.58 0.26 0.39 1.00 0.25 0.55 0.91 Note: All correlations at more th a n 0.30 are significant at levels less then 0.05. n=42

PAGE 142

142 Table 6 2 Antecedents to the use of boundary objects in PPP projects (n=42) VARIABLES I II III IV V VI VII VII IX X XI XII Total Amount of Coordination 0.26 0.23 0.24 0.26 0.42** 0.24 0.20 0.27 0.24 0.3 9 0.38** 0.37** (0.16) (0.16) (0.16) (0.16) (0.16) (0.17) (0.18) (0.17) (0.17) (0.19) (0.17) (0.15) Use of Contracts 0.32** 0.21 0.28 0.24 0.24 0.28 0.3 2 0.26 0.27 0.27 0.21 0.17 (0.15) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.16) (0.18) (0.19) (0.17) (0.18) (0.20) (0.18) (0.15) Quality of DPR 0.23* 0.2 1 0.2 3 0.18 0.17 0.2 3 0.24* 0.2 2 0.2 3 0.18 0.20 0. 20 (0.11) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.11) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.13) (0.12) (0.10) Land A cquisition S tatus 0.30 0.47 0.34 0.39 0.68* 0.34 0.26 0.41 0.34 0.63 0.63 0.7 1 (0.37) (0.38) (0.38) (0.38) (0.36) (0.39) (0.41) (0.40) (0.39) (0.42) (0.39) (0.35) Firm s C onstruction E xperience 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01* 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Firm F ocus on H ighway s 0.72* 0.68 0.05 0.61 0.69 0.61 0.78* 0.70 0.67 0.60 0.67 (0.41) (0.43) (0.72) (0.58) (0.53) (0.45) (0.45) (0.48) (0.87) (0.72) (0.56) Firm F ocus on PPP s 0.13 0.04 0.06 0.13 0.04 0.45 0.56 0.02 0.01 0.42 (0.37) (0.37) (0.37) (0.33) (0.39) (0.89) (0.78) (0.48) (1.03) (0.87) Manager's H ighway E xperience 0.01 0.07 0.03* 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.06) Manager's PPP E xperience 0.02 0.00 0.2 6 ** 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.02 0.27* 0.2 7 0.26*** (0.04) (0.04) (0.10) (0.04) (0.04) (0.10) (0.04) (0.14) (0.13) (0.09) Manager's F irm T enure 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.00 (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.07 0.01 (0.06) (0.07) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.36*** 0.33* 0. 30 ** 0.3 4 *** (0.12) (0.16) (0.13) (0.11) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.00 0.00 0.00 (0.05) (0.08) (0.07) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.03 0.03 (0.05) (0.06) Firm PPP focus X Manager's PPP 0.09 0.05 0.03 (0.12) (0.15) (0.13) Firm PPP focus X Manager's Tenure 0.00 0.01 0.03 (0.06) (0.09) (0.08) Constant 2.1 1 ** 2.24** 1.80* 2.2 9 ** 2.64*** 1. 80 1.52 2.1 3 ** 1. 80 2.5 6 ** 2.8 3 ** 2.90*** (0.87) (0.86) (0.92) (0.99) (0.87) (0.95) (1.04) (1.02) (0.94) (1.15) (1.02) (0.84) R squared 0.41 0.47 0.52 0.55 0.63 0.52 0.53 0.53 0.52 0.63 0.60 0.58

PAGE 143

143 Table 6 3 Antecedents to the use of common ground in PPP projects (n=42) VARIABLES I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X XI XII Total Amount of Coordination 0.3 3 0.3 8 ** 0. 40 ** 0.4 2 ** 0.55 *** 0.4 2** 0.4 1** 0.3 2* 0.42 ** 0.60*** 0.5 3 *** 0.42** (0.16) (0.18) (0.17) (0.18) (0.18) (0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.17) (0.18) (0.16) (0.16) Use of Contracts 0.3 2 ** 0.325* 0.18 0.15 0.14 0.18 0.17 0.19 0.06 0.07 0.02 0.19 (0.16) (0.17) (0.18) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.18) (0.20) (0.17) (0.15) Quality of DPR 0.2 7 ** 0.25* 0.2 9 ** 0.25* 0.24* 0.3 1 ** 0.28** 0.29** 0.29** 0.21 0.24** 0.29** (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.13) (0.12) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.12) (0.13) (0.11) (0.12) Land A cquisition S tatus 0.02 0.09 0.06 0.03 0.23 0.07 0.04 0.12 0.05 0.25 0.12 0.16 (0.38) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.44) (0.43) (0.39) (0.41) (0.37) (0.37) Firms C onstruction E xperience 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Firm F ocus on H ighway s 0.08 0.07 0.59 1.15* 0.20 0.05 0.15 0.37 1.22 1.14 (0.44) (0.46) (0.78) (0.66) (0.56) (0.48) (0.48) (0.48) (0.84) (0.69) Firm F ocus on PPP s 0.28 0.27 0.28 0.34 0.17 0.40 0.17 0.37 1.01 1.61* 0.51 (0.40) (0.40) (0.40) (0.38) (0.41) (0.95) (0.84) (0.48) (1.00) (0.83) (0.46) Manager's highway E xperience 0.03 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04 (0.02) (0.05) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.06) Manager's PPP E xperience 0.08* 0.09** 0.31*** 0.07 0.08* 0.02 0.04 0.11 0.13 (0.04) (0.04) (0.11) (0.04) (0.04) (0.11) (0.04) (0.14) (0.13) Manager's F irm T enure 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.06* 0.06 0.06 0.0 7 ** (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.05 0.00 (0.06) (0.06) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.30** 0.37** 0.34** (0.14) (0.16) (0.13) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.05 0.04 0.04 (0.06) (0.08) (0.07) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.01 0.06 (0.06) (0.06) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.08 0.2 9 0.2 2 (0.13) (0.14) (0.12) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.1 3 ** 0.17** 0.17** 0.13** (0.06) (0.08) (0.08) (0.05) Constant 1.7 9 1.75* 2.3 7 ** 2.7 1 ** 3.0 7 *** 2.21** 2.44** 2. 1 0* 2.14** 2.67** 2.22** 1.7 2 (0.91) (0.93) (0.98) (1.07) (0.98) (1.00) (1.12) (1.09) (0.93) (1.11) (0.97) (0.87) R squared 0.44 0.45 0.52 0.53 0.58 0.53 0.52 0.52 0.58 0.70 0.68 0.55

PAGE 144

144 Table 6 4 Robustness check: Simultaneous equations regression with both dependent variables predicted together (n=42) VARIABLES I II III IV Total Amount of Coordination 0.3 9 *** 0.60*** 0.37*** 0.57*** (0.15) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14) Use of Contracts 0.27* 0.07 0.18 0.05 (0.16) (0.15) (0.13) (0.14) Quality of DPR 0.18* 0.2 1 ** 0.20** 0.24*** (0.10) (0.10) (0.09) (0.09) Land A cquisition S tatus 0.6 3 0.25 0. 60 0.24 (0.32) (0.31) (0.32) (0.32) Firm C onstruction E xperience 0.01** 0.00 0.01* 0.00 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Firm F ocus on H ighway s 0.67 1.2 2 0.52 0.69 (0.67) (0.65) (0.52) (0.55) Firm F ocus on PPP s 0.01 1.01 0.07 0.23 (0.80) (0.77) (0.29) (0.38) Manager's H ighway E xperience 0.02 0.04 (0.05) (0.04) Manager's PPP E xperience 0.27** 0.11 0.23*** 0.2 7 *** (0.11) (0.10) (0.09) (0.09) Manager's F irm T enure 0.01 0.06** 0.02 0.04 (0.03) (0.03) (0.01) (0.03) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.01 0.00 (0.05) (0.05) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.33*** 0.3 7 *** 0. 30 *** 0.29*** (0.13) (0.12) (0.10) (0.11) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.00 0.04 (0.06) (0.06) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Highway 0.03 0.06 (0.05) (0.04) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.05 0.2 9 *** (0.11) (0.11) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.01 0.17*** 0.1 2 *** (0.07) (0.06) (0.05) Constant 2.5 6 *** 2.67*** 2.6 6 *** 2.81*** (0.89) (0.86) (0.77) (0.78) R squared 0.63 0.70 0.59 0.64

PAGE 145

145 Table 6 5 A lternate model results Antecedents to the extent of coordination achieved in PPP projects. (n=42) VARIABLES I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X XI XII XIII Use of Contracts 0.33** 0.312* 0.310* 0.22 0.20 0.10 0.22 0.20 0.13 0.14 0.25 0.06 0.10 (0.15) (0.18) (0.18) (0.16) (0.16) (0.17) (0.19) (0.17) (0.18) (0.18) (0.18) (0.15) (0.15) Quality of DPR 0.16 0.17 0.19 0.08 0.06 0.01 0.10 0.04 0.01 0.08 0.02 0.08 0.09 (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.12) (0.13) (0.11) (0.11) Land A cquisition S tatus 0.48 0.30 0.54 0.53 0.42 0.47 0.38 0.24 0.30 0.748* 0.23 0.69** 0.634* (0.38) (0.41) (0.41) (0.37) (0.36) (0.36) (0.41) (0.39) (0.39) (0.38) (0.39) (0.32) (0.32) Firm s C onstruction E xperience 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Firm F ocus on H ighway s 0.00 1.03 0.19 0.02 0.14 1.1 3 0.23 1.16** 1.18** (0.46) (0.69) (0.47) (0.44) (0.45) (0.64) (0.48) (0.54) (0.55) Firm F ocus on PPP s 0.64 0.57 0.61 0.647* 0.620* 0.54 0.27 0.28 0.32 (0.39) (0.48) (0.38) (0.36) (0.36) (0.44) (0.48) (0.38) (0.39) Manager's H ighway E xperience 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.02 (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) Manager's PPP E xperience 0.02 0.24** 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.32*** 0.03 0.37*** 0.36*** (0.04) (0.11) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.10) (0.04) (0.09) (0.09) Manager's F irm T enure 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.04 0.02 0.02 (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Firm Highway F ocus X Manager's PPP 0.30** 0.4*** 0.45*** 0.41*** (0.13) (0.13) (0.11) (0.11) Firm PPP F ocus X Manager's Tenure 0.01 0.01 0.07 0.06 0.05 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.05) (0.05) Use of Boundary Objects 0.27 0.26 0.27 0.23 0.45** 0.41*** 0.3 9 ** (0.17) (0.16) (0.19) (0.18) (0.17) (0.15) (0.15) Use of Common Ground 0.31* 0.30* 0.36** 0.34** 0.42** 0.46*** 0.49*** (0.15) (0.15) (0.16) (0.16) (0.17) (0.13) (0.13) Constant 2.2 6 ** 1.8 7 0.91 1.54 1.48 0.83 1.25 0.74 0.29 0.47 0.66 1.8 8 1.86* (0.83) (0.94) (1.00) (0.93) (0.89) (0.96) (1.01) (1.01) (1.05) (1.05) (1.01) (0.99) (1.00) R squared 0.21 0.31 0.41 0.26 0.29 0.33 0.35 0.41 0.44 0.52 0.43 0.67 0.65

PAGE 146

146 Figure 6 1 Plot of i nteraction e ffects of a firm s highway focus and a o bjects "# "$%& "$%' "$%( "$%# "$ ")%& ")%' ")%( ")%# ) )%)$ )%** )%'( )%+, Emphasis on use of boundary objects for coordination Firm's experience focus (Highway experience as a proportion of total experience) Manager's High PPP Experience Manager's Avg PPP Experience Manager's Low PPP Experience

PAGE 147

147 Figure 6 2 Plot of i nteraction e ffects of a firm s highway focus and a m PPP experience on use of common ground. "#%"# "$%"$ ")%) )%)$ )%** )%')%+, Emphasis on use of common ground for coordination Firm's experience focus (Highway experience as a proportion of total experience) Manager's High PPP Experience Manager's Avg PPP Experience Manager's Low PPP Experience

PAGE 148

148 Figure 6 3 Plot of interaction e ffects of a PPP focus and a firm tenure on use of common ground ")%& ")%' ")%( ")%# ) )%# )%( )%' ) )%** )%'' )%++ Emphasis on use of common ground for coordination Firms experience focus ( PPP experience as a proportion of total experience) Manager's High Firm tenure Manager's Avg Firm tenure Manager's Low Firm Tenure

PAGE 149

149 Figure 6 4 The alternate model

PAGE 150

150 Figure 6 5 Plot of i nteraction e ffects in alternate model. A) Interaction of fi rm experience on amount of coordination ( w ithout boundary objects and common ground in model) B) objects and common ground in model). C) Interaction of amount of coordination. ) )%# )%( )%' )%& $ $%# $%( $%' $%& # )%)$ )%** )%'( )%+, Extent of coordination existing Firm's experience focus (Highway experience as a proportion of total experience) Manager's High PPP Experience Manager's Avg PPP Experience Manager's Low PPP Experience A

PAGE 151

151 Figure 6 5 Continued ) )%$ $%# #%* )%)$ )%** )%')%+, Extent of coordination existing Firm's experience focus (Highway experience as a proportion of total experience Manager's High PPP Experience Manager's Avg PPP Experience Manager's Low PPP Experience B

PAGE 152

152 Figure 6 5 Continued ")%* ")%# ")%$ ) )%$ )%# )%* )%( )%)%' )%, )%& ) )%** )%'' )%++ Extent of coordination existing Firm's experience focus (PPP experience as a proportion of total experience) Manager's High Firm tenure Manager's Avg Firm tenure Manager's Low Firm Tenure C

PAGE 153

153 CHAPTER 7 DISCUSSION This chapter discusses the empirical findings, firstly in light of what we already know about coordination of work, and secondly in the context of PPPs wherein work is coordinated at organizational boundaries, the public private interface in our case Whil e doing so, the chapter develops the coordination perspective of work and identifies the distinctive aspects of PPP working. The need for these developments was felt when gaps in the literature were found while reviewing the literature on organizational co ordination and PPP s to study the research questions put forward in Chapter 1 On delving into the literatures studying coordination in organization s and organizational interfaces (i.e., alliance s) it emerged that the literatures have different foci, and b oth had failed to recognize the different aspects of work in which coordination is done. Hence, in this chapter a theoretical model is proposed developing the concept of aspects of coordination Similarly, while studying the existing PPP literature it emer ged that although the literature is vast and ever growing it has little to say about coordinati on of the work in PPPs. To substantiate, b oth the academic and practice literatures which study PPP s are restrict ively focus ed on how structuring mechanisms, like contracts, guide PPP working and fail to build a comprehensive organizational view of PPPs, which covers both structuring and emergent aspects of PPP working. Making an a ttempt towards addressing this gap in the literature, t he later part of this chapter identifies some of the key aspects that would enable the develop ment of a more comprehensive organizational view of PPP s

PAGE 154

154 An I ntegrative C oordination P erspective Contributions to C urrent L iterature Organizations achieve their fu ndamental purpose by coordination of work and this coordination becomes more important when work is required to be done at the boundaries of the organizations. Alliances are one such organizational arrangement wherein work is required to be coordinated at the firms interface, and al liances face coordination challenges to a larger extent (Child & Faulkner, 1998; de Rond & Bouchikhi, 2004; Harrigan, 1985). While studies of coordination in organizations investigate how coordination is carried out (e.g., Lawre nce & Lorsch, 1967; Tsai, 2002), studies of coordination at organizational interfaces, such as alliance studies, are primarily concerned with the antecedents and consequences of coordination and narrowly focus on the degree to which coordination is done. This study contributes to the current literature, firstly by identifying the different mechanisms of coordination used interfaces and s econdly by identifying the role played by the manager in carrying out such coordination. Coordination mechanis ms used at organizational interfaces Organizational literature studying coordination has identified a large number of modes, means, and mechanisms by which coordination is carried out (Ref to Table 2 1 for a summary). At the same time, the literature has also used many different categorizations to classify them f or example group, individual and impersonal modes ( v an de Ven, Delbecq, & Koenig, 1976) ; formal and informal modes (Fang & Zou, 2010; Gulati Lawrence, & Puranam, 2005; Jansen, Tempelaar, Van Den Bosch, & Volberda, 2009; Martinez & Jarillo, 1989) ; objects, plans, roles, routines, and proximity (Okhuysen & Bechky, 2009) ; programmed and non programmed modes (Argote, 1982) ; and

PAGE 155

155 modularization, on going communication, and tacit coordination mechanisms (Srikanth & Puranam, 201 0 ). As discussed in Chapter 2, t he se varied ways of categoriz ing coordination mechanisms make it difficult to aggregate the existing literature A ccordingly, a generic three fol d categorization of coordination mechanisms was developed consisting of: i) coordination by the structuring of task s by task design or organizational design, such as use of contracts; ii) coordination by the enactment and use of purposive boundary objects ; and iii) coordination by relying on common ground. This categorization is an improvement over the earlier attempts as it is theoretically motivated and thus enables us to aggregate existing studies of coordination, as is evident during the formulation o f hypothes e s in Chapter 4 While Chapter 2 discusses the theoretical differences between these categories and Table 2 1 categorizes the different mechanisms of coordination studied in the existing literature as per this refined categorization the empirica l study further emphasizes this categorization by finding discriminant validity between them (Ref to Table 5 1). Hence, the first contribution of this study lies in the specification, development, and confirmation of a robust categorization of the mechanis ms of coordination. While this categorization is new to the coordination literature, it is similar to the categorization of motivational mechanisms suggested by Bridoux, Coeurderoy, & Durand (2011) in the Groups and T eams literature. These authors argue th at teams cooperate using three generic and distinctive motivational mechanisms: monetary incentives, emphasis on disciplined cooperation, and reliance on benevolent cooperation each of which bears similarities to the different coordination mechanisms iden tified by us.

PAGE 156

156 Role of the manager in coordination The coordination literature identifies task and organization characteristics as the primary antecedents to the use of coordination mechanisms. Guided by this research, this study sought to examine a ffects the emphasis placed on the use of different coordination mechanisms. The empirical study found the ( i.e., highway experience ) to be positively associated with the use of purposive boundary objects, but not with the use of ( i.e., PPP organizational working ) was not found to have any direct e ffects on the use of different coordination mecha nisms. These mixed findings lead us to believe that the antecedents to the use of coordination mechanisms cannot be simply linked with a that there may be other important factors at play, which are being ignored in the literatur e. Our search for other factors that may a ffect the use of coordination mechanisms was guided by the upper echelons literature, which has found strong evidence of the important role played by managers in the working of firms. Herein, the experience of the manager has been found to determine the strategic choices made by him (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, 200 8 ). For instance, a manager international experience makes him diversify the firm internationally, as this experience gives the manager a broade r understanding of the global marketplace (Chen & Stucker, 1997). On the other hand, an increase in a avoid strategic changes, as tenure makes him follow discernible patterns over time and ma specific

PAGE 157

157 practices, as industry experience inserts him into a social setting in which actions, c ontexts, and outcomes are subject to industry level shared interpretations (Burrell, Morgan, & Morgan, 1979; Hambrick, Geletkanycz, & Fredrickson, 1993). This stream of st udies that examine the mediating pathways through which the manager affects firm strategy and performance We a coordinating mechanisms is one such pathway through which manager molds a firms working. T he logic al next step involves identif ying the direct e ffects of a experience on the use of coordination mechanism s While no direct hypotheses were made of these relationships, the intermediate models in the empirical study do test for such direct e ffect s, that is Model 3 in Table 6 2 and Model 3 in Table 6 3. Of the three kinds of experience modeled in the study (technical domain experience, PPP working experience, and length of firm tenure), we only found direct negative e ffects of 0.08, s.e.= 0.04 Model III i n Table 6 3). That is, one out of the six e ffects was found to be significant. Thus, it appears that some complex interplay of a a characteristics may be at work when coordination is carried out at organizational interfaces. In an attempt to identify these complex dynamics, we tested for the interaction e so while contributing to the exis ting literature, w e make two significant departures Firstly, by underscoring the role played by the manager we contribute to alliance literature which

PAGE 158

158 has so far only empirically tested the effects of task and firm characteristics on the amount of coordi nation done (Bensaou & Venkatraman, 1995; Gerwin, 2004; Gulati & Sytch, 2007; Mesquita & Brush, 2008; Sobrero & Schrader, 1998; Srikanth & Puranam, 2011; Subramani & Venkatraman, 2003; White & Lui, 2005; Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1998). While the literat ure on alliance management has recognized the importance of it exist, and this study provides the first such test (for e.g., Child & Faulkner, 1998; Galagan, 1990; Spekman, Isabella, & MacAvoy, 2000). Secondly, this research goes beyond the literature that empirically or theoretically identifies the antecedents of coordination to lie in the main e ffects of task, organization, or managerial characteristics. Specifically, th is study determines that these characteri stics interact in laying emphasis on the use of different coordination mechanisms, and the re exists a need to identify these complex moderating conditions. The empirical study finds some moderating conditions. Firstly, the e ffects of a on the emphasis placed on the different mechanism s of coordination ( i.e., the use of boundary objec ts and the use of common ground ) is e ffects on the different mechanism of coor dination exist for different reasons. The effect of a is p ositive ly moderat ed by the as the manager s PPP experience enables him to put to use the practices and objects that the firm akes available to him. In effect, the manager complement s the firm makes an unambiguous set of highway specific practices available for use in the project for efficiency consideration, the ma nager emphasizes the use of these available objects

PAGE 159

159 in the unique context of PPP working as these same objects also bring in transparency and leave a trail behind, and the manager better recognizes their importance on account of his greater PPP experience. The positive moderation effects of the ground highway focus makes the firm deemphasize the use of common ground to coordinate work the manager e reduces the emphasis on the use of common ground, as the firm is primarily guided by its experience in short term contracts with the government, in which investments in common groun d are not of much use. On the other hand, t he manager with PPP and he carries out coordination by emphasizing the use of common ground, which he is able to recognize as i mportant to work in the PPP context Contrary to our hypothesis, the e ffects of a common ground were Hypothesis 8b argued that a manager with a high firm tenure supplements the positive e ffects of a on the emphasis placed on the use of common ground, as the manager was a part of the firm when the firm made the transition from the use of short term highway contracts with the government to the use o f long term PPP concession contracts. The negative moderation e ffects found are not by chance and their effects remain consistently negative in t he different models tested This makes us look for alternate explanations. One such explanation lie s in recognizing the unique aspects of PPP working PPPs distinctively involve bundling of risks and a long term

PAGE 160

160 focus, and these aspects are structurally address ed by the use of SPV s The SPV, while localizing and containing the coordination of work within it, also create s a distance between the firm and the actual work. This is u nique to SPVs, for on the one hand they exist as a division of the private firm, such that the work performed in the SPV is the private firm exists as a holding company for the SPV, such that the financial and organ izational responsibilities for the SPV solely lie with it and the SPV is fully responsible for the projects day to day working along with the decisions taken by the stakeholders of the SPV. Consequently, interests feel the need to reduce the use of spontaneous mechanisms like common ground ( which reduce transparency with the firm and d o not leave a trail ), when the firm is shouldering a large bundle of project risks but working in a distinct organization With these findings, this study contributes to the coordination literature by proposing and testing a more integrative model of coord ination in the alliance context. That is, the study finds evidence that not only can coordination in the alliance context be brought about by the use of different mechanisms but the manager s experience play s an important role in molding the use of c oordi nation mechanism s. Also, the firm characteristics and manager characteristics interact affecting the use of coordination mechanism. Contributing to the upper echelon literature, th is research finds that the the actions by molding the emphasis that s differently At the same time, manager characteristics were found to have few direct e ffects primary moderating the e ffects of

PAGE 161

161 Developing the C oord ination P erspective The organizational literature studies why coordination is done (i.e., sources of coordination challenges), how it is done (i.e., mechanism and modes of coordination), and how much of it is done (i.e., amount and degree of coordination). But while doing so it ignores what is being coordinated. Consequently, the literature has overlooked the fact that work is multi dimensional, and coordination is important in each of the different dimensions. For example, while working together coordinati on is required to be carried out both in exchanging information and also in conflict resolution. Each of these are distinct dimensions of work requiring coordination, and while coordination challenges may exist to different degrees in each of these dimensi ons, even the mechanisms and modes used to address these challenges may also be very different. For instance, while coordination in exchanging information can be done by the use of databases, communication, and information systems; coordination for conflic t resolution requires the use of formal dispute resolution mechanisms, like arbitration, and recognition and accommodation of the other agenc interests. Here the multiple dimension s or facets of work requiring coordination are referred to as different a spects of coordination. Our recognition of the multiple aspects of work requiring coordination is not new to the vast coordination literature. However, existing studies do not explicitly distinguish among the various dimensions but instead club them togeth er into a single construct or focus on only one of the many dimensions For example, Gulati & Sytch (2007) in their study of the US automobile industry clubbed the different dimensions of work together and used a single construct of coordination joint act ion In this study, joint action referred to the extent to which firms in a buyer supplier relationship coordinated in design, quality improvement, cost control, production modification, forecasting, mutual

PAGE 162

162 adjustment, and treating problems as joint responsibilities. On the other hand, Li n & Germain (1998) explicitly stud ied how coordination in conflict resolution is carried out, and Nickerson & Zenger (2004) t ook a problem solving perspective on coordination. Aspects of coordination With a view to identify the different aspects of work c oordination, the coordination literature was revisited. After an extensive exercise which involv ed listing, categorization, and re categorization of the aspect s of work studied in existing literature four theoretically different aspects of work requiring coordination were identified : monitoring and control, decision making, information exchange, and conflict resolution. The need for identifying and differentiating among the different aspects of work emerges as important when one recognizes that work in di fferent contexts essentially differs in the extent to which it requires emphasis on one o r another aspect of work. For instance, coordination in the context of arms length contracts, like buyer supplier relationships or civil contracting is essentially abo ut monitoring and controlling the actions of the other agency. In contrast, research alliances primarily require coordinat i on in the exchange of information, whereas joint marketing efforts primarily require coordination in decision making When work is jo intly performed, not only is the work performed required to be monitored and controlled but also even the behavior and actions of the agency with which work is being coordinated may require monitoring Monitoring and control possess coordination challenges that are above and beyond those brought in by motivational aspects, and are generally studied in the cooperation literature. Because managers are bounded ly rational, even when incentives are fully al igned and the misalignments are of common knowledge, managers need to be aware of the activities

PAGE 163

163 of the other agency Hence, the need exists for the coordinated activities to be visible to the coordinating partners, such that the coordinating agencies may keep a watch on how the work is being performed together, and control it to ensure that the objectives are met. Many options for such monitoring and control exist, and the agencies coordinating the work may independently monitor and control the work, or th ey may come together and coordinate in monitoring and controlling the sub tasks involved (Gulati & Sytch, 2007). To clarify, in the case of alliances monitoring and control refers to the reliance on contractual clauses, use of joint reviews and meetings, or building up common trust with one another that reduces the need for the agencies to monitor each others work (Das & Teng, 2000 ; Kumar & Seth, 1998; Mayer & N ickerson, 2005; Salancik & Pfeffer 1978; Poppo & Zenger, 2002; Williamson, 1985; Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002). When two or more agencies come together to perform a common task the task is interdependently performed and shared decision making is required to manage the interdependence in the task (Gulati & Sytch, 2007; Krishnan, Martin & Noorderhaven 2006). Wh ile from the cooperation perspective, the incentive differences between exchange partners leads to a need for shared decision making from a coordination perspective shared decision making is required to manage the interdependence between exchan ge partners as managers are bounded ly rational In inter organizational relationships trust leads to performance as the exchange partners can carry out shared decision making (Uzzi, 1997; Zaheer, McEvily & Perrone, 1998, pg 155). Also, in the context of alliances, routines have been argued to lead to improved

PAGE 164

164 performance as they facilitate decision making in the alliance (Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002, pg 709). Information exchange between exchange partners is the other key aspect of work, which becomes important when work is done interdependently ( see Carson, Madhok, Varman, & John, 2003, Krishnan, Martin & Noorderhaven, 2006; Gulati & Sytch, 2007). The need for information exchange arises on account of the information asymmetry inherent in interfirm exc hanges (Zaheer, McEvily & Perrone, 1998, pg 144). Alliance studies have consistently recognized the importance of information exchange in interdependent work and while some have claimed i t to be an important mediator between trust and performance, other s a rgue d that it has a moderating e ffect on the performance of work when done interdependently (Carson, Madhok, Varman, & John, 2003; Gupta & Govindarajan, 1991; Palay, 1984; Poppo, Zhou & Zenger, 2008; Krishnan, Martin & Noorderhaven, 2006; Mohr & Spekman, 1 994; Uzzi, 1997; Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002). Furthermore, the knowledge based view of the firm sees it a s a bundle of information, and the knowledge perspective of alliances view s it as a conduit for the transfer and exchange of information making the e xchange of information a key aspect of work coordination. An important aspect of alliance management is conflict management (Parkhe, 1993; Madhok, 1995), as alliances require continuous interaction between partners in which disagreements inevitably occur (Schaan & Beamish, 1988). However, conflict management involves the use of different conflict resolution strategies like problem solving, compromising, forcing and legalistic strategy, and the choice of conflict resolution strategy in international joint v entures has performance implication s (Lin &

PAGE 165

165 Germain, 1998). In the coordination literature, arguments regarding how antecedents affect firm or alliance performance are often based on how conflict gets resolved, making conflict resolution a key aspect of co ordination (Gulati & Nickerson, 2008; Krishnan, Martin & Noorderhaven, 2006; Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002; Mohr & Spekman, 1994; Zaheer, McEvily & Perrone, 1998). Relating mechanisms and aspects of coordination To develop a more comprehensive view of work coordination it is essential to consider b oth mechanisms of coordination and aspects of work coordination While the aspects of coordination identify where coordination is done and what is being coordinated, the mechanisms of coordination identify how coor dination is carried out. This makes the mechanisms of coordination, identified earlier as use of structuring, use of boundary objects, or use of common ground, to lie orthogonal to the aspects of work task s requiring coordination, such that each of the mec hanisms of coordination can bring out coordination in each of the aspects of coordination through different mechanisms or pathways. This conceptualization leads us to a 3 X 4 matrix, presented in Table 7 1. The table identifies the theoretical pathways th rough which mechanisms and aspect s of coordination are related These twelve distinct pathways which relat e the three mechanisms of coordination to the four aspects of coordination, are next elaborated. The structuring of work by the use of mechanisms like contracts, modularity, task specification, standardization and organizational design, bring about role allocations between the coordinating agencies to affect the different aspects of work requiring coo rdination At the same time, elements of structuring generate monitoring and control

PAGE 166

166 in relationships by bringing about accountability and specifying the incentives and punish ments for the agencies involved. They also enable decision making by choosing who will make decisions and if required forcing consensus Further, structuring enable s standards for formal information exchange in the relationship, and also reduce s conf lict by reducing the degree of ambiguity and increasing the clarity of roles and responsibilities. The use of boundary objects, such as schedules, plans, joint review, and joint statements, bring about sequencing and interfacing and hence a ffect the diffe rent aspects of work. Also, the use of boundary objects enables monitoring and control in relationships by generating predictability and agreement between the agencies (Okhuysen & Bechky, 20 09 ), and also specifying the targets to be achieved and the implic ations of failure. Further, boundary objects enable decision making by specifying when decisions need to be made by clearly defining and sequen cing the work phases They enabl e information exchange in relationships by specifying the frequency and content o f communication and the use of communication protocols, such that the cognitive challenges faced by managers in assessing, storing and sharing information at the firms interface get mitigated (Kellogg, Orlikowski, & Yates, 2006). Boundary objects also redu ce conflict in relationships by specifying the hand off stages and if conflicts do arise, they guide the choice of actions for conflict resolution. The use of common ground, such as common understanding, common knowledge, common culture, common identity, norms, and expectation s brings in shared understanding and flexibility between the coordinating partners, and this affects all of

PAGE 167

167 the different aspects of work. At the same time, common ground reduces the need for monitoring by bringing in a common purpos e and brings in control of the relationship through the social means like coercion and social pressure (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Common ground enables decision making by helping each party understand the o needs and motivating accommodat ion of the c oordination partner. Also, common ground enables and ease s exchange of information by building a common pool of information establishing a common language for exchange, and decreas ing t he chances of conflicts in relationships by bringing familiarity If c onflicts do arise common ground enables their resolution by making the coordinating agencies accommodate one another. While suggesting the association of aspects and mechanisms of coordination, it is recognized that the existing literature through provid ing guiding arguments often emerge s as an impediment, as it does not explicitly distinguish between the different aspects of work. For instance, while examining the link between a performance and emphasizing the importance of different kinds of routines Zollo, Reuer, & Singh (2002, pg 709) state : alliance by facilitating the information gathering, communication, decision making conflict resolution, and the overall governance of the collaborative process Hence, these authors fail to distinguish between the different aspects of work. Furthermore, the existing literature also argues for cross linkages between the different aspects and mechanism s of coordinat ion as is evident from the remark by Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone (1998, pg 154 155) while examining the nature of trust

PAGE 168

168 reduced conflict resulting from interorganization al trust may in fact be an enabling conditions allowing exchange partners to pursue a variety of bilateral governance mechanisms such as exchange of personnel and shared decision making that lead to The PPP C ontext In Chapter 3, the distinctive aspects of PPP working were attributed to the presence of the government as an alliance partner and the delivery of public infrastructure. The presence of the government as an alliance partner in PPPs affects PPP working as the government has d ifferent objective function s has a different source of sustenance, possesses asymmetric authority, and has greater credibility and legitimacy, besides the government managers hold ing a different risk aptitude. At the same time, the delivery of public infr astructure molds PPP working as PPPs involve l umpy, indivisible, and long term investments possess toll good and monopolistic characteristics and possess positive and negative externalities PPP working accordingly gets structured in ways different from B2B alliances (Rufin & Rivera Santos, 2010) and also possesses distinctive emergent aspects. For structuring, PPPs use a common objective, an SPV, and an IC, all of which guide how work gets coordinated. From an emergent perspective, PPP working is molde d by the dominant line of business experience possessed by the private firm managing the concession agreement, and the experience of the managers that the private firm deploys to the project. While Chapter 3 elaborated on how the distinctive structuring of a PPP takes place, the empirical study focuses on the emergent ways of coordination in PPPs. The distinctive aspects of PPP structuring and the empirical findings are next discussed in the context of PPP working.

PAGE 169

169 S tructuring and W orking of PPPs In the Ind ian highway sector in particular, and contractual concessions in general (Marques & Berg, 2010), a common objective, an I ndependent C onsultant (IC) and a special purpose vehicles (SPV) a re identified as the distinctive structuring mechanisms used, in addition to the use of contracts and structuring of work. The common objective provides both a unifying concept to guide work and a common platform for work to be carried out ( Mahoney, McGahan, and Pitelis 2009) The IC, on the other hand, monitors the wo rk on behalf of the public in general and the government in particular, and while bringing in flexibility in how work gets coordinated, provides the first stage for conflict resolution. Distinctive to the PPP context, and different from B2B alliances, the IC plays an active role as a project intermediary between the two primary coordinating agencies (government and private firm) That is, it is not there to manage exceptions when they arise, but rather actively participates in the project, such that the IC has an important set of roles and responsibilities to fulfill even in a project functioning normally. The SPV localizes and contains the coordination of work in PPPs and also provides a communicative framework (Koschmann, Kuhn, & Pfarrer, f orthcoming), wh ich can deliver value in the distinctive context of PPPs It carries out coordination by bringing proximity between the coordinating agencies and reducing elements of work ambiguity (Okhuysen & Bechky, 2009) The two distinctive aspects of PPP working whic h are, i) the presence of the government as an alliance partner and ii) the delivery of public infrastructure, get addressed both by the presence of the SPV and its working. It is the separate legal entity of the SPV and its serving as a hub to the interf aces between the different stakeholders of the project (i.e., government, consultants, parent firm, end users, financing agencies, and the construction contractors, R ef Figure 3 1)

PAGE 170

170 that enables the SPV to address the distinctive aspects of a PPP while con structing a public infrastructure. The empirical study finds that while the SPV serves to localize and contain coordination, it also introduces a distance between the parent firm and the work in the project. This distance significantly a ffects how work is carried out, as it makes the managers with high firm tenure reduce the use of common ground for coordination. R ole of F irm F ocus In PPPs, the private firm assumes a large bundle of project risks and makes large and lumpy front end investments in the project. For this the firm has to possess some unique capabilities, like availability of significant amounts of cash, proven worth in efficiently managing cash flows in a construction project, and a long term focus, all of which enable the firm to not onl y seek additional debt and equity finances from the market, but also to manage the project over the long concession period to achieve the desired rate of returns. At the same time, the private firm also needs to coordinate work with the government, which i s philosophically a different identify, along with a large number of project stake holders. F irms differ in the extent to which they possess these capabilities, and Chapter 4 identifies these capabilities to lie in the experience focus of the firm ( i.e., h ighway or PPP focus ) The highway focus of a firm reflects the degree to which the firm possesses a developed set of highway specific boundary objects (HSBOs) and understands the distinctiveness of working with out sourced government contracts. On the othe r hand, the PPP focus of a firm makes the firm recognize the distinctive aspects of PPP working, which lie in the need for long term focus and the need for transparency in working. The empirical study has investigated how these foci mold the firm s use of coordination mechanism s in the project. While no significant

PAGE 171

171 e ffects of a the highway focus of the firm was found to be positively associated with the emphasis placed on the use of boundary objects for coordination. These findi ngs can also be interpreted in the broader context of PPPs. The government chooses private sector partners in PPPs based on the expertise in construction that they possess. A ccordingly it expects the private construction firm to make significant technical contributions to the project. While i n the conventional buying of construction services the private construction agencies only shoulder construction risks in PPPs the y are also required to take on the design risks. To be able to assume this bundle of both construction and design risks, the need for the private firm to demonstrate its t echnical capability in the focal sector gets emphasized. The focus of the firm on the highway business refle cts th e technical capability that the firm possesses in designing, constructing, and operating highway projects, in an unambiguous and it build up its own unique way s of working in the sector, some of which involve creating firm specific scheduling and planning practices, adopting sector specific practices across the firm, and recognizing the idiosyncrasies of the sector and giving them their due. The empirical result s support these contentions, and we find a to be a significant predictor of the use of boundary objects in projects. Interpreting the findings in the context of the Indian highway sector, we find that while a large variation exists in the focus of the firms participating in the PPP highway projects in India, firms with a dominant highway business line add distinctiveness to how the project is worked. Highway sector being a growth sector for the Indian economy,

PAGE 172

172 firms look upon the sector as an opportunity to grow with the economy, hence besides the incumbents in the industry there are also a large number of new entrants (Bandyopadhyay, Swaminathan, & Rohatgi, 2008) These new entrants play an important role in the sector by sustaining the high growth rate of the sector and the Indian economy (P ress Information Bureau of India 2011), these new entrants play an important role in the sector. More broadly, t his study finds that the incumbents and new entrants work the highway projects in diff erent ways, and the se differences require attention from the other agencies coordinating in the project Role of E xperience While the organizational literature has long recognized the need to view the manager as being bounded ly rational (Simon, 1945), such a need has also been felt in public policy literature, and more so when new forms of public organizations are being studied (Ostrom, 2009). PPPs are one such new form of public organization, wherein the activities traditionally performed by th e government are now being increasingly carried out at the private public interface. Hence, this study contributes to the public policy literature, both as it studies the working at the government s interface, and also as it studies how a bounded ly rationa l manager a ffects this working. More specifically, the empirical study finds that different kinds of managerial experience have different e ffects. While this is well recognized in managerial practice, this study operationalizes the arguments in practice an d with the growing use of PPPs as an organizational from, identifies PPP experience of a manager as a different and distinctive experience set That is, empirically we find that while h ighway experience and PPP experience possess differences. They are similar in that both him/her to

PAGE 173

173 coordinate with government managers, who are risk averse, but who possess significantly higher levels of authority, credibility, and legitimacy. Howev er, PPP experience is distinct from highway experience as it also involves the recognition of the distinctive ways of PPP working, where transparency in working and the need to use procedures that leave a trail are very important. The study also identifies the mechanism by which manager ial experience molds the work as the differential emphasis that they place on the use of different coordination mechanisms. The other kind of manager ial experience examined in this study is the length of a ith the firm. As PPPs involve a major departure from arms length contracts, and require firms to take on significant risks, make long term investments, and also expose the firm to significant externalities, the extent to which the manager identifies with t he firm a ffects the actions taken by the manager to protect and watch over the firm s long term interest. We do find support for these arguments when we find To interpret the fi ndings in the context of the Indian highway sector, it need s to be recognized that the sector is not only witnessing a changing profile of the firms participating in the sector but also in the locally available pool of managers with relevant domain experi ence. The supplementary and complementary e ffects of manager ial experience. Interpreting the above findings in light of the null findings of moderation of the e

PAGE 174

174 firm and manager ial experience are very different in their e ffects. That is, the reciprocal e ffects of the : PPP experience supplements and complements the the e ffects.

PAGE 175

175 T able 7 1. M echanisms and a spects of c oordination M echanisms of c oordination Aspects of coordination --Coordination in doing what (face of coordination) Monitoring & Control Decision m aking Information p rocessing Conflict r esolution Structure Standardizing and structuring of work and organizations. Like, h ierarchy, d epartmentalization, contract, r oles and r esponsibilities (HOW) Accountability ; i ncentive/ p unishments (HOW) Authority (who will make decisions) ; f orcing consensus (HOW) Visibility ; f ormal i nformation e xchange (HOW) Reduce ambiguity; b ring c larity of rules and regulations ; a rbitration m echanisms. C ommon e lements : Specification of r oles and r esponsibilities ( r ole a llocation) Elements of structuring bring about monitoring and control in relationships by bringing in accountability and incentives and punishments for the agencies involved in the relationship. Elements of structuring enable decision making in relationships by deciding who will make decisions and at t imes forcing a decision making by consensus. Elements of structuring enable information processing in relationships by bridging in visibility on who has to do what and further defines standards for formal information exchange in the relationship Elements of structuring reduce opportunities for conflict resolution by reducing scope for ambiguity and bringing in clarity of roles and responsibilities. Further, if conflicts do arise then the elements of structuring define and clarify the arbitration m echanism to be adopted for resolving the disputes. Plan P rogramming and p lanning (HOW) Predictability ; a greement ; t arget specification ; i ncentives (HOW) When decisions need to be made ; g uide o ptions (HOW) Specification of frequency ; c ontent of communication ; u niformity of understanding between parties ; u niformizaton of communication. (HOW) Provide c hoices C ommon e lements : Sequencing, f eedback, i nterfaces Elements of planning bring in control in relationships by bringing in predictability and agreement, while it specifies the targets to be achieved and specifies the implications for failing. Elements of planning enable decision making in relationships by deciding when decisions required to made, by clearly defining and sequencing the planning and working phases. Elements of planning enable information processing in relationships by uniformizing communication by specification of frequency and content of communication. Elements of planning reduce conflict in relationships by firstly guiding choices that the agenci es in relationships need to make and secondly by deciding handing off stages restrict conflict to specific places. Sharedeness S hared c haracteristics f lexibility c ommon c ulture/ n orms/ i dentity / e xpectation (HOW) Common p urpose ; s ocial pressure ; c oercion (HOW) Understanding others needs (creating empathy) (HOW) Common l anguage ; e ase of c ommunication (HOW) Accommodation ; f amiliarity C ommon e lements : Shared u nderstanding, f lexibility Elements of s haredeness reduce need for monitoring by bringing in a common purpose and further control the relationship through the social means like coercion and social pressure. Elements of sharedeness help decision making by bringing about an understanding of others needs and by making parties flexible t o each others needs. Elements of s haredeness enable information processing by building a common pool of information and establishing a common language for exchange. E ase communication Elements of s haredeness decrease the chances of conflict in relationships by bringing familiarity. When conflicts do arise they see to resolve them by making agencies accommodati ve to the others needs.

PAGE 176

176 CHAPTER 8 CONCLUSIONS Summary of F indings This study finds that the coordination of work at a boundaries can line of business ( ) and the managers that it deploys to manage this work, mold the emphasis placed on the use of these mechanisms. While working for a firm with a greater highway focus, managers with a greater experience in the emerging forms of work ( i.e., PPP experience ) tend to amplify the use of the purposive boundary objects, and these same managers also amplify the use of common ground for carrying out the work, albeit for different reasons. A manager with greater PPP experience emphasizes the use of highway specific practices, which are made available by the highway focused firm, recognizing that they increase transparency and leave a trail behind; the same manager emphasizes the use of common ground, as he /she compensates for the highway standing of PPP working, recognizing that it is important to address its d istinctive characteristics. of working ( i.e., PPP working ) the managers who possess a longer tenure with the firm tend to deemphasize the use of common ground. Managers are likely to behave in this way because they increasingly realize that the firm now has a long term focus on the work and recognize that a distance exists between the firm and project l evel work; the distance increases when work is located and contained in the distinct entity of SPV. This necessitates that the manager no longer emphasize short term and spontaneous

PAGE 177

177 mechanisms of coordination, which lack transparency, leave no trail, and t he use of which may in the long Limitations and F uture D irections The small sample size of the empirical analysis is a key limitation of this study, and to address this limitation, another round of survey is proposed. Considering that we have achieved a respectable coverage of 25% (45 of the 176 PPP highway projects in the country have been covered), a second survey in the same sample domain is unlikely to significantly increase the sample size Fortunately with the growing use of the PPP model to execute highway projects in India, the number of projects that round of survey after a significant time gap is likely to increase the number of projects that can be included in our sampling frame. At the same time, a few other options for expanding the sampling frame also exist. First, while this study has been conducted in the context of PPP highway projects in the construction pha se, we can also possibly include PPP highway projects in the operations phase. Secondly, we may include PPP projects in other infrastructure domains such as airports, seaports, water supply, sewage, etc., taking care to only include PPP projects that have been modeled in ways similar to th ose in the highway sector such as contractual PPPs involving long term concessions (Marques & Berg, 2010). When work is performed jointly, as in our context, the task characteristics mold the use of coordination mechanism s (Thompson, 1967). Here, while studying the other antecedents to the use of coordination mechanisms, we control for some task characteristics ( i.e., the quality of the DPR ) the extent of land acquisition at the beginning of the project, and the amount of coordination existing in the project. Existing

PAGE 178

178 studies of alliance working, like Carson, Madhok, Varman & John (2003), White & Lui (200 5 ), and Robson, Katsikeas, & Bello (2008), have found the project value, a proxy measure of project complexity, to be a s ignificant antecedent of how coordination is carried out. In the sample studied, firm value project cost, and project length are s ignificant ly correlated at 0.48. Hence, while we do not specifically control for project value, we indirectly control its eff ects by controlling for a The empirical analysis testing for the e ffects of the antecedents of the coordination mechanism s was run on a unique sample of PPP projects. Herein, if the government selects firms for undertaking PPP projects based on the coordination mechanisms that they use, it could potentially bias the results due to sample selection In the context of PPP firm selection it need s to be recognized that government procurement s of such kinds, are not a ffected by the shadow of the past or a shadow of the future (Henisz & Levitt, 2009) a nd further the selection of private firms for taking up a work of public importance is strictly guided by an elaborately laid out and quantitative financial and technical parameters (Wang & Bun n 2004). Thus, p re selection of the private firm based on the coordination practices that the firm uses is unlikely to be of concern in the sample. Also, aspects such as t he use of coordination me chanisms are more emergent and qualitative in nature and the government procurement evaluations are unlikely to consider them. Further, we have no evidence of any such sample selection. T here exists a large variance in the experience of the private firms in the sample (mean = 11.97, s.d. 15.77) indicating that our sample included firms that possessed very different characteristics. N evertheless, the analysis statistically controlled for the extent as a proxy of the eristics

PAGE 179

179 Another possible source of sampling bias could lie in the selection of managers by the firms. That is, firms may preselect managers who tend to use specific kinds of coordination mechanisms While we have no way for controlling for this bias in the study, it nevertheless contributes to the recruitment literature by finding evidence that manager ial experience one of the important parameters based on which managers get recruited, differently af fects the emphasis that managers place on the use of different c oordination mechanism s. While the above are some of the likely sources that could have biased our results, we feel that our findings lie on the conservative side T he highway PPP projects that we study are structured using very similar model concession agreements 1 These contracts not only structure the projects in a very similar fashion but they also guide the use of coordination mechanism s in the projects. For instance, in the context of hig hway PPP projects the model concession agreement not only specif ies the roles and responsibilities of the parties and the incentives and penalties for not fulfilling them, but it al so specifies that monthly progress reports need be prepared and the projec t must be weekly inspected by the IC (Chapter XIV, Model Concession agreement) Further, it states that written records of dispute s need to be kept and that disputes need be first resolved amicably by the a ffected parties ; only if resolution fails should the IC intervene or the case be taken up for arbitration (Chapter XXXIX, Model Concession agreement). T he se clauses in the contract reduce the options that agencies have in working in the project, and hence restr ain the choi ce of c oordination mechanism While we have no reason to believe that the se restrains would differently affect the use of different !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 The model concession agreement that guides all PPP highway construction projects in India can be downloaded from http://www.nhai.org.

PAGE 180

180 coordination mechanism s we do feel that they reduce the variance in the studied dependent variables making the results mor e conservative. To study how managers affect the project working, this study models the he/she possess es However, a experience is only one kind of functional competency, with others being e ducation, business knowledge, and line/staff skills (Spekman, Isabella, & MacAvoy, 2000). Besides functional aspects, the competencies of an alliance manager also lie in earned competencies, like credibility, respect, and interpersonal networks, as well as interpersonal competencies, like social skills, communication skills, and cross cultural mindedness, flexibility, self confidence, sensitivity, and drive to achieve, are also important (Child & Faulker, 1998). Hence, a need exists for future studies exploring the role of managers in carrying out coordination in order to study the e ffects of these characteristics, such as earned and interpersonal competencies, personality traits and psychological attributes. work, a potentially rich research ground exists wherein the effects of the diff erent characteristics of the firm, like extent of diversification, kind of organization (line/staff, matrix, project based, organic), nature of ownership, kind of leadership, etc., may be studied. Lastly, PPP are an emerging way of working, and not only ha ve many different practical manifestations of PPPs emerged (i.e., BOLT, BOT, DBOF, annuity, toll, negative or positive grant), but they have also take n different conceptual forms. For

PAGE 181

181 instance, Marques & Berg (2010) identify institutional and contractual P PPs as two different conceptual forms of PPPs, and study how risk is differently allocated in each. Similarly Kivleniece & QuŽlin ( f orthcoming) identify two ideal types of public private tie governance ( autonomous and integrative ) and argue that they differ in both the rationale for which partnerships are made and also in how they create value. At the same time, it has been recognized that t he conceptual difference s between the different forms of PPPs are not only limited to the allocation of partners between risks, but they also extend to how work is performed within them (Bult Spiering & Dewulf, 2006), and hence mold coordination of work To ensure empirical homogeneity in the sample, this study focused on PPPs that shared a structural form, hence the sample frame was defined as PPPs in the Indian highway sector. Future studies are required to examine the coordination of work in the many different forms that PPPs have taken. Implications for Managers There is a vast and growing body of literature stud ying PPPs 2 Found in economic, financial, and public policy domains, this literature seeks to understand the rationale, structuring, and benefits of PPPs. While this literature is very valuable for making policy decisions, it provides little guidance to ma nagers on how to manage PPPs once they have been created. The distinctive nature of PPPs makes the study of PPP management all the more important, as PPPs entail a new context in which public private interactions take place. Also, the evaluation of PPP per formance can be highly ambiguous as its performance implies different things to different stakeholders (Hodge & Greve, 2010). Accordingly, this research focuses on the process of PPP working, and !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 2 For instance, the I nternational Handbook of PPPs has been published in 2011 aggregating findings from different domains and contexts, and it is the first publication of its kind (Hodge, Greve, & Boardman, 2011)

PAGE 182

182 studies the antecedents of the intermediate aspects of work ( i.e., use of coordination mechanisms to carry out the work ) This study provides evidence that although the ex ante contract guides how work is performed, coordination mechanisms are used and emphasized differently, which has implications for managers. A lso, while the parent firm molds the work context, the important role in how coordination is carried out, and different kinds of experience can implying that a m ay experience in the technical domain. This is an important finding in the context of the Indian highway sector which is growing at a very fast pace and firms need time to gain experience in managing the distinctive wa y of PPP working. The deployment of managers with greater PPP experience can enable firms with l esser PPP experience, but high highway experience, to jump the experience curve and carry out coordination in ways similar to that carried out by firms possessi ng more PPP experience. Accordingly, the findings of this study can guide firms in hiring managers for working in this new and emerging sector. Further, this study identifies the distinctive aspects of PPP structuring as the use of common objective functio n s SPV, and IC, and finds SPVs to uniquely mold how work is carried out. It was found that SPVs, while locating and containing coordination, also create a distance between the firm and actual working of the project. This distance is

PAGE 183

183 not inconsequential, a nd affects how managers recognize that distance and adapt their working While protecting spontaneous coordination m echanisms, which may bring in adhocracy. This finding at first seems to be contradictory to managerial thought, as managers with experience and tenure are expected to use greater amount of trust to get work done. These unexpected findings can be explained by recognizing that trust comes from both a shadow of the past and a shadow of the future, and PPP working is unique in its requirements of transparency, use of SPV, as well as its need for trail leaving actions. It is pertinent to note that these findings were quite robust across all tested models. Hence, the study finds that managers recognize the distinctive nature of PPP working and adapt their work in PPPs accordingly. Locat ion in C urrent T hought and F inal W ords This dissertation contributes to existin g literature by deepening our understanding of how work is coordinated in an emerging context of public private interactions, while recognizing the existence of bounded ly rational managers (Simon, 1945). This is in contrast to the literature in both organi zational theory and public policy, which studies work cooperation while emphasizing the role of motivation. While contributing to these literatures, this study is also located in recent thought that has emerged in both of these domains. In the public polic y domain, while summarizing the current theoretical developments in the governance of complex economic systems, Nobel Laureate Elinor Ostrom remarks in her Nobel Prize winning lecture:

PAGE 184

184 As illustrated the updated theoretical assumptions of learning a nd norm adopting individuals can be used as the foundation for understanding how individuals may gain increased levels of trust in others, leading to more cooperation and higher benefits with feedback mechanisms that reinforce positive or negative learning (Elinor Ostrom, Prize lecture December 8, 2009, pg 432). This research can be seen as an instantiation of the above argument, where by departing from the rational choice assumptions about individuals, we study how coordination is achieved in complex econ omic systems like PPPs while accounting for There exists a need for developing a more comprehensive understanding of work coordination, as work is increasingly organized in new ways both within and between organizations (Barley & Kunda, 2001; McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003; Sinha & Van de Ven, 2005). At the same time, the study of value creation in PPPs is a current and emergent research theme for organizational theorists (Strategy Research Foundation, 2011). This study lies at t he intersection of these, addressing the needs of both Firstly, it attempts to develop a more comprehensive understanding of work coordination by recognizing the important role played by the individual in carrying out coordination, proposing a theory driv en categorization of coordination mechanism s and developing the coordination perspective by distinguishing mechanisms and aspects of coordination. Secondly, it studies the working of PPPs, of which we have little understanding, despite the large body of P PP literature. Hence, this study is located in current themes of research, while contribute to the existing literature.

PAGE 185

185 A PPENDIX S URVEY FORM Survey of the Modes of Coordination used in Large Construction Projects Dear Sir, I am an Indian Railways Mechanical Engineer on study leave, pursuing a Ph.D. in Management at the University of Florida, US. As part of my dissertation I propose to study how coordination is done in large organizations and projects. For this purpose I have prepared a sur vey form that I propose to use to survey the top managers who are involved with the highway construction projects in India. More specifically, the survey proposes to gather insights from the different agencies involved (who are coordinating the work) in su ch projects ( i.e. Project Director (NHAI), Project Manager (Concessionaire), Team Leader (Independent Consultant) and the Corporate Officer (Concessionaire Corporate Interface Unit) ). I have identified successfully running or completed projects from vario us sources, and your project is one such project. As you are heading your project and working in one of the roles above, I seek your help and request you to kindly spare 20 mins and complete the following survey for my study. The survey seeks to measure yo ur perceptions about your and your colleagues work, and IS NOT about performance of the project or about any disputes or issues. Further, only the researchers involved in the study will have access to your responses. Your responses will not be shared with the other participants in the study or your colleagues in the industry. As an industry professional and colleague, I seek your cooperation and help in completing this academic research project. Thanks, Swapnil Garg You can also take this survey onlin e at : http://edu.surveygizmo.com/s3/406546/Coordination Survey A Project Name : Name: Designation : Contact Phone : Email Id:

PAGE 186

186 Part A: Project Level Working Kindly name the different agencies involved in the project: Client: PIU Name: Concessionaire (Bidder): Consultant: Using the legend as below, kindly tick your response Not at all Low Moderate High Very High To what extent do the agencies (Client, Concessionaire & Consultant) coordinate in 1. 2. and integration of the work of different agencies) 3. circumstances? The first set of questions(4 18) refers to the role that the contract plays. To what extent does the CONTRACT 4. (Client, Concessionaire and Consultant) ? 5. 6. 7. (e.g., L 1 Schedules, budget )? 8. (e.g. time and cost) to agencies for not meeting contractual commitments? 9 (e.g. time and cost) to agencies for fulfilling contractual commitments? 10 ( e.g., decisions about scope changes ) 11 decisions? 12 (Client, Concessionaire and Consultant)? 13 14 (e.g., monthly reports, progress reports) 15 whom? 16 clear & unambiguous? 17 responsibilities of agencies clear & unambiguous? 18

PAGE 187

187 Not at all Low Moderate High Very High The second set of questions (19 35) refers to the role that the planning plays in the relationship To what extent has the SCHEDULING/PLANNING 19. (Client, Concessionaire and Consultant) 20. been agreed upon by the different agencies? (e.g., agreeing on detailed method of construction) 21. ( e.g., activities on critical path which are to be monitored, and day to day work schedules ) 22. ( e.g., procedure for tests, inspection, approvals) 23. ( e.g., identify the human resources, material, and equipment to be provided by each agency) 24. be done by different agencies in the project? ( e.g., preparation of Level 2 and Level 3 plans) 25. monitoring of work? (e.g., clear delegation of work and regular follow up of the work delegated to other agencies) 26. sch edule? (e.g., specifying which activities to monitor on the critical path, and how this monitoring is to be done) 27. among the agencies? 28. making? ( e.g., does planning help improve, alter or eliminate activities and allow for considering different more effective alternatives) 29. ? (e.g., handover of land for construction to start or handover of finished work) 30. site reports or site visits? 31. adoption of a procedure database & common information system ? (i.e., an organized means to communicate project information among the agencies) 32. changes? (e.g., communicating plan and schedule changes to all agencies) 33. remedial work methods and programs for defect rectification) 34. 35.

PAGE 188

188 Not at all Low Moderate High Very High The third set of questions (36 54) refers to the role that the SOCIAL relationships play To what extent do agencies (Client, Concessionaire & Consultant) 36. (Client, Concessionaire & Consultant) ? 37. cultural similarities ? 38. ? 39. ? 40. 41. reduce need for monitoring? ( e.g., common views of the agencies on time, cost, quality, and safety of the project, reduces the need for agencies to monitor one another.) 42. (Client, Concessionaire and Cons ultant) ? 43. team spirit) lead to smooth working? 44. ? ( e.g., if norms are not followed then others agencies try to discipline and ensure that the norms are followed) 45. decisions? (e.g., facilitating timely payments to sub contractors and employees) 46. 47. phone? 48. 49. 50. project information? 51. agencies comfortable in explaining and supporting the work of specialized suppliers) 52. their working procedures to help others work better) 53. 54. Part B Project Information DIRECTIONS : Kindly provide the following information about the project Not at all Low Moderate High Very High 1. This project has had SERIOUS problems, i.e., law and order or labor. 2. This project has had SERIOUS problems with the environmental agencies

PAGE 189

189 3. The quality of the DPR for this project was (1 is Bad, 5 Excellent) 4. The scope of the project has increased by _________ % since start 5. The land acquisition at the start of the Project was _________ % Complete 6. At this stage the progress of this project (a) _________ % Financially Complete (b) _________ % Physically Complete 7. The project by this time SHOULD have been (As per original plan) (a) _________ % Financially Complete ( b) _________ % Physically Complete 8. The procurement of material for this project is Centralized with Concessionaire Centralized at Project Locally procured as required 9. The Machinery & Plant of the Project is Centralized with Concessionaire Centralized at Project Hired Locally as required Strongly Disagree Disagree Neutral Agree Strongly Agree 1. The project is on the way to achieve its set goals 2. The time & effort spent by the agencies in developing the project has been worthwhile 3. This project has not been progressing as we would have liked it to be 4. The project is characterized by a strong and harmonious relationship between the agencies 5. In this project, resources are deployed efficiently 6. Procedures and mechanisms used for project resource utilization are cost effective 7. The project is not effective in converting resource inputs into project outputs 8. The project can adapt quickly to environmental changes 9. The project agencies are able to make adjustments to project to cope with changing circumstances 10 Whenever some unexpected situation arises, the project management is capable of modifying the existing structure and strategies of the project 11 In the face of problems or special circumstances, managers cannot adjust the project as required. Part C: Individual DIRECTIONS: In this section please tell us something about yourself 1. Your Age _________ years 2. Highest Educational Qualification (Tick as Applicable) Diploma Engineering Post Graduate Degree (Technology ) Post Gradate Degree (Management )

PAGE 190

190 3. Your Professional Qualifications (Tick as Applicable) Project Management professional (PMP) ISO Auditor / Quality Professional Other Technical Qualification 4. How many professional development courses (Technical) have you attended in the last 5 years? (e.g., Highway Construction, Highway Design) ____________ No of Courses 5. How many professional development courses (Management) have you attended in the last 5 years? (e.g., Construction Management, Leadership ) ____________ No of Courses 6. Your Total Highway Construction Experience _________ No of Projects, ______ No of Years, 7. Your Total International Experience _______ No of Projects, _________ No of Years 8. Have you been in this role since the beginning of this project? YES, since when_________ NO 9. When did you join your parent firm (most recently)? _________ Year 10. How long have you worked in the corporate office of your parent firm? ____________ No of Years 11. Were you involved with the initial project structuring (Making of packages of work)? YES NO Part D: Other Other Issues that you faced during the implementation of this project Issues Importance ( 1 a little, 5 Very Serious) 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Thanks a lot for sparing your valuable time to take this survey.

PAGE 191

191 LIST OF REFERENCES Aiken, M., & Hage, J. 1968. Organizational interdependence and intra organizational structure. American Sociological Review 33(6): 912 930. Anand, B. N., & Khanna, T. 2000. The structure of licensing contracts. The Journal of Industrial Economics 48(1): 103 135. Argote, L. 1982. Input uncertainty and organizational coordination in hospital emergency units. Administrative Science Quarterly 27(3): 420 434. Argote, L. 1996. Organizational learning curves: Persistence, transfer and turnover. Inter national Journal of Technology Management 11(7): 759. Argyres, N., & Mayer, K. J. 2007. Contract design as a firm capability: An integration of learning and transaction cost perspectives. The Academy of Management Review ARCHIVE 32(4): 1060 1077. Ashfor th, B. E., & Fried, Y. 1988. The mindlessness of organizational behaviors. Human Relations 41(4): 305 329. Axlerod, R. 1981. The evolution of cooperation. Science 211: 1390 1396. Baldwin, C. Y., & Clark, K. B. 2000. Design rules: The power of modularit y. The MIT Press. Bandyopadhyay, A., Swaminathan, A.K. & Rohatgi, R 2008, Indian road construction industry: Capacity issues, constraints & recommendations. Policy Note The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development The World Bank Barki, H., & Pinsonneault, A. 2005. A model of organizational integration, implementation effort, and performance. Organization Science 16(2): 165. Barley, S. R., & Kunda, G. 2001. Bringing work back in. Organization Science 12(1): 76 95. Barnard, C., I. 1938. The functions of the executive Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. 1986. The moderator mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of per sonality and social psychology 51(6): 1173 Baum, J. A. C., & Ingram, P. 1998. Survival enhancing learning in the Manhattan hotel industry, 1898 1980. Management Science 44(7): 996 1016.

PAGE 192

192 Becker, M. C. 2004. Organizational routines: A review of the literature. Industrial and Corporate Change 13(4): 643. Bensaou, M., & Venkatraman, N. 1995. Configurations of interorganizational relationships: A comparison between US and Japanese automakers Management Science : 1471 1492. Blau, P. M. 1964. Exchange and power in social life. Transaction Publishers Boeing Singh, L., & Kalidindi, S. N. 2006. Traffic revenue risk management through annuity model of PPP road projects in India International Jou rnal of Project Management 24(7): 605 613. Bridoux, F., Coeurderoy, R., & Durand, R. 2011. Heterogeneous motives and the collective creation of value. Academy of Management Review 36(4): 711 730. Bult Spiering, M., & Dewulf, G. 2006. Strategic issues i n public private partnerships : An international perspective Oxford, UK ; Malden, MA: Blackwell Pub. Burrell, G., Morgan, G., & Morgan, G. 1979. Sociological paradigms and organizational analysis : Elements of the sociology of corporate life London: Heinemann. Campbell, J. L. 2004. Institutional change and globalization. Princeton University Press. Carson, S. J., Madhok, A., Varman, R., & John, G. 2003. Information processing moderators of the effectiveness of trust based governance in int erfirm R&D collaboration. Organization Science 14(1): 45 56. Chandler, A. D. 1962. Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of American enterprise Checherita, C., & Gifford, J. 2008. Risk sharing in public private partnerships; general considera tions and an evaluation of the US practice in road transportation Paper presented at Transportation Research Board Conference. Washington, DC. Chen, B. R., & Chiu, Y. S. 2010. Public private partnerships: Task interdependence and contractibility. Interna tional Journal of Industrial Organization Chen, M., & Stucker, K. 1997. Multinational management and multimarket rivalry: Toward a theoretical development of global competition Academy of Management.

PAGE 193

193 Child, J., & Faulkner, D. 1998. Strategies of cooper ation: Managing alliances, networks, and joint ventures Oxford University Press. Choi, J., Chung, J., & Lee, D. J. 2010. Risk perception analysis: Participation in china's water PPP market. International Journal of Project Management 28(6): 580 592. Clark, H. 1996. Using language Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Coase, R. H. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16): 386 405. Daft, R. L., & Lengel, R. H. 1986. Organizational information requirements, media richness and structural desi gn. Management science : 554 571. Das, T. K., & Teng, B. S. 2000. Instabilities of strategic alliances: An internal tensions perspective. Organization Science : 77 101. Dash, D.K., 201 0 October 10 Nath warns NHAI over tardy highway construction Times of India http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/india/Nath warns NHAI over ta rdy highway construction/articleshow/6721791.cms Dash, D.K., 2011 October 17 Highways back on track, 11km added per day Times of I ndia http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/india/Highways back on track 11km added per day/articleshow/10382170.cms Davids s on, J. S. 2010. Driving growth: Regulatory reform and expressways in Indonesia Regulation and Governance 4(4): 465 484. d e Rond, M., & Bouchikhi, H. 2004. On the dialectics of strategic alliances. Organization Science : 56 69. Delmon, J. 2010. Understanding options for public private partnerships in infrastructure: Sorting out the forest from the trees: BOT, DBFO, DCMF, concession, lease. The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series: 5173. Deshpande, R., & Zaltman, G. 1982. Factors affe cting the use of market research information: A path analysis. Journal of Marketing Research 19(1): 14 31. DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. Amer ican Sociological Review : 147 160. Dixit, A. K., Pindyck, R. S., & Davis, G. A. 1994. Investment under uncertainty Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

PAGE 194

194 Donaldson, L. 2001. The contingency theory of organizations Sage Publications, Inc Duncan, W. R. 2003. Guide to the project management body of knowledge PMBOK guide 2003 edition Pennsylvania: Project Management Institute. Dyer, J. H., Kale, P., & Singh, H. 2001. How to make strategic alliances work. MIT Sloan Management Review 42(4): 37 43. Edwards, J. R., & Lambert, L. S. 2007. Methods for integrating moderation and mediation: A general analytical framework using moderated path analysis. Psychological methods 12(1): 1. Edmondson, A. C., Bohmer, R. M., & Pisano, G. P. 2001. Disrupt ed routines: Team learning and new technology implementation in hospitals. Administrative Science Quarterly 46(4): 685 716. Estache, A., & Fay, M. 2007. Alternatives to infrastructure privatization revisited: Public enterprise reform from the 1960s to th e 1980s. World Faems, D., Janssens, M., Madhok, A., & Van Looy, B. 2008. Toward an integrative perspective on alliance governance: Connecting contract design, trust dynamics, and contract application. The Academy of Management Journal 51(6): 1053 1078. Fang, E., & Zou, S. 2010. The effects of absorptive and joint learning on the instability of international joint ventures in emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies 41(5): 906 924. Fang, E. E., & Zou, S. 2009. Antecedents and conse quences of marketing dynamic capabilities in international joint ventures. Journal of International Business Studies 40(5): 742 761. Feldman, M. S., & Pentland, B. T. 2003. Re conceptualizing organizational routines as a source of flexibility and change. Administrative Science Quarterly 48(1): 94 121. Finkelstein, S., Hambrick, D. C., & Cannella, A. A. 2008. Strategic leadership: Theory and research on executives, top manageme nt teams, and boards Oxford University Press, USA. Frederic, B. B., Goldsmith, H., & Valila, T. 2007. P ublic private Partnerships in Europe: An Update Economic and Financial Reports Fulghieri, P., & Sevilir, M. 2009. Size and focus of a venture capita list's portfolio. Review of Financial Studies 22(11): 4643.

PAGE 195

195 Galbraith, J. 1973. Designing complex organizations Addison Wesley Longman Publishing Co., Inc. Boston, MA, US Gerwin, D. 2004. Coordinating new product development in strategic alliances. The Academy of Management Review 29(2): 241 257. Gittell, J. H. 2002. Coordinating mechanisms in care provider groups: Relational coordination as a mediator and input uncertainty as a moderator of performance effects. Management Science 48(11): 1408 1426. Glouberman, S., & Mintzberg, H. 2001. Managing the care of health and the cure of disease part II: Integration. Health care management review 26(1): 70. Gomes Casseres, B. 1996. The alliance revolution: The new shape of business rivalry. Harvard Univ ersi ty Press. Grandori, A. 1997 a Governance structures, coordination mechanisms and cognitive models. Journal of Management and Governance 1(1): 29 47. Grandori, A. 1997 b An organizational assessment of interfirm coordination modes. Organization Studies 18(6): 897. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. Readings in economic sociology : 63 68. Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J. J., & Straub, S. 2007. Concessions of infrastructure in Latin America : Government l ed renegotiation. Journal of Applied Econometrics 22(7): 1267 1294. Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J. J., & Straub, S. 2008. Renegotiation of concession contracts in Latin America : Evidence from the water and transport sectors. International Journal of Industri al Organization 26(2): 421 442. Gulati, R. 1995. Social structure and alliance formation patterns: A longitudinal analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly 40(4). Gulati, R., Lawrence, P. R., & Puranam, P. 2005. Adaptation in vertical relationships: B eyond incentive conflict. Strategic Management Journal 26(5): 415 440. Gulati, R., & Nickerson, J. A. 2008. Interorganizational trust, governance choice, and exchange performance. Organization Science 19(5): 688 708. Gulati, R., & Sytch, M. 2007. Depen dence asymmetry and joint dependence in interorganizational relationships: Effects of embeddedness on a manufacturer's performance in procurement relationships. Administrative Science Quarterly 52(1): 32 69.

PAGE 196

196 Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V. 1991. Knowled ge flows and the structure of control within multinational corporations. Academy of management review : 768 792. Hair, J. F., Black, W. C., Babin, B. J., Anderson, R. E., & Tatham, R. L. 2006. Multivariate data analysis (Sixth ed.). New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. Hambrick, D. C., Geletkanycz, M. A., & Fredrickson, J. W. 1993. Top executive commitment to the status quo: Some tests of its determinants. Strategic Management Journal 14(6): 401 418. Hambrick, D. C., & Fukutomi, G. D. 1991. The seasons of a CEO's tenure. Academy of Management Review 16(4): 719 742. Harrigan, K. R. 1985. Strategies for joint ventures. Lexington books. Hart, O. 2003. Incomplete contracts and public ownership: Remarks, and an application to Public p rivate partnerships. The Economic Journal 113(486): C69 C76. Hayes, S. R., Pisano, G., Upton, D. M., & Wheelwright, S. 2005. Operations, strategy, and technology: Pursuing the competitive edge John Wiley & Sons. Heald, D., & Georgiou, G. 2011. 11 accounting for PPPs in a converging world. International Handbook on Public Private Partnerships : 237. Heath, C., & Staudenmayer, N. 2000. Coordination neglect: How lay theories of organizing complicate coordination in organizations Research in Organizational Behavior 22: 153 192. Heimeriks, K. H., & Duysters, G. 2007. Alliance capability as a mediator between experience and alliance performance: An empirical investigation into the alliance capability development process. Journal of Management Studies 44(1): 25 49. Henderson, A. D., Miller, D., & Hambrick, D. C. 2006. How quickly do CEOs become obsolete? industry dynamism, CEO tenure, and company performance. Strategic Management Journal 27(5): 447 460. Henisz, W. J., & Levitt, R. E. 2009. Normative and cognitive institutional supports for relational contracting in infrastructure projects. Unpublished manuscript The Wharton School. Hennart, J. F. 1988. A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 9(4): 361 374. Hinkin, T. R. 1998. A brief tutorial on the development of measures for use in survey questionnaires. Organizational Research Methods 1(1): 104.

PAGE 197

197 Hoang, H., & Rothaermel, F. T. 2010. Leveraging internal and external experience: Ex ploration, exploitation, and R&D project performance. Strategic Management Journal 31(7): 734 758. Hodge, G. A., & Greve, C. 2007. Public private partnerships: An international performance review. Public administration review 67(3): 545 558. Hodge, G., & Greve, C. 2010. Public p rivate partnerships: Governance scheme or language game? Australian Journal of Public Administration 69: S8 S22. Hodge, G. A., Greve, C., & Boardman, A. E. 2011. International handbook on public private partnerships Edward Elgar Publishing. Howard Grenville, J. 2005. The persistence of flexible organizational routines: The role of agency and organizational context. Organization Science 16(6): 618 636. Huckman, R. S., & Zinner, D. E. 2008. Does focus improve operati onal performance? lessons from the management of clinical trials. Strategic Management Journal 29(2): 173 193. Hughes, O. E., & ebrary, I. 2003. Public management and administration: An introduction Palgrave. IFSL Research. 2008. PPPs in the UK & PPP i n Europe London: International finance services. India Infrastructure Research. 2010. Road development of India V ol I & V ol II India Infrastructure publishing. Ito, J. K., & Peterson, R. B. 1986. Effects of task difficulty and inter unit interdependence on information processing systems. Academy of Management Journal 29(1): 139 149. Iyer, K. C., Chaphalkar, N. B., & Joshi, G. A. 2008. Understanding time delay disputes in co nstruction contracts. International Journal of Project Management 26(2): 174 184. Iyer, K. C., & Jha, K. N. 2005. Factors affecting cost performance: Evidence from Indian construction projects. International Journal of Project Management 23(4): 283 295. Iyer, K. C., & Jha, K. N. 2006. Critical factors affecting schedule performance: Evidence from Indian construction projects. Journal of Construction Engineering & Management 132(8): 871 881.

PAGE 198

198 Jansen, J. J. P., Tempelaar, M. P., Van den Bosch, F. A. J., & Volberda, H. W. 2009. Structural differentiation and ambidexterity: The mediating role of integration mechanisms. Organization Science 20(4): 797 811. Jha, K. N., & Iyer, K. C. 2006 a Critical determinants of project coordination. International Journal of Project Management 24(4): 314 322. Jha, K. N., & Iyer, K. C. 2006 b Critical factors affecting quality performance in construction projects. Total Quality Management & Business Excellence 17(9): 1155 1170. Jha, K. N., & Iyer, K. C. 2007. Commitment coordination, competence and the iron triangle. International Journal of Project Management 25(5): 527 540. Kale, P., Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. 2002. Alliance capability, stock market response, and long term alliance success: The role of the alliance fu nction. Strategic Management Journal 23(8): 747 767. Kale, P., & Singh, H. 2009. Managing strategic alliances: What do we know now, and where do we go from here? The Academy of Management Perspectives 23(3): 45 62. Katz, R. 1982. The effects of group longevity on project communication and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly 27(1): 81 104. Kanter, R. M. 1977. Men and women of the corporation. Basic Books (AZ). Kellogg, K. C., Orlikowski, W. J., & Yates, J. A. 2006. Life in the trading zone: Structuring coordination across boundaries in post bureaucratic organizations. Organization Science 17(1): 22. Ketokivi, M., & Jokinen, M. 2006. Strategy, uncertainty and the focused factory in international process ma nufacturing. Journal of Operations Management 24(3): 250 270. Kivleniece, I., & QuŽlin, B. Forthcoming. Creating and capturing value in public private ties: A private actor's perspective. Academy of Management Review Klepper, S. 2002. The capabilities of new firms and the evolution of the US automobile industry. Industrial & Corporate Change 11: 645 666. Koppenjan, J. F. M., & Enserink, B. 2009. Public Private partnerships in urban infrastructures: Reconciling privat e sector participation and sustainability. Public administration review 69(2): 284 296.

PAGE 199

199 Koschmann, M.A., Kuhn,T. R., & Pfarrer.M. D. Forthcoming. A communicative framework of value in cross sector partnerships. Academy of Management Review Krishnan, R., Martin, X., & Noorderhaven, N. G. 2006. When does trust matter to alliance performance? Academy of Management Journal 49(5): 894 917. Kumar, S., & Seth, A. 1998. The design of coordination and control mechanisms for managing joint venture parent relation ships. Strategic Management Journal 19(6): 579. Laffont, J. J., & Tirole, J. 1993. A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation The MIT Press. Lawrence, P. R., & Lorsch, J. W. 1967. Differentiation and integration in complex organizations. Admin istrative Science Quarterly 12(1): 1 47. Lichtenthaler, U., Ernst, H., & Hoegl, M. 2010. Not sold here: How attitudes influence external knowledge exploitation. Organization Science 21(5): 1054 1071. Lin, X., & Germain, R. 1998. Sustaining satisfactory joint venture relationships: The role of conflict resolution strategy. Journal of International Business Studies : 179 196. Litterer, J. A. 1965. Administrative decision making: A heuristic model. American Sociolo gical Review 30(4): 638 639. Lorenzoni, G., & Lipparini, A. 1999. The leveraging of interfirm relationships as a distinctive organizational capability: A longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal 20(4): 317 338. Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. 2001. The internationalization and performance of SMEs. Strategic Management Journal 22(6): 565. Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. 2004. International diversification and firm performance: The S curve hypothesis. Academy of Management Journal 47(4): 598 609. Luo, Y. 2008. Structuring interorganizational cooperation: The role of economic integration in strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal 29(6): 617 637. MacAvoy, S. F., Robert, E., Theodore, M., Lynn, A., & Thomas, C. 1998. Alliance management: A view from the past and a look to the future. Journal of Management Studies 35(6): 747 772.

PAGE 200

200 Madhok, A. 1995. Opportunism and trust in joint venture relationships: An exploratory study and a model. Scandinavian Jour nal of Management 11(1): 57 74. Mahalingam, A. 2005. Understanding and mitigating institutional costs on global projects (Doctoral Dissertation). Retrieved from dissertation and Theses database. (UMI No. 3197479) S tanford University, California. Mahalingam, A. 2010. PPP experiences in Indian cities: Barriers, enablers, and the way forward. Journal of Construction Engineering & Management 136(4): 419 429. Mahoney, J. T., McGahan, A. M., & Pitelis, C. N. 2009. Perspective --the interdependence of private and public interests. Organization Science 20(6): 1034 1052. Malhotra, D K & McLeod, R. W, 1997. An Empirical Analysis of Mutual Fund Expenses, Journal of Financial Research vol. 20(2), pages 175 90, Summer. Malone, T. W., & Crowston, K. 1994. The interdisciplinary study of coordination. ACM Computing Surveys (CSUR) 26(1): 87 119. March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. 1958. Organizations New York: John Wiley. Marques, R. C., & Berg, S. 2010. Revisiting the strengths and limitations of regulatory cont racts in infrastructure industries. Journal of Infrastructure Systems 16: 334. Marques, R. C., & Berg, S. V. forthcoming Public private partnership contracts: A tale of two cities with different contractual arrangements. Public Administration Marques, R., & Berg, S. 2011 Risks, contracts and private sector participation in infrastructure. Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 1(1): 243. Martimort, D., & Pouyet, J. 2008. To build or not to build: Normative and positive theories of public private partnerships. International Journal of Industrial Organization 26(2): 393 411. Martinez, J. I., & Jarillo, J. C. 1989. The evolution of research on coordination mechanisms in multinational corporations. Journal of International Business Studies : 489 514. Mayer, K. J., & Nickerson, J. A. 2005. Antecedents and performance implications of contracting for knowledge workers: Evidence from information technology servi ces. Organization Science : 225 242.

PAGE 201

201 McDermott, G. A., Corredoira, R. A., & Kruse, G. 2009. Public private institutions as catalysts of upgrading in emerging market societies. The Academy of Management Journal (AMJ) 52(6): 1270 1296. McEvily, B., Perrone V., & Zaheer, A. 2003. Trust as an organizing principle. Organization Science 14(1): 91 103. Mesquita, L. F., & Brush, T. H. 2008. Untangling safeguard and production coordination effects in long term buyer supplier relationships. The Academy of Manage ment Journal 51(4): 785 807. Miller, D. 1991. Stale in the saddle: CEO tenure and the match between organization and environment. Management Science 37(1): 34 52. Mintzberg, H. 1984. Power and organization life cycles. The Academy of Management Review 9(2): 207 224. Mohr, J., & Spekman, R. 1994. Characteristics of partnership success: Partnership attributes, communication behavior, and conflict resolution techniques. Strategic Management Journal 15(2): 135 152. Mom, T. J. M., Van Den Bosch, F. A. J., & Volberda, H. W. 2009. Understanding variation in managers' ambidexterity: Investigating direct and interaction effects of formal structural and personal coordination mechanisms. Organization Science 20(4): 812 828 Montgomery, C. A., & Wernerfelt, B. 1988. Diversification, R icardian rents, and T obin's q. The Rand journal of economics : 623 632. Nelson, R. R. 1994. The co evolution of technology, industrial structure, and supporting institutions. Industrial & Corporate Change 3(1): 47 63. Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap press Nickerson, J. A., & Zenger, T. R. 2004. A knowledge based theory of the firm: The problem solving perspective. Organization Scienc e : 617 632. Nunnally, J. C. 1978. Psychometric theory New York: McGraw Hill. Okhuysen, G. A., & Bechky, B. A. 2009. 10 coordination in organizations: An integrative perspective. The Academy of Management Annals 3(1): 463 502. Ostrom, E. 2005. Understa nding institutional diversity. Princeton University press.

PAGE 202

202 Ostrom, E. 2009. Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems Citeseer. Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. 1961. The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. The American Political Science Review 55(4): 831 842. Owen Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. 2004. Knowledge networks as channels and conduits: The effects of spillov ers in the Boston biotechnology community. Organization Science : 5 21. Oxley, J., & Wada, T. 2009. Alliance structure and the scope of knowledge transfer: Evidence from US japan agreements. Management Science 55(4): 635 649. Palay, T. M. 1984. Comparati ve institutional economics: The governance of rail freight contracting. The Journal of Legal Studies 13(2): 265 287. Palich, L. E., Cardinal, L. B., & Miller, C. C. 2000. The diversification performance linkage. Strategic Management Journal 21(2): 155 1 74. Parkhe, A. 1993. Strategic alliance structuring: A game theoretic and transaction cost examination of interfirm cooperation. Academy of management journal : 794 829. Pirson, M., & Malhotra, D. 2010. Foundations of organizational trust: What matters to different stakeholders? Organization Science : orsc. 1100.0581 v1. Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 2002. Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Management Journal 23(8): 707 725. Poppo, L., Zhou, K. Z., & Ryu, S. 2008. Alternative origins to interorganizational trust: An interdependence perspective on the shadow of the past and the shadow of the future. Organization Science 19(1): 39 55. Poppo, L., Zhou, K. Z., & Zenger, T. R. 2008. Examining the conditional limits of relational governance: Specialized assets, performance ambiguity, and long standing ties. Journal of Management Studies 45(7): 1195 1216. Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive advantage: Creating and sustaining competitive performance Fre e press. Porter, M. E., & Fuller, M. B. 1986. Coalitions and global strategy. Competition in global industries 1(10): 315 343.

PAGE 203

203 Powell W. W. 1990. Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization. Research in organizational behavior 12: 295 336. Press Information Bureau of India 2011, Prime Minister to Inaugurate Conference on Public Private Partnership in National Highways. Press release http://pib.nic.in Puranam, P., & Vanneste, B. S. 2009. Trust and governance: Untangling a tangled web. The Academy of Management Review 34(1): 11 31. Rangan, S., Samii, R., & Van Wassenhove, N. K. 2006. Constructive partnerships: When alliances between private firms and public actors c an enable creative strategies. The Academy of Management Review ARCHIVE 31(3): 738 751. Reuer, J. J., & Ari–o, A. 2007. Strategic alliance contracts: Dimensions and determinants of contractual complexity. Strategic Management Journal 28(3): 313 330. Re uer, J. J., Zollo, M., & Singh, H. 2002. Post f ormation dynamics in strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal 23(2): 135 151. Ring, P. S., & van de ven .D.D. 1992. Structuring cooperative relationships between organizations. Strategic Management Journal 13(7): 483 498. Ring, P. S., Bigley, G. A., D'Aunno, T., & Khanna, T. 2005. Introduction to special topic forum: Perspectives on how governments matter. The Academy of Management Review : 308 320. Rivera Santos, M., & Rufin, C. 2010. Global villa ge vs. small town: Understanding networks at the base of the pyramid. International Business Review 19(2): 126 139. Rivkin, J. W., & Siggelkow, N. 2003. Balancing search and stability: Interdependencies among elements organizational design. Management Sc ience : 290 311 Robson, M. J., Katsikeas, C. S., & Bello, D. C. 2008. Drivers and performance outcomes of trust in international strategic alliances: The role of organizational complexity. Organization Science 19(4): 647 665. Ruf’n, C., & Rivera Santos, M 2010. Between commonweal and competition: Understanding the governance of Public Private partnerships. Journal of Management Rui, M., De Jong, M., & Ten Heuvelhof, E. 2008 Public private partnerships for expressways in china: An agency theory approach Paper presented at Infrastructure Systems and Services: Building Networks for a Brighter Future (INFRA), First International Conference.

PAGE 204

204 Salancik, G. R., & Pfeffer, J. 1978. The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective. Harper and Row. Sampson, R. C. 2004. The cost of misaligned governance in R&D alliances. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 20(2): 484. Samuelson, P. A. 1954. The pure theory of public expenditure. The review of economics and statistics 36(4): 387 38 9. Sanchez, R., & Mahoney, J. T. 1994. The modularity principle in product and organizational design University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign: Office of Research. Savas, E. S. 2000. Privatization and public private partnerships New York: Chatham Hous e. Schaan, J. L., & Beamish, P. W. 1988. Joint venture managers in LDC's. Cooperative strategies in international business : 279 299. Schaeffer, P. V., & Loveridge, S. 2002. Toward an understanding of types of public private cooperation. Public Performanc e & Management Review 26(2): 169 189. Schilke, O., & Goerzen, A. 2010. Alliance management capability: An investigation of the construct and its measurement. Journal of Management 36(5): 1192. Scott, W. R. 1998. Organizations: Rational, natural, and open systems Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Scott, W. R., & Davis, G. F. 2007. Organizations and organizing: Rational, natural, and open systems perspectives Pearson College Div ision Schreiner, M., Kale, P., & Corsten, D. 2009. What really is al liance management capability and how does it impact alliance outcomes and success? Strategic Management Journal 30(13): 1395 1419. Sewell Jr, W. H. 1992. A theory of structure: Duality, agency, and transformation. American journal of sociology : 1 29. Sh erman, J. D., & Keller, R. T. 2010. Suboptimal assessment of inter unit task interdependence: Modes of integration and information processing for coordination performance. Organization Science Shleifer, A. 1998. State vs. private ownership. Journal of ec onomic perspectives 12(4): 133 150.

PAGE 205

205 Siggelkow, N., & Levinthal, D. A. 2003. Temporarily divide to conquer: Centralized, decentralized, and reintegrated organizational approaches to exploration and adaptation. Organization Science : 650 669. Simon, H. A. 1945. Administrative behavior The MacMillian Company, New York Sinha, K. K., & Van de Ven, A. H. 2005. Designing work within and between organizations. Organization Science 16(4): 389. Skinner, W. 1974. The focused factory. Harvard business review 52(3 ): 113 121. Smith, A. 1776. The wealth of nations books I III Sobrero, M., & Schrader, S. 1998. Structuring inter firm relationships: A meta analytic approach. Organization Studies 19(4): 585. Spekman, R. E., Isabella, L. A., & MacAvoy, T. C. 2000. Alliance competence: Maximizing the value of your partnerships Wiley. Spekman, R. E., Isabella, L. A., MacAvoy, T. C., & Forbes, T. 1996. Creating strategic alliances which endure. Long range planning 29(3): 346 357. Srikanth, K., & Puranam, P. 2010. I ntegrating distributed work: Comparing task design, communication, and tacit coordination mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal Strategic Management Society. 2011 Strategy research foundation: Current research themes theme 1 V alue creation through collaborative public private interactions. http://srf.strategicmanagement.net/current_research_themes.php November 03 2011. Stinchcombe, A. L. 1965. Organizations and social structure. Handbook of organizations : 142 193. Subramani, M. R., & Venkatraman, N. 2003. Safeguarding investments in asymmetric inter organizational relationships: Theory and evidence. Academy of Management Journal 46(1): 46 62. Szulanski, G. 1996. Exploring internal stickiness: Impediments to the transfer of best practice within the firm. Strategic Management Journal 17: 27 43. Taylor, F. W. 1911. Shop management Harper & Brothers. Thelen, K. A. 2004. How institutions evolve: The political economy of skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan Cambridge University Press.

PAGE 206

206 Thomas, A. V., Kalidindi, S. N., & Ananthanarayanan, K. 2003. Risk perception analysis of BOT road project participants in India Construction Management and Economics 21(4): 393 407. Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in action New York: McGraw Hill. Tsai, W. 2002. Social structure of "co opetition" within a multi unit organization: Coordination, competition, and intra organizational knowledge sharing. Organization science : 179 190. Tushman, M. L. 1979. Work characteristics and subunit communication structure: A contingency analysis. Admin istrative Science Quarterly : 82 98. Tushman, M. L., & Nadler, D. A. 1978. Information processing as an integrating concept in organizational design. The Academy of Management Review 3(3): 613 624. Uzzi, B. 1997. Social structure and competition in inter firm networks: The paradox of embeddedness. Administrative Science Quarterly : 35 67. Van de Ven, A. H., Delbecq, A. L., & Koenig Jr, R. 1976. Determinants of coordination modes within organizations. American Sociological Review 41(2): 322 338. Van de Ve n, A. H., & Walker, G. 1984. The dynamics of inter organizational coordination. Administrative Science Quarterly 29(4): 598 621. Vlaar, P. W. L., Van Den Bosch, F. A. J., & Volberda, H. W. 2007. Towards a dialectic perspective on formalization in inter o rganizational relationships: How alliance managers capitalize on the duality inherent in contracts, rules and procedures. Organization Studies 28(4): 437. Wang, S., & Bunn, M. D. 2004. Government business relationships: Insights into contract implementat ion. Journal of Public Procurement 4: 84 115. White, S., & Lui, S. 2005. Distinguishing costs of cooperation and control in alliances. Strategic Management Journal 26(10): 913 932. Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firm, markets, relational contracting New York: The Free Press. Wiseman, R. M. 2009. On the use and misuse of ratios in strategic management research. Wren, D. A. 1967. Interface and inter organizational coordination. The Academy of Management Journal 10(1): 69 81.

PAGE 207

207 Young Ybarra, C., & Wiersema, M. 1999. Strategic flexibility in information technology alliances: The influence of transaction cost economics and social exchange theory. Organization Science : 439 459. Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V 1998. Does trust matter? E xploring the effects of inter organizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization science : 141 159. Zaheer, A., & Venkatraman, N. 1995. Relational governance as an inter organizational strategy: An empirical tes t of the role of trust in economic exchange. Strategic Management Journal 16(5): 373 392. Zollo, M., Reuer, J. J., & Singh, H. 2002. Inter organizational routines and performance in strategic alliances. Organization Science : 701 713.

PAGE 208

208 BIOGRAPHI CAL SKETCH Swapn il Garg is a railway mechanical engineer who is comfortable working at the interface of academia and industry. At the early age of 18 he was selected by the Indian government t o be part of the Special Class Railway Apprentice undergraduate program which has an acceptance rate of less than 0.1%. H ere he was trained to be a mechanical engineer and groomed to be an officer gentleman at the prestigious Jamalpur Gymkhana and Indian Railways I nstitute of Mechanical and Electrical En gineers in Bihar, India. During this program Swapnil also earned credentials in mechanical, electrical, and electronics engineering from IMechE (UK) and the Institution of Engineers (India). Upon graduation, Swapnil served with the Northern Railway in a M echanical E ngineering role in four division s During this period he was head of various operational divisions and maintenance sheds and gained experience in a variety of roles. In the year 2000, Swapnil was selected for the Executive MBA program called N ational Management Program, at the Management Development Institute in Gurgaon, India. Herein, individuals from the public and private sector s join a residential program sponsored by the Indian government common program and interact with one another for a 15 month period to develop a deeper understanding of the how the two sectors work interdependently. Due to his specializ ation in I nformation S ystems M anagement in the MBA program, his interest shifted from engineering to management Swapnil spent two years at Diesel Locomotive Works in Varanasi, India piloting their nascent E nterprise Resource Planning project ; he later spent four years at IRCON International Limited, India managing their different IT initiat ives that were adopted during this period such

PAGE 209

209 as the implementation of Enterprise Resource Planning (SAP) and the P roject Management Information System s continued to evolve, and he found himself drawn to broader managerial practice and general management With almost 20 years of techno managerial experience in diverse industries ( i.e., railroad, construction, and information systems ) combined with his graduate level education, he became attracted to the academic underpinning s of managerial practices. S wapnil thereupon joined the Ph.D. M anagement program at the Warrington College of Business A dministration in August of 200 7 where he could conduct research in the area of management. His research interests have over time narrowed to strategic alliances, with a specific f ocus on partnerships at the public private interface and the process of entrepreneurship. Upon c ompletion of his Ph.D. from the University of Florida in 201 2 Swapnil has return ed to his job at Indian Railways