• TABLE OF CONTENTS
HIDE
 Front Cover
 Title Page
 Foreword
 Table of Contents
 List of Tables
 List of Figures
 Chapter 1: Introduction
 Chapter 2: An approach to rural...
 Chapter 3: The physical setting...
 Chapter 4: Market structure
 Chapter 5: Agriculture : the physical...
 Chapter 6: Institutional conte...
 Chapter 7: A coordinated rural...
 Chapter 8: Implementation...
 Summary and conclusions
 Appendix A: Proposed regulations...
 Bibliography






Title: Social institutional profile of the Cayes Plain Basin
CITATION PAGE IMAGE ZOOMABLE PAGE TEXT
Full Citation
STANDARD VIEW MARC VIEW
Permanent Link: http://ufdc.ufl.edu/UF00054854/00001
 Material Information
Title: Social institutional profile of the Cayes Plain Basin
Physical Description: Book
Language: English
Creator: Coffey, William J.,
Lewis, Laurence A.
Haugue, Ann B.
Jauwerysen, Herman J. ( Contributor )
Affiliation: Clark University -- Institute for Development Anthropology
Publisher: Clark University, Institute for Development Anthropology
Publication Date: 1984
 Subjects
Subject: Farming   ( lcsh )
Agriculture   ( lcsh )
Farm life   ( lcsh )
Spatial Coverage: North America -- United States of America -- Massachussetts
 Notes
Funding: Electronic resources created as part of a prototype UF Institutional Repository and Faculty Papers project by the University of Florida.
 Record Information
Bibliographic ID: UF00054854
Volume ID: VID00001
Source Institution: University of Florida
Holding Location: University of Florida
Rights Management: All rights reserved by the source institution and holding location.
Resource Identifier: oclc - 23032334

Table of Contents
    Front Cover
        Front Cover
    Title Page
        Page i
    Foreword
        Page ii
        Page iii
    Table of Contents
        Page iv
    List of Tables
        Page v
    List of Figures
        Page vi
        Page vii
    Chapter 1: Introduction
        Page 1
        Page 2
        Page 3
        Page 4
        Page 5
        Page 6
    Chapter 2: An approach to rural regional development: Planning and implementation in the Haitian context
        Page 7
        Page 8
        Page 9
        Page 10
        Page 11
        Page 12
        Page 13
        Page 14
        Page 15
        Page 16
        Page 17
    Chapter 3: The physical setting : active processes and the existing environmental situation
        Page 18
        Page 19
        Page 20
        Page 21
        Page 22
        Page 23
        Page 24
        Page 25
        Page 26
        Page 27
        Page 28
        Page 29
        Page 30
        Page 31
        Page 32
        Page 33
        Page 34
        Page 35
        Page 36
        Page 37
    Chapter 4: Market structure
        Page 38
        Page 39
        Page 40
        Page 41
        Page 42
        Page 43
        Page 44
        Page 45
        Page 46
        Page 47
        Page 48
        Page 49
        Page 50
        Page 51
        Page 52
        Page 53
        Page 54
        Page 55
        Page 56
        Page 57
        Page 58
        Page 59
        Page 60
        Page 61
        Page 62
        Page 63
        Page 64
        Page 65
    Chapter 5: Agriculture : the physical economic interface
        Page 66
        Page 67
        Page 68
        Page 69
        Page 70
        Page 71
        Page 72
        Page 73
        Page 74
        Page 75
        Page 76
        Page 77
        Page 78
        Page 79
        Page 80
        Page 81
        Page 82
        Page 83
        Page 84
        Page 85
        Page 86
        Page 87
        Page 88
        Page 89
        Page 90
    Chapter 6: Institutional context
        Page 91
        Page 92
        Page 93
        Page 94
        Page 95
        Page 96
        Page 97
        Page 98
        Page 99
        Page 100
        Page 101
        Page 102
        Page 103
        Page 104
        Page 105
        Page 106
        Page 107
        Page 108
        Page 109
        Page 110
        Page 111
        Page 112
        Page 113
        Page 114
        Page 115
        Page 116
        Page 117
        Page 118
        Page 119
        Page 120
        Page 121
        Page 122
        Page 123
        Page 124
        Page 125
        Page 126
        Page 127
        Page 128
        Page 129
        Page 130
        Page 131
        Page 132
        Page 133
        Page 134
        Page 135
        Page 136
        Page 137
        Page 138
        Page 139
        Page 140
        Page 141
        Page 142
        Page 143
        Page 144
        Page 145
        Page 146
        Page 147
        Page 148
    Chapter 7: A coordinated rural regional development plan for the Cayes plain basin
        Page 149
        Page 150
        Page 151
        Page 152
        Page 153
        Page 154
        Page 155
        Page 156
        Page 157
        Page 158
        Page 159
        Page 160
        Page 161
        Page 162
        Page 163
        Page 164
        Page 165
        Page 166
        Page 167
    Chapter 8: Implementation strategy
        Page 168
        Page 169
        Page 170
        Page 171
        Page 172
        Page 173
        Page 174
        Page 175
        Page 176
        Page 177
        Page 178
        Page 179
        Page 180
        Page 181
        Page 182
        Page 183
        Page 184
        Page 185
        Page 186
        Page 187
        Page 188
    Summary and conclusions
        Page 189
        Page 190
    Appendix A: Proposed regulations for water users association for the Canal D'Avezac
        Page 191
        Page 192
        Page 193
        Page 194
    Bibliography
        Page 195
        Page 196
        Page 197
        Page 198
        Page 199
        Page 200
Full Text

62/,


COOPERATIVE AGREEMENT ON HUMAN SETTLEMENTS
AND NATURAL RESOURCE SYSTEMS ANALYSIS


SOCIAL INSTITUTIONAL PROFILE OF THE CAYES PLAIN BASIN:
TOWARDS A COORDINATED RURAL REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY


Dy
William J. Coffey, Laurence A. Lewis
Ann B. Hause

with the assistance of
Herman J. Jauwerysen


Haiti Regional Report
Clark University/Institute for Development Anthropology
Cooperative Agreement (USAID


[I


w


t U


II -'


I}


Clark University
International DevelopmenI Program
950 Main Street
Worceste MA AO1610


Institute for Development Anthropology
Suite 302. P O. Box 818
S99 Collier Street
Rillnhalil,'-1n NV 1'?Qf)


; -- ;- --- i :; -- -ili


0 ~3


\4Wa


/00#


k \




















SOCIAL INSTITUTIONAL PROFILE OF THE CAYES PLAIN BASIN:

TOWARDS A COORDINATED RURAL REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY






by


William J. Coffey, Laurence A. Lewis
Ann B. Hauge


With the Assistance of
Herman J. Lauwerysen









Clark University/Institute for Development Anthropology
Cooperative Agreement (USAID)


January 1984










FOREWORD


In this proposed plan for coordinated rural regional
development, the two primary goals are to improve the rural quality
of life and at the same time to improve the land resource base.
These two objectives are only possible to attain by considering all
lands within the targeted areas in regard to their potential
capabilities for development and resource improvements. Among
others, these resource improvements include possible production
capabilities related to food, fuel (charcoal), and timber; physical
factors including hydrology, drought likelihood, slope stability,
and erosion-siltation rates; infrastructure improvement including
storage facilities and transportation; economic improvements in
marketing, credit, and processing; and improvements in the
agricultural use of lands including seed improvements, new-crops,
conservation practices and field consolidation.

The physical factors affecting production and environmental
quality in a land-rural based economy are largely related to the
nature of the drainage basin in which the lands are situated,
including climatic, lithologic, and topographic properties. The
degree to which development activities are conceptualized within
the physical environmental constraints--that is, work in harmony
with nature--will determine to a large degree interactions of the
human activities in maintaining or improving the area's
environmental situation.

Regional development may be implemented within any boundary,
but planning environmental improvements, infrastructures, and
mobilization of human resources will encounter significant
restrictions unless carried out within meaningful units. In a
river basin all natural resources can be controlled from the
highest to lowest lands through the regulation of surface waters.
For this reason basin boundaries delimit a meaningful planning unit
in most humid areas where agricultural expansion is the primary
goal. Almost all river basins are formed through a system of
tributary or smaller stream basins. Because of this structural
property, a development plan can be executed gradually in a
regional context sub-basin by sub-basin according to the
availability of human, financial, institutional, and other
development requisites. When the planning strategy is expanded
from tributary to tributary basin on a systematic basis, upon
completion of the planning and implementation stages of the
project, the whole river basin's socio-economic and land resource
base will be improved.

From the physical perspective, a planning strategy attempts
to initiate improvements in the tributary basins located in the
major watershed areas of the river basin, then sequentially
incorporates the remaining basins in the downstream direction.








This approach reflects the natural unidirectional flow of energy
and matter within river systems. However, human systems such as
market and social networks needed to initiate and absorb physical
changes usually have different functional relations than the
upstream-downstream spatial pattern of the river network. Until
the regional river basin development project is complete, the human
physical domains must be integrated into a complementary planning
unit to insure continuous acceptance and maintenance of completed
land use and institutional improvements.

Most projects are begun and completed with various ranges of
success in the short term. However, even the most successful
projects often need to be restarted after a number of years. All
too often with the completion of a project in the formal sense
(termination of external funding), its dynamics gradually wind
down, and lands revert to their original status. A number of years
later the project in new trappings is reintroduced and the old
scheme is recreated. With the increasing population, deteriorating
hydrologic conditions, and ongoing soil degradation, a new project
incurs higher costs and less degrees of freedom in meeting its
expected goals. Many Haitian agricultural projects have been
analogous to the Alice Through the Looking Glass phenomenon of
running forward on a reverse running conveyor belt. To remain
where you are, let alone to improve the situation, requires even
more effort. For example, ever since colonial times when
irrigation was introduced in Saint-Domingue, a vicious cycle of
abandonment and rebuilding of irrigation has been set into motion.
Yet with each rebuilding scheme, potential has decreased due to the
chronic processes of deforestation and soil erosion that directly
affect water and soil resources. Superimposed on these ongoing
physical factors are a plethora of human variables such as land
tenure, organizational deficiencies, and increasing population
densities that diminish the likelihood of success.

Perhaps the one underlying design flaw in most previous
rural-based projects was that projects were conceptualized within
the very narrow confines of the immediate project. Offsite project
variables and impacts were rarely considered. Likewise, the
engineering and public works components were usually stressed while
the human infrastructure, including organization and maintenance
components, were downplayed. It is for these reasons that this
plan stresses a regional rather than sectoral approach and that the
conceptualization of the rural development strategy includes both
the physical and human components in a coordinated framework. The
river basin, as a whole, as opposed to specific units within it, is
the focus for the development strategy since all areas within the
basin have direct and indirect impacts throughout the entire
system. Thus, the coordinated rural regional development strategy
that is presented in the following sections of this report attempts
to incorporate existing processes as they operate in rural areas.
It attempts to stimulate the region's latent potential as well as
to strengthen its existing capabilities.













TABLE OF CONTENTS


FORWORD ................ ...................... ..... .

LIST OF TABLES ...............................................

LIST OF FIGURES ........................... .. .. ..........


CHAPTER 1 Introduction .....................................



CHAPTER 2 An Approach to Rural Regional Development: Planning
and Implementation in the Haitian Context .........


CHAPTER 3 The Physical Setting: Active Processes
and the Existing Environmental Situation ..........


CHAPTER 4 Market Structure ....................................



CHAPTER 5 Agriculture: The Physical Economic Interface .....



CHAPTER 6 Institutional Context ..........................


CHAPTER 7 A Coordinated Rural Regional Development Plan
for the Cayes Plain Basin ...............................


CHAPTER 8 Implementation Strategy ........................

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS .. ...................................

APPENDIX A .........................................


BIBLIOGRAPHY ..................................... ... ....


ii

iv

v


1




7



18


38



66



91




149


168

189
191


195









LIST OF TABLES


Tables Page

3.1 Class Characteristics and Recommended Land Use .......... 25

3.2 L'Acul River Basin Topographic Units .................... 29

3.3 Monthly Moisture Availability Index for L'Acul
River Basin ............................................ 33

3.4 Soil Classes of Upper L'Acul ........................... 35

4.1 Topologies of Haitian Markets .......................... 40

4.2 Market Days in L'Acul River Basin ....................... 43

4.3 Market Characteristics ................................... 46

4.4 L'Acul River Basin Marketing System Hierarchy .......... 49

4.5 Origin--Destination Matrix: Commodity Flows ............ 56

4.6 Market Prices: L'Acul River Basin Marketing System ..... 58

4.7 Retailer Profits ...................................... 62

5.1 Potential Rainfed Crops for Cayes Plain Basin ........... 67

5.2 Crops Observed: November December, 1983 in
L'Acul River Basin .................................... 69

5.3 Modes of Tenure ........................................... 74

5.4 Ownership/Tenancy Arrangements by Topographical Unit .... 88

6.1 DCCH/CARITAS Affiliated Groupments in Cayes Basin ....... 98

6.2 DCCH/CARITAS Land Farmed by Groupments .................. 98

6.3 DCCH/CARITAS Groupment Investments in Cayes Basin, 1983.. 99

6.4 Irrigation Projects in the Torbeck Plain ................ 104

6.5 Irrigation Projects in the L'Acul and Cayes Plain ....... 106

6.7 Estimated Water Taxes Assessed in Les Cayes
Agricultural District ................................ 118

6.8 1982-83 Extension of Credit in Cayes Plain Basin by IDAI. 126

6.9 1981-82 BCA Loans for the Cayes Regional Office ......... 128










LIST OF FIGURES


Figures Page

1.1 The Cayes Plain Basin Region .......................... 4

2.1 Matrix of Planning Approaches ......................... 11

2.2. Delimitation of River Basin ........................... 14

2.3 Conceptual Model of Rural Regional Development
Planning in Haiti ................................... 15

3.1 L'Acul River Basin .................................. 24

3.2 Sequence of Assigning Classes to Land Suitable for
Cultivation .................................. .... 26

3.3 Terrain Characteristics--L'Acul River Basin ............ 28

3.4 Distribution of Soils in Cayes Plain Basin ............. 36

4.1 Market Locations--L'Acul Basin ........................ 44

4.2 Spatial and Temporal Dimensions, L'Acul
Marketing System .................................... 45

4.3 Market Hierarchy, L'Acul Basin Marketing System ........ 50

4.4 Origins of Goods Flowing to L'Acul River Basin
Markets (13 Figures) ............................... 51-54

4.5 Temporal Variations in Average Monthly Prices for
Selected Commodities ................................ 59

4.6 Les Cayes Market Price Averages ........................ 60

5.1 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Purchased Plots by Location ........................... 76

5.2 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Inherited Plots by Location ........................... 76

5.3 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Owned Plots (Inherited or Bought) by Location ......... 76

5.4 Frequency Distribution of Number of Plots (per farmer)
by Location .......................................... 77










5.5 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Rented Plots by Location .............................. 77

5.6 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Sharecropped Plots by Location ...................... 77

5.7 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Rented Plots by Size ................................ 79

5.8 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Owned Plots by Size .................................. 79

5.9 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Number of
Sharecropped Plots by Size ............................ 80

5.10 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Total Number
of Plots by Size ..................................... 80

5.11 Frequency Distribution of Farm Size Average by Location. 80

5.12 Frequency Distribution of Purchased Land Prices
(per karo) by Location ............................... 82

5.13 Frequency Distribution of Rented Land Prices
(per karo) (per year) by Location ..................... 82

5.14 Frequency Distribution of Land Prices (Purchased)
(by decades) by Location .............................. 82

5.15 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Owned
(Inherited or Purchased) Land by Location ............. 84

5.16 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Rented Land
by Location ........................................... 84

5.17 Frequency and Percentage Distribution of Sharecropped
Land by Location ..................................... 84

5.18 Frequency Distribution of Average Plot Sizes
by Location ........................................... 85

5.19 Frequency and Percentage of Number of Farmers by
Type of Tenure ...................................... 85

7.1 Planning Goals and Interventions ....................... 152









CHAPTER 1


INTRODUCTION


1.1 THE SCOPE OF THE STUDY

A Social Institutional Profile (SIP) usually is intended to
provide information on the social-economic, natural resource, and
organizational/institutional structures in a particular area, so as to
facilitate the USAID in-country mission's pursuit of its goals in that
area. However, the present report extends the conventional limits of
a SIP since, in addition to furnishing useful background information
on the Cayes Plain Basin study area (in the form of "hard" data,
interview results, field observations and more impressionistic
information), it seeks to accomplish three other objectives. First,
it attempts to establish a general methodology that can be used to
analyze the physical, economic, and institutional characteristics of a
rural region and, subsequently, to construct a workable development
plan for that region. Second, it attempts to conduct the background
analysis and to specify the dimensions of such a development plan for
the Cayes Plain Basin. As indicated in the Foreword, the principal
goals of a development plan for tnis area are the amelioration of the
quality of rural life and the improvement of the land resource base.
Finally, this report seeks to develop an appropriate and effective
strategy for implementing the.development plan. This latter objective
is especially crucial since, without a set of effective implementation
mechanisms, even the most well-conceived plan is merely a hypothetical
exercise.


1.2 THE CAYES PLAIN BASIN: RATIONALE

The focus of this extended SIP, the Cayes Plain Basin, has been
selected for analysis for a number of cogent reasons.

1. The Cayes Plain Basin is in many ways an archetype of the humid
portions of Haiti since it manifests all of the topographic units
found in these humid areas. The Platons Unit, while of minor areal
extent compared to the total area of the Cayes Plain Basin, is in many
ways a microcosm of the physical environment in the Central Plateau
and, to some extent, it is characterized by similar problems of
restricted accessibility.

2. The Basin is both a major agricultural area and one of the
country's most densely populated regions, approximately 375,000 people
live within the Cayes Plain Basin (SNEM 1982). It is an area
characterized by a range of settlement types, including the city of
Les Cayes (pop. 37,000), Haiti's third largest center. The land in
the basin is intensively utilized and covers the spectrum in terms of
quality and productivity.










3. The Basin is an area having untapped water resources which hold
high potential for the enhancement of agriculture. Further, like
other portions of Haiti, it contains active irrigation works which are
characterized by a continual need for rehabilitation.

4. Not only does the Basin appear to be an operationally valid
planning region, from both human and physical points of view, but it
also appears to be a manageable planning unit. The latter denotes
that the Basin is sufficiently compact (compared, for example, with
the Central Plateau) such that investments committed will not be
spread too thinly; and that logical sub-regional units exist that may
be employed for the implementation of a development plan. That is to
say, from a temporal perspective it is impossible to simultaneously
implement all elements of a plan in all portions of the planning
region. Implementation must be phased, and this requires the
delineation of sub-regions which possess an internal functional
integrity in terms of both human and physical criteria. The Cayes
Plain Basin is completely occupied by three such units: The drainage
areas of a set of small rivers that emerge from groundwaters on the
lowlands (e.g., the Picot and Bordonne Rivers), the Rivibre de la
Grande Ravine du Sud, and L'Acul River Basin.

For reasons of logistics and human resources it has not been
possible for the Study Team to examine each of these three sub-regions
in equal depth. For the following reasons L'Acul River Basin has been
selected as the detailed case-study of this report.

a. Just as the Cayes Plain Basin is a model for the humid portions
of Haiti, L'Acul River Basin is a model which manifests the general
characteristics of the larger Cayes Plain region. In addition, L'Acul
Basin contains the Platons highlands which, as noted above, are unique
in the Cayes Plain Basin, but are typical in the broader national
context.

b. Due to L'Acul Watershed Project conducted by the U.S. Soil
Conservation Service, there exists a useful set of background data
which can be used as a point of reference for L'Acul sub-region. The
dearth of consistent and reliable data continues to be a major
constraint to development planning in all regions of Haiti.

c. A number of AID projects and interventions have been instituted
in L'Acul Basin in recent years. It is hoped that the program
outlined here can complement and build upon these initiatives in such
a manner that the individual impacts of all activities will be
multiplicative.

d. Just as the Cayes Plain Basin is identified as a valid and
manageable planning region, at a reduced spatial scale the same
characteristics are attributed to L'Acul River Basin. L'Acul Basin is
a relatively self-contained unit from both a human and a physical
perspective. Further, it is composed of four distinct sub-regional
units which can be effectively utilized for the construction and
implementation of a coordinated rural regional development plan.









1.3 THE CAYES PLAIN BASIN REGION: OVERVIEW

Located in the southwestern portion of the Southern Peninsula,
the Cayes Plain Basin comprises approximately 720 square kilometers
(Figure 1.1). Two large river systems, L'Acul and Grande Ravine du
Sud, as well as ten smaller permanent river systems are found within
the basin. From a perspective of rural development, a wide spectrum
of ecologic conditions exist in the area. These range from high-risk,
low potential, severely degraded lands to low-risk, high potential
agricultural lands (DATPE 1982).

Estimates of population vary widely for the Cayes Plain Basin.
According to the 1982 census, approximately 375,000 people live within
the area. Of this total, 10 percent live in Les Cayes. Excluding Les
Cayes, and to a far lesser extent Camp Perrin, almost all the
remaining inhabitants earn their livelihood from occupations directly
connected to agricultural pursuits. Accurate figures on the age
structure of the population are elusive, but a casual, non-scientific
sample undertaken by the Study Team indicates that approximately 40
percent of the population is under fifteen years. As this population
ages and enters the reproductive stage, either ever increasing demands
will be placed on the immediate lands within the basin or outmigration
will dramatically increase. Already population densities range from
over 475/km2 on the lowlands to a "low" of 125/km2 in the poorer
agricultural areas within the slope zones. No place within the whole
Cayes Plain Basin can be classified as underpopulated.

As would be expected, the economic structure'within the Cayes
Plain is dominated by the agricultural activities of its inhabitants.
No secondary industries exist within the basin. Additionally, none of
the primary industries utilize materials that are imported into the
region. Thus the industrial sector that exists within the area is
directly linked to the land resource. This is obvious from the
following list of active industries. Within the Cayes Plain Basin
there are a few small clairin distilleries, one small sugar central,
one small dairy plant, a few vetiver plants, and some livestock
slaughtering facilities; these represent the gamut of industrial
activity. A small tomato processing plant functioning in 1982-1983
appears at this time to be out of business. This paucity of
industrial development is reflected in the economic structure of the
family unit for the overwhelming majority of the Cayes Plain Basin
inhabitants. The rural family unit is largely a self-sufficient
entity that lacks any real specialization. Even the irrigated rice
farmers grow a variety of crops. While this self-sufficient structure
maximizes the family unit's ability to survive under present
environmental conditions, it must result in a decreased level of
economic efficiency and output. This is reflected in the low
agricultural yields when the Cayes Plain Basin is compared to other
areas in the world.




























Golfe de la
Gonave


FIGURE 1.1


HAITI


International boundary
Department boundary
o National capital
0 Departement capitals
* Cities

0 10 20 30 Miles
0 10 20 30 Kilometers








The crops grown in the area are dominated by varieties that are
largely consumed locally, as will be shown in Chapter 5. This is
particularly true for the rainfed agricultural areas. The two
dominant irrigated crops, tobacco and rice, clearly enter the national
market. Throughout the Cayes Plain Basin a well articulated market
system exists. The flows of commodities through this market system
reach the most distant points of the basin with surprising facility.
Yet, like the industrial composition of the region, the market's goods
are dominated by the agrarian economy of the area. The structure and
functions of the Cayes Plain Basin marketing system are developed in
Chapter 4.

The institutional composition of the basin in many ways reflects
both the patterns of population densities and the ease of
accessibility within the Cayes Plain Basin. By far, the greatest
concentration of institutions is located on the Cayes Plain. Except
for the church, government security, conseils communautaires, a few
PVOs and a number of informal local community-based organizations, the
upland areas of the basin have been largely ignored. It is on the
lowlands that the majority of public and private, both formal and
informal organizations are located. Most government ministries are
represented in the basin, specifically in Les Cayes. However
reflected by the magnitude of their presence and the level of the
functionaries, this region appears to have been a relatively low
priority for the national government.

Given this low level of involvement, the government has chosen
to emphasize the lowlands in the 'majority of its spheres of work. For
example, while limited government credit (BCA) has just become
available (1983) for the small farmers, the BCA efforts have only been
on the lowlands. This is likewise true for most church activities,
with the exception of some missionary work. Since most PVOs in the
Cayes area are related to church activities, these too have been
proportionally biased to the lowlands. One slight exception to this
is in the Camp Perrin area, a location immediately juxtaposed to the
lowlands. Even USAID has emphasized the lowlands. This concentration
of activities on the lowlands, by almost all organizations, has
resulted in an unequal allocation of resources within the basin to the
detriment of all areas in the region including the lowlands. The role
and nature of organizations in the context of co-operative rural
development for the Cayes Plain Basin, is discussed in detail in
Chapter 6.








1.4 THE STUDY PLAN

As noted at the beginning of this chapter, the present document
is designed to accomplish four objectives:

1. The provision of a range of specific data and general
information concerning the study area;

2. The establishment of a planning methodology which can be
generally employed throughout Haiti;

3. The specification of a coordinated rural regional development
plan for the Cayes Plain Basin and, in particular, L'Acul River Basin;
and

4. The recommendation of an appropriate and effective set of
mechanisms for the implementation of the development plan.

Chapters 2 through 6 deal with the first two objectives.
Chapter 2 specifies the conceptual model of the planning process that
the Study Team utilizes subsequently in this report. Chapters 3 and 4
are detailed descriptions and analyses of the physical setting and
marketing structure of L'Acul River Basin; Chapter 5 deals with the
interface of these two elements in L'Acul system: agricultural
activity. These latter three chapters are relatively lengthy as they
are intended not only to present specific information about the study
area but also to inform the reader concerning the relevent factors and
variables that need to be taken into consideration, and concerning the
appropriate methods of analyses to be utilized. To the reader
concerned strictly with policy formulation and policy implementation
these technical chapters may seem painfully detailed. It is the hope
of the Study Team, however, that this document can serve as a useful
model for the entire planning process--technical assessment as well as
policy formulation and implementation.

Chapter 6 presents a description and analysis of the
institutional context of the study area and considers a range of
formal and informal, governmental and non-governmental organizations
which have significant implications not only for the formulation of a
development plan but also, and most particularly, for the
implementation of a plan.

The third and fourth objectives cited above--the specification
of a coordinated rural regional development plan for L'Acul River
Basin, and the recommendation of an effective set of implementation
mechanisms--are the concern of the final sections, Chapters 7 and 8.
The material contained in these two chapters is the logical
culmination of the approaches developed and the analyses conducted in
Chapters 2 through 6.










CHAPTER 2


AN APPROACH TO RURAL REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT:
PLANNING AND IMPLEMENTATION IN THE HAITIAN CONTEXT


2.1 INTRODUCTION

The purpose of this chapter is to make explicit the view of the
planning process that the study team will utilize subsequently in this
report. After some general comments on major issues in development
planning, the elements of the coordinated regional approach employed
in this exercise are outlined and justified. A conceptual model of
the development planning process based upon these elements is then
presented.


2.2 ISSUES IN DEVELOPMENT PLANNING

Over the past thirty years, during which period regional
development, in general, and rural development, in particular, have
occupied the attention of governments and planners in the developed
and developing worlds, a number of identifiable approaches to the
stimulation of economic growth and social well-being have been
adopted. The nature of these individual approaches is, in turn, a
function of the view of the causes of underdevelopment that is
explicitly or implicitly held by decision-makers and planners.

There are essentially six views of the roots of
underdevelopment; naturally, these views are not mutually exclusive
and there is considerable overlap between them. The first view is
based upon a combined balance of trade/economic base framework and
holds that exports are the principal growth stimulus for a region.
Export-producing activities ("basic activities", in the terminology of
economic base theory) create "injections" into the local (regional)
economy which, through the multiplier mechanism and the circular flow
of income, not only generate wealth but also stimulate local-serving
or "non-basic" activities (e.g., retail stores, services,
entertainment facilities etc.). A related concept is that of import
substitution. By reducing the "leakages" from the local economy that
occur when imported goods and services are purchased--that is, by
substituting local products for the imports--an effect similar to that
resulting from the stimulation of exports can be achieved. Regional
development policies which are based upon this view stress the
creation and expansion of export markets and opportunities for the
substitution of local goods and services for imports. A related
concept is the staples theory, which attributes the lack of growth or
the decline of the economies of certain regions to a natural resource
base for which there is a low demand, i.e., for which there is little
export potential.









A second view concerns the role of migration as an economic
adjustment mechanism. According to this line of neo-classical
reasoning, per capital income is the sole acceptable measure of
development; per capital income is a function of both the total
population of a region and its total earned income. An increase in
per capital income may be achieved by a reduction in the divisor, i.e.
by the out-migration of unemployed and underemployed portions of the
population to areas where employment opportunities are more
plentiful. It is believed that this economic adjustment will
generally occur as a result of the normal functioning of the labor
market mechanism. The major constraint to this approach is policies
(e.g. social assistance programs) which attempt to interfere with the
market mechanism by creating a better standard of living for the
population in situ, thus reducing the motivation for migration.
Policies based upon this view emphasize the reduction in the social
"safety net", the encouragement of the free operation of the labor
market, and the provision of incentives to migration.

A third view stresses the role of physical capital and
infrastructure in development. The argument is essentially a simple
one based on the notions that industry requires a suitable environment
in order to develop and to flourish and that improving both
intraregional and interregional accessibility will stimulate economic
transactions. The construction of roads and sewers, the extension of
electrical networks, and the establishment of serviced industrial
parks are among the policies associated with this approach.

A fourth view stresses the importance of a region's industrial
structure. The argument here is that in order for economic growth to
occur a region requires both certain strategic industries (for
example, those that can create value added from the region's resource
bases) and a sufficiently well-developed set of linkages between
industries. The latter point refers to the complementarity achieved
when two or more firms create functional connections between their
products in the form of forward or backward linkages; for example, a
firm producing automobile engines has backward linkages to the firm
producing carburators and forward linkages to the firm that assembles
the finished automobile. Policies based upon this view involve the
analysis of industrial structure, generally using input-output or
inter-industry analysis, and attempts to alleviate bottlenecks and to
fill-in "missing-links" in the industrial structure. A policy that
overlaps both the physical capital/infrastructure and industrial
structure viewpoints involves the establishment of growth centers. A
growth center represents an attempt to maximize a region's
connectivity with the rest of the national economic system,
particularly with the nation's urban network, so that "growth
impulses" generated nationally will diffuse throughout the region via
"spread" or "trickle down" effects. The designated growth center is
generally an existing urban node into which various types of economic
activity are concentrated in order to induce regional economic growth
and to create the potential for facilitating inter-industry linkages.









A fifth view assigns the causality for underdevelopment not to
intrinsic factors within the region itself but to external
exploitation; this is the neo-marxist approach of dependency theory.
The reasoning here is that the economic and political "center" of a
country is able to dominate the "periphery" (i.e., the lesser
developed regions) and to extract surplus economic value from its
natural resource base, its relatively weak industrial structure, and
its labor force. Dependency theory thus builds a model of polarized
economic development in which the center continues to grow both as a
result of its own attributes and as a result of its exploitation of
the periphery, and in which the periphery remains at a low level of
development. Policies associated with this approach involve selective
regional closure, that is, attempts to reduce the linkages between the
center and the periphery, thus curtailing the domination by the former
of the latter.

Finally, there are a number of related views which attribute
underdevelopment to certain barriers preventing the indigenous
regional population from reaching its full economic and societal
potential. Lack of information, knowledge, and know-how, as well as
insufficiently developed levels of animation, motivation, and
entrepreneurial spirit retard the capacity of the population for
raising its level of social and economic well-being. This approach is
based upon the notion that the source of development lies in the local
population rather than in the region's natural resource endowment or
in external factors. Policies stemming from this viewpoint stress the
need for better knowledge and skills, better access to information,
and a higher degree of both social animation and entrepreneurial
activity. To a large extent, these types of policies, stressing as
they do the indigenous population and its potential, are the inverse
of those mentioned above which stress external linkages, physical
capital, infrastructure, and industrial structure.

In the discussion above two general issues are explicit: that
of increasing the degree of integration of a region into the national
economic structure versus regional closure; and that of emphasizing
the development of human resources versus emphasizing physical capital
and infrastructure. Related to these two issues, and implicit in the
above discussion, are two others. First, there is the question of the
goal of regional development: achieving national economic efficiency
(i.e. maximizing total economic output) or promoting equity between
individuals and/or regions. The mutual exclusion of these two goals
is one of the classic dilemmas of development theory, one which
appears incapable of resolution. Second, there is the question of
adopting a regional (spatial) approach versus a sectoral approach.
This dichotomy is discussed in detail in the following section.
However, it must be stressed that there is no single answer to the
complex problem of regional development. All of the viewpoints that
have been presented contain within them elements of truth.









2.3 RURAL DEVELOPMENT PLANNING: THE COORDINATED REGIONAL APPROACH

In this section, the Study Team's basic planning philosophy is
made explicit. This document is neither philosophical nor theoretical
in purpose, but the nature of the approach adopted must be specified
from the outset. The most effective manner in which to present this
approach is to situate it in the context of a simple typology of
planning alternatives (Figure 2.1). This typology is constructed
using two dimensions: spatial orientation and functional
orientation. Type I approaches are not only sectoral (rather than
regional) in orientation, but also focus upon a single activity. This
is often referred to as a "development project" strategy and may be
exemplified by the construction of a dam or of an irrigation project.
A Type II strategy involves a single activity but is concerned with
its distribution over a certain region; for example, an attempt to
increase tree planting in the Artibonite River Basin. Type III
approaches are non-regional but do attempt to coordinate sectoral
activity. One may cite as an example a general national health
program having the following components: the provision of better
sanitation facilities, the provision of potable water, increased
capacity for the treatment of malaria, and the suppression of the
mosquito population. Finally, a Type IV strategy is both regional and
coordinated in nature. This is the approach adopted by the Study Team
and is now explored in more detail.

A coordinated approach to planning signifies one in which
various economic sectors (e.g., marketing, transportation,
agriculture, industry), various.components of the physical environment
(e.g., rainfall, soil depth and quality, geomorphology and lithology),
and various elements of the socio-cultural milieu (e.g., attitudes,
values, and beliefs associated with farming practices and land tenure)
are considered. Further, this approach recognizes that these three
broad categories are themselves functionally interrelated. Thus, one
would take into consideration not only agricultural, marketing, and
processing activities but also the relationship of these to both
physical and socio-cultural factors. From a systems perspective the
planning environment can be regarded as a set of interacting systems,
each of which is composed of interacting sub-systems. Obviously there
are degrees of coordination between the extremes of the single
activity approach and the "perfectly" coordinated approach. While
"perfect" coordination is unlikely to ever be achieved, one can strive
to identify and to coordinate a set of key interacting elements. One
important implication of a coordinated approach to planning is that
its successful operationalization requires an interdisciplinary effort.

A regional approach is one in which the spatial dimensions of
both human social-economic activity and the physical environment are
incorporated into the planning process. In contrast to the sectoral
view implicitly held by the classical economist, who treats the world
as if it were located on the head of a pin and as if location in space
is of no import, the regional view acknowledges two important facts:










first, that all human and physical phenomena are located (in both
absolute, and relative terms) somewhere in terrestrial space; and,
second, that the specific location at which a phenomenon is found can
not only exert a profound influence upon the nature of that phenomenon
but can also affect the degree to which that phenomenon is capable of
influencing other phenomena. For example, the economic viability of
an aluminum smelter may range from very poor to very good, depending
upon how it is situated relative to sources of hydroelectric energy.







FIGURE 2.1

MATRIX OF PLANNING APPROACHES



Spatial Orientation


Single
Activity
Approach


Functional

Orientation


Coordinated
Approach


Sectoral Approach Regional Approacn




I II









III IV


h m A i










Similarly, its location will have potentially strong effects upon ooth
the employment levels and the environmental quality of the surrounding
area. Thus, economic geographers, regional planners, and regional
economists concern themselves not only with such concepts as distance
decay functions, spillover and neighborhood effects, and distribution
over space, but also with the manner in which individual subregions
interact with one another over space through flows of people, goods,
information, and physical material. From an entirely pragmatic
viewpoint the regional approach is eminently sensible since it
encourages the concentration of efforts within a well-defined area
rather than allowing them to be spread too thinly over a wide area.
Having discussed the elements of the regional approach, it is
necessary to define more precisely the concept of "region" and then to
specify the regional unit employed in this study. A region is an
intellectual construct having no existence beyond the minds of the
planners and policy-makers who establish it for a specific purpose
using various human and physical criteria that will best permit
planning goals to be achieved. That is to say, regions do not exist
naturally but are delineated as needed. There is, however, a logic to
the delineation of a region, and this generally involves the
consideration of both the homogeneity of attributes (e.g., per capital
income, soil and crop types) and the flow patterns of people,
products, information, money, energy and physical matter (e.g., soil
particles, water). The basic rule of thumb in delineating a region is
that the variation in the criteria utilized should be lower within the
region than that between the region and an external area. For
example, one would expect that the per capital income level (if that
were one of the criteria utilized) at two points within the region
would vary less than between one point within the region and one
external point.

In the approach utilized here the river basin is the regional
unit of analysis. There are two reasons for this decision. First,
many of the variables and attributes upon which this rural regional
development planning methodology is based (e.g., pedological,
biological, and hydrological factors) clearly function within the
boundaries of major river basins. Second, field investigation by the
Study Team has shown that many manifestations of human social and
economic activity in Haiti also tend to function most strongly within
river basin boundaries. That is to say, there are generally more
social and economic flows within river basins than between basins.
(See, for example, the discussion of marketing in chapter 4). This is
in contrast to developed countries characterized by better
transportation capabilities and more mobile populations, where the
river basin is generally not, from a human perspective, an appropriate
regional unit since it does not effectively delimit the boundaries of
economic and social flows. In the Haitian context there is also a
third consideration. Due to the general unavailability of
socio-economic data for units below the national level, and in the









absence of specific fieldwork, insufficient human acitvity information
exists for attempting to delineate regions. Thus, by default
exclusively physical criteria must often be utilized. In summary,
when higher agricultural productivity and the preservation of the
environment in a particular area of Haiti are the goals of the
planning exercise, as they are here, both physical and human evidence
suggests that the river basin is an appropriate regional unit.

By definition a river basin comprises all of the area above the
mouth of a river that contributes to the discharge of the river
system. A basin includes both the area that contributes to the
surface (runoff) waters as well as the zones contributing groundwater,
since the discharge of a permanent river is determined by both the
former and the latter. In practice, however, most river basin
boundaries are determined solely by topographic features that produce
the surface flows into the river network (Figure 2.2).

In a river basin all energy and matter flow in a unidirectional
manner from the upper reaches to the mouth of the river. It is this
property that makes the river basin a logical unit for regional
development concerned with agriculture and environment since two
crucial variables affecting agriculture, water and soil, are removed
and transported from the land via the river system. In addition, the
flow characteristics of these two variables as well as the
interactions of numerous human interactions (e.g., crop treatment)
with these variables are determined by the energy attributes
(altitude, slope) of the basin. According to Donner (1975: 44-45),
because of Haiti's rugged topography, only when the river basin is the
basic planning unit can agricultural development dccur.


2.4 A CONCEPTUAL MODEL OF THE COORDINATED RURAL REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT
PROCESS

Having explored the nature of the terms "coordinated" and
"regional", the conceptual model of the coordinated rural regional
development process that is utilized by the Study Team is now
presented (Figure 2.3). It must be stressed that this model is not
simply a theoretical creation but is, rather, one designed to achieve
results. It is for this reason that, in the planning process, the
implementation of the plan is given equal weight with the development
of a logical plan.

Rural development in Haiti is ultimately a question of being
able to improve its agricultural system. This statement is not meant
to imply that other activities such as primary and secondary
processing and urban-based growth center functions do not play a role;
it is simply a recognition of the fact that the overwhelming majority
of the rural population earns its livelihood from worKing the soil.









Delimination of River Basin


A D S D B
Cross -sector along line A B
D = basin divide
S = stream channel


K000


Figure 2 .2












FIGURE 2.3 CONCEPTUAL MODEL OF RURAL REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN HAITI


Technical Assessment Filter 1. Development Filter 2.
Plan




Natural Attitudes, Potentials and Existing and Potential
Resource Values, Constraints: Development Mechanisms
System Beliefs, b and Organizations
j Perceptions Rural Regional
of Population Development (Public and Private
Concerning Sectors, PVOs)
Agricultural System Natural,
SAgricultural,
Market Systems

Market System









Social-Cultural- Design, Execution,
Institutional Monitoring, Evalua-
Context tion, Phasing,
Investment Level



Implementation Strategy










Agricultural production is subject to the constraints and potentials
of the natural resource system: rainfall, climate, soil type and
depth. Similarly, in an economy such as Haiti's where produce is not
grown exclusively for on-site consumption, the nature of the marketing
system has important implications for the creation and retention of
surplus value by individual households. Thus, the first step in the
planning process is a technical assessment of these three interrelated
systems.

An "objective" technical assessment, however, does not
necessarily reflect the "real" world. It is an axiom of social
science that the use of the natural environment by man and the manner
in which he conducts social and economic activities will be a function
of his attitudes, values, beliefs, and perceptions: not only those
that relate directly to the systems in 'question but also those that
relate to ancilliary phenomena and processes, e.g., religious
practices, the ownership of land and animals, the role of the extended
family. It is for this reason that the technical assessment must be
passed through a first social-cultural-institutional filter. At this
point certain directions and initiatives suggested by the technical
assessment will be shown to be inappropriate wnile other, new
considerations may emerge.

Having developed a thorough understanding of the three critical
systems and of the social-cultural-institutional context in which they
are situated, it becomes possible to weigh the regions's potentials
and constraints and to arrive at a development plan which explicitly
considers the interaction of the various economic sectors, components
of the physical environment, and elements of the socio-cultural
milieu, all within a regional framework. Depending upon the specific
nature of the planning exercise and upon the specific goals
established, the regional scope and substantive breadth will vary.

However, the most well-conceived plan is merely an intellectual
curiosity until it is implemented. The implementation stage is thus
the most critical element of the planning process and has two
components: the identification or establishment of suitable
implementation mechanisms and the formulation of an implementation
strategy. The former may involve governmental or quasi-governmental
authorities and organizations, actors from the private sector, private
voluntary organizations and other organizations and institutions in
the not-for-profit sector. Once again, in order to arrive at the
appropriate implementation mechanisms, "objective" reality must be
passed through a social-cultural-institutional filter which may
eliminate certain alternatives and suggest others. Once this has been
accomplished the latter concern, the implementation strategy, may then
be addressed. As indicated, this includes considerations of the
design of individual plan components as well as execution of the
overall strategy; the on-going monitoring and evaluation of plan
implementation; the phasing of the specific components of the plan
implementation strategy; and requisite levels of investment.





17



Having specified the nature of the coordinated rural regional
development approach adopted, the following chapters examine the
individual elements of the planning model. Chapters 3, 4, and 5
comprise the technical assessment of the physical, marketing, and
agricultural systems. Chapter 6 explores the social-cultural-
institutional context that underlies the model's two filters, focusing
specifically upon institutions and organizations--not only describing
those that exist but also citing what will be required in order to
successfully implement a coordinated rural regional development plan.
The final two chapters outline the specific development plan and
implementation strategy that are indicated by the factors and
conditions reviewed in Chapters 3 to 6.









CHAPTER 3


THE PHYSICAL SETTING: ACTIVE PROCESSES AND
THE EXISTING ENVIRONMENTAL SITUATION



3.1 INTRODUCTION

In humid tropical areas erosion is one of the most serious
limiting factors in agricultural and livestock production. Geologic
erosion is a natural'phenomenon. In most areas where vegetation has
been unaltered by human activities a general balance exists between
erosion and soil formation. With the introduction of cultivation, the
soil is broken and the natural vegetation is removed. Both of these
changes increase the potential for soil erosion. If measures are not
simultaneously introduced to counter these changes accelerated soil
erosion almost always follows. In Haiti, in response to both an
increasing population and limited access to the better agricultural
lands, peasants have continually needed to search for new lands to
cultivate. Most of the lands available for peasants were and are in
physical settings that from an agricultural perspective have a low
potential and high erosional risk if brought under continuous
cultivation. In past years a system of shifting cultivation and
fallowing of lands was a response to the degradation of the soil as a
result of agricultural activities.

Today, with the extreme scarcity of agricultural lands,
intensification of cultivation is necessary. There is not enough land
available for the individual farmers to continue practicing the
previous rotation of crops interdispersed with periods of fallow.
Almost no land remains fallow for a long enough period to restore soil
fertility to adequate levels. This results in lower yields and the
need to increase the proportion of land under cultivation just to meet
previous agricultural outputs. Also with lower yields, the vegetation
cover of the crops is reduced and the soil is less protected from
rainfall. Thus, with the continuous increase in the use of marginal
lands, erosion has been in an accelerated phase for a long period of
time. Today, the evidence indicates that the process continues
unabated. According to Ahmad (1977), Haiti is a classic example of
continuing severe land degradation, perhaps more than any other
country in the world. In the following sections we explore the
problems and processes of land degradation in general and
specifically, within the Haitian context, in the Cayes Plain Basin.

In the following sections basic concepts and methods of
measurements (assessment) are introduced. All the constructs and
indicies presented in this chapter contribute to an understanding of
the environmental situation as it exists, or could exist under
different conditions. The generation of numerical values for the









crucial variables of soil-loss, land capability, and moisture
availability provide the necessary background information to permit
rational planning decisions to be made. To meet the demands of this
SIP it was necessary to develop some primary data in order to
determine the viable options that exist for agriculture in the Cayes
Plain Basin. Even to meet the preliminary needs of this study, the
data base was so poor that it was necessary to estimate the primary
data in many cases. In the next phase of a coordinated rural regional
development project more information for constructing these indicies
will need to be provided if planners are to have sufficient
information available to make valid planning decisions.


3.2 EROSIONAL PROCESSES

This report only considers soil erosion resulting from water
since in Haiti it is clearly the dominant erosional agent. Erosion is
caused by the impact of raindrops on exposed soil and by runoff
causing sheet, rill, and gully erosion. In restricted Haitian
environmental settings, stream bank and sub-surface flow erosion are
important.

On cultivated lands six factors have been identified as the
crucial variables affecting the erosional rates on given parcels of
land. These are rainfall intensity and quantity, runoff, soil
erodibility, slope steepness, plant cover, and conservation
practices. Whether accelerated soil erosion occurs or not depends on
the balance between the energy, resistance, and protection factors.
Energy factors include the energy potential of rainfall and runoff to
initiate erosion (erosivity), the slope steepness, and the length of
the field. The resistance group is comprised of those properties of
these soil that resist erosion.

The resistance of the soil to erosion, called erodibility, is
determined by its physical, chemical, and organic composition. Soil
properties increasing water infiltration (decreasing runoff) decrease
erodibility; conversely factors decreasing infiltration such as
compaction, increase erodibility. Protection variables include
vegetation cover and conservation practices.

Soil erosion is a two-phase process. First, individual
particles of the soil need to be detached from the soil mass.
Raindrop impact on the soil is the most important agent initiating
soil detachment. It is only effective when bare soil is exposed to
the direct impact of the raindrop. Land clearing always increases the
effectiveness of this process. Once soil is detached, the second
process of transport in running water is required. Overland (runoff)
flow is the agent that transports the soil downslope and eventually to
the river system. When sufficient energy (velocity) is no longer
present to transport the soil particles in the runoff, deposition
occurs. From an agricultural perspective both excessive erosion and










deposition create situations that result in lower crop yields. In
Haiti, in areas under irrigation excessive deposition has historically
been a major problem.

With the clearing of the natural vegetation from most of Haiti's
land and the substitution of vegetation that does not protect the soil
to the same degree from raindrop impact, widespread accelerated
erosion exists. Change in vegetation cover, alone, has resulted in
major soil-loss on most agricultural lands. With erosion occurring
over a long period, the soil moisture retention as well as the soil
infiltration rates have decreased. This has increased the overall
proportion of rainfall that flows as runoff and concomittantly has
decreased ground water recharge. This results in larger storm flows
which increases the capacity of existing streams to transport
materials. Thus the initiation of accelerated erosion without
immediate counter efforts sets into motion a positive feedback
mechanism that makes eroding landscapes even more favorable for
further erosion.

Under these conditions erosion causes disastrous floods and
pseudo-droughts, those resulting from pedological not climatological
change, are created through the reduction of the water holding
capacity of soils, and the drying up of springs and river flow. This
leads to a continuing lowering of agricultural, grazing, and
silvacultural potential of the affected area. Because of the
deterioration in the environment resulting from erosion, it is easier
to prevent erosion than to reverse it once it has reached a major
intensity. Unfortunately in Haiti already a large proportion of its
lands are experiencing accelerated soil loss. However, in tnose few
upland areas where soil erosion has not become excessive, such as Les
Platons, immediate preventive actions will be less costly than waiting
until these areas reach the stage of the majority of today's Haitian
lands.

The five types of erosion are sheet and rill erosion, gully
erosion, streambank erosion and sub-surface flow erosion. Sheet
erosion is the removal of soil via unconcentrated overland flow. It
is the dominant form of soil-loss on gentle slopes (less than 4
percent).

Rill erosion begins to occur when the overland flow becomes
concentrated. This movement of water in flow streams results in the
formation of ephemeral local channels known as rills. In Western
Nigeria rills began to form on slopes greater than 4 percent, they
became the dominant erosional process on 15 percent slopes (Lewis,
1980). When sheet and rill erosion occur and land is cultivated for
the next planting season, manifestations of the erosion are not
readily visible. One intense storm or runoff from saturated soils may
remove 2 to 5 mm of soil in a few hours. On moderate or gentle
slopes, sheet and rill erosion remove the fine soil particles









resulting in a coarser soil texture. This residual soil material has
lower fertility and productive capacity. Worldwide, sheet and rill
erosion are the major form of erosion on agricultural lands.

Gully erosion is the next important form of erosion on a
worldwide basis, but where it exists, it is the most destructive phase
of water erosion. It is caused by the concentration of runoff from
extended areas. When both the volume and velocity of the water
becomes high enough, it gradually removes the soil material and
excavates a ditch. Unlike the rill, gullies are permanent steep-sided
channels. Like the rill, they only have discharges during and
immediately following a rain event. Almost always their presence
indicates accelerated erosion. When no engineering structures are
present, a gully always forms in the lower portion of a slope and
precedes upslope. Pathways in many rural settings result in the
initiation of gully formation. Today road building and associated
drainage diversion result in excessive runoff at specific points.
Under these conditions the gully is initiated at the road and rapidly
moves downslope. In Haiti where lands over 30 degrees are under
cultivation, gully erosion is a major widespread process that is
removing productive lands into the completely non-productive category.

Stream bank erosion occurs when riverbanks cave in due to the
undercutting of the river channel. It is a natural process associated
with the normal dynamics of river channel migration. However, it can
be associated with accelerated erosion in areas where the flow regime
of the river has been altered due to changes in the balance between
overland and groundwater flows. Where the overland flow component has
increased, the river channel must handle a larger discharge than
previously for the same flow frequency. This requires the river to
scour a larger channel resulting in riverbank collapse. In the
process, cropland juxtaposed to the river channel is lost.

Finally, subsurface erosion is important in areas where earth
materials permit concentrated flow in natural tunnels or pipes.
Limestone areas are one example of an environmental situation where
this can occur. In addition plant nutrients especially those added by
fertilizers, are removed by this process. This removal of soluble
minerals reduces a soil's resistance to erosion by reducing plant
growth and thereby reducing plant cover. Rarely is sub-surface
erosion accelerated by human interventions. When excessive fertilizer
losses occur they are usually the result of increased overland flows
not sub-surface erosion.


3.3 ESTIMATING SOIL-LOSS AND CLASSIFYING LAND CAPABILITY

The erosion rate for specific locations within a river basin is
determined by the interaction and magnitude of the numerous physical
and management variables at the sites. The Universal Soil Loss
Equation (USLE) is the most widely used model to evaluate erosional










conditions. It was originally developed to predict the long term
average soil losses resulting from sheet and rill erosion from
specific fields under specified cropping and management systems
(Wischimeier & Smith 1978). Recently it has been extended to be
applicable to noncrop land use as well as to estimating river basin
erosion and sedimentation delivery rates. The USLE is defined as:

Am = RK L S C P where

Am = Soil loss in metric tons per hectare per year

R = Runoff and Rainfall factor

K = Soil erodibility factor

L = Slope length factor

S = Slope factor an evaluation of the interaction
between slope length and steepness.

C = Crop and management factor

P = Conservation practices

Only the R factor is completely independent of human
interactions with the land resource. It is solely defined by the
precipitation characteristics of the area. The K factor, while
largely determined by the soil's structure and texture, can be altered
through interventions affecting the organic content of the soil.
Additionally agricultural practices such as the use of fire and
irrigation can alter the K value. Field length and slope angles can
be modified by boundary changes and morphology changes such as
terracing. Both the C and P factors for any parcel of land are
completely determined by human intervention. It can be seen clearly
from the variables identified as crucial in the USLE that soil erosion
rates can be strongly altered by the land use patterns established in
a given region.

One of the problems in applying the USLE to tropical areas is
that it is an empirically derived equation. It was formulated in the
U.S.A. where climate, soil types, and agricultural systems differ
markedly from most third world countries. Recently, research in some
tropical areas, mostly in Africa, have begun to develop numerical
values for many tropical settings (Roose 1977). For Haiti, as a
whole, little information is available at the required degree of
precision to apply the USLE. In particular rainfall records are too
sparse in areal coverage to determine the erosivity value, a crucial
input in determining the R value. Fortunately the p2/P ratio can be
calibrated and substituted for erosivity (Fournier 1960) where p is
the highest mean monthly rainfall and P is the annual mean rainfall.










Only in the upper portion of L'Acul River Basin does specific data
exist permitting the USLE to be applied (USDA SCS, 1983) (Figure
3.1) in Haiti without making major assumptions.

No widely acceptable methodologies comparable to the USLE exist
for predicting gully, streambank, and subsurface erosion. To
accurately assess these forms of erosion the need still exists to
measure them in the field or from large scale remotely sensed
information. For example, for planning purposes the erosional hazard
for gullying can be estimated directly from aerial photographs by
calculating simple indices such as gully density. Yet even this
simple method requires large scale and recent photographs. Unlike the
USLE, this approach cannot be used to simulate the gully hazard if
changes in the vegetation and conservation practices would be
planned. But it does permit the identification of hazard prone areas
if the frequency of gullies can be correlated to specific phenomena
such as slope steepness thresholds, paths, and road culverts.

The Land Capability Classification's (LCC) (Klingebiel and
Montgomery 1966) primary objective is to regionalize land units into
units of similar rural land use capability. When land is utilized
inappropriately either it is underutilized which results in less than
maximum economic return; or if it is overutilized, land degradation
will occur. In its assignment of land capability the LCC gives heavy
weight to the role of slope angle. Furthermore, it does not specify
the suitability of the land within each of its land classes for
particular crops. However, this can be inferred if the erosional
protection of the crops are known. The LCC delimits all lands into
one of eight classes sequentially ordered from Class I to Class VIII.
Class I includes all lands with little or no risk of soil erosion when
placed into cultivation. At the opposite end of the spectrum, Class
VIII can only be safely "utilized" in its natural state (Table 3.1).
Only classes I through IV are from an environmental perspective
suitable for cultivation. In Haiti, all classes nave been used for
cultivation at one time or another. This accounts for the rampant
erosion throughout the nation, which at its extreme results in exposed
bedrock. This misuse of the land, specifically placing lands in
cultivation that fall within higher classes (V-VIII), resulting from
land scarcity for the small farmer, is one major contributing factor
to land degradation.

In addition to the prime designation of land into eight major
classes, capability subclasses are formed by adding an additional e,
w, or s to the Roman Numerals. The letter e indicates that erosion
risk is the major limiting land use factor; w indicates poor drainage
or a high water table affects plant growth; and s specifies that the
shallow nature of the soil is the prime limiting factor. In Haiti,
the s sub-category has been increasing due to its ongoing erosional
problem. As a result, the Haitian land resource is continuously
decreasing in terms of its production potential and lands previously
in the lower classes have today moved into higher categories.















L'ACUL RIVER BASIN


LEGEND

-- Cayes Plain Basin

L'Acul River Basin

------ L'Acul Divide Subsurface


River
-- Ravine


i..i::iii USDA/SCS L'Acul Watershed


Les Caye,


FIGURE 3.1










TABLE 3.1


CLASS CHARACTERISTICS AND RECOMMENDED LANDUSE

I Deep, productive soils, easily worked, on nearly level
land; not subject to overland flow; no or slight risk of
damage when cultivated; use of fertilizers and lime, cover
crops, crop rotations required to maintain soil fertility
and soil structure.

II Productive soils on gentle slopes; moderate depth; subject
to occasional overland flow; may require drainage;
moderate risk of damage when cultivated; use crop
rotations, water-control systems or special tillage
practices to control erosion.

III Soils of moderate fertility on moderately steep slopes,
subject to more severe erosion; subject to severe risk of
damage but can be used for crops provided adequate plant
cover is maintained; hay or other sod crops should be
grown instead of row crops.

IV Good soils on steep slopes, subject to severe erosion;
very severe risk of damage but may be cultivated
occasionally if handled with great care; keep in hay or
pasture but a grain crop may be grown once in five or six
years.

V Land is too wet or stony for cultivation but of nearly
level slope; subject to only slight erosion if properly
managed; should be used for pasture or forestry but
grazing should be regulated to prevent plant cover from
being destroyed.

VI Shallow soils on steep slopes; use of grazing and
forestry; grazing should be regulated to preserve plant
cover; if the plant cover is destroyed, use should be
restricted until cover is re-established.

VII Steep, rough, eroded land with shallow soils; also
includes drought and swampy land; severe risk of damage
even when used for pasture or forestry; strict grazing or
forest management must be applied.

VIII Very rough land; not suitable even for woodland or
grazing; reserve for wildlife, recreation or watershed
conservation.


Classes I-IV denote soils suitable for cultivation.
Classes V-VIII denote soils unsuitable for cultivation.


LCC Klingebiel & Montgomery 1966










Since all slopes greater than 70 fall outside lands suitable
for cultivation, the LCC is probably too restrictive in countries when
manual labor and not machinery is the major method of farming. In
addition modifications in the LCC for tropical areas is warranted
since generally tropical soils have greater concentrations of iron and
aluminum oxides than mid-latitude soils. This gives them a lower
erodibility than soils of similar texture and structure permitting
their rational utilization on steeper slopes. Nevertheless, the
methodology for classification as presented in the LCC is a useful
planning device as it clearly gives a basis for assessing the relative
erosional risks of tracts of land for agriculture, grazing and
silvaculture.

Figure 3.2 illustrates the sequence for assigning units of land
into their appropriate class. The LCC is especially pertinent to the
Haitian situation given the dominant role of agriculture in the
employment and economy of the country. It can, as a first
approximation, rapidly determine current land use that is out of
harmony with the physical environment. As such it is a useful tool
for deciding which areas should be targeted into a priority action
designation in order to arrest a region's erosional rates.


3.4 THE PHYSICAL/ENVIRONMENTAL CONTEXT OF L'ACUL RIVER BASIN

3.4.1 Discharge Characteristics

L'Acul River Basin, occupying approximately 30 percent of the
Cayes Plain Basin, is 230 square kilometers in area. L'Acul is
situated along the western margin of the Cayes Plain Basin with its
major river axis oriented from the northwest toward the southeast. In
terms of catchment area, L'Acul Basin is the tenth largest Haitian
river basin (Figure 3.3). The total length of the major stream
segment (Ravine and River Acul) is 34.9 km. With the exception of the
Ravine Caiman all of the headwaters in the basin are intermittent
during a portion of the dry season.

River discharge properties are determined by a complex set of
variables all interacting simultaneously Among the primary variables
affecting discharge are the temperature and rainfall attributes, the
local geology, the topography, the shape of the basin, the vegetation
cover and the soil. Because of the complexity of the interactions
that determine the discharge of a river system, the only accurate
method of obtaining this information is by direct measurements. For
the Cayes Plain Basin as a whole, no continuous stream flow data exist
since 1935 (Harza 1979, p. B-ll-4). In L'Acul only one published
figure exists using only one year for measurement, published by
Sheladia Associates (1983). Given this paucity of hydrologic data it
is only possible to crudely estimate that L'Acul's mean annual
discharge at its mouth falls within the range of 2.5 5 m3/sec.
Given the elongated shape of the basin, which should result in an
extreme stream regime having brief periods of large peak discharges















SEQUENCE OF ASSIGNING CLASSES TO LAND SUITABLE

FOR CULTIVATION
THE L C C

0-10 (1)



AX BC DEFG (2)

50 38 25 50 38 25 100 50 38 25 (3)


75 125 150 125 150 25 125 125 75 125 125 (4)

I I I5 I 12 I I I2
III II III III IV IV III II III IV III I II III IV (5)



1-2.5 (1)




AX BC DEFG (2)

50 38 25 50 38 25 50 38 25 (3)

7 125 150 75 125 150 75 125 (4)
I I I f I I I I
III III III IV IV III II III IV III II III IV (5)

2.5 4.50 4.5 70 (1)
AX BC DEFG BC DEFG (2)
I A A
50-25 38 25 25 (3)
1 I I I 1
IV III IV III IV IV (5)
A= SAND X= LOAMY SAND B- SANDY LOAM C= SANDY CLAY D- CLAY LOAM
E- SANDY CLAY F- CLAY
(1)= Slope of land (2)= Topsoil Texture (3)= Effective Soil Depth (CM)
(4)= Permeability of Upper Subsoil (B Horizon) (5)= Class

Figure 3.2















TERRAIN CHACTERISTICS

L'ACUL RIVER BASIN


TERRAIN


I Igneou

I II Plateau

jl III Slopes

El IV Flat Lo


s Highlands


lands


Les Ca,


FIGURE 3.3










after periods of rainfall, the steep slopes in the upper and middle
portions of the basin, the removal of the tree cover, and the thin to
bare rock soil cover in large areas of the basin, L'Acul River and all
of its tributaries must have periods when they flow as raging torrents
with discharge far in excess of their mean flow. The presence of
bedload material over one-half meter in diameter in most of the basins
streams attests to the large velocities experienced during the peak
flows. The general absence of finer materials in the river beds
indicates the highly erosive nature of the river flows in the River
Basin. In order to maximize the water resources of L'Acul Basin,
strategies to dampen the extreme nature of today's river discharges
need to be undertaken. By lowering the peak discharges larger
quantities of water will be available for utilization, especially in
the flat lowlands. Today, during the peak flows, a large percentage
of the basins' waters pass through the system and empty into the
Caribbean without being utilized either for irrigation or potable
water supply.

3.4.2 Topography

Using lithologic, slope inclination, and elevation criteria,
L'Acul River Basin can be divided into four major topographic units.
These units differ both in their erosional and agricultural
potential. Because the environmental interaction between these units
is relative to the dynamics of L'Acul river system, the proper
management of these topographic units will both improve their in situ
environmental characteristics as well as improve the lands beyond each
of the units. It is this latter characteristic that necessitates the
need to co-ordinate land use activities within all of the basin's
topographic units if the basin's soil and water resources are to be
used in the most rational manner.

On Figure 3.3 the four major topographic units are delimited.
The greatest relief and highest elevations within the basin are found
in the Igneous Highland Unit. This unit comprizes a little less than
one percent of the basin or approximately 3 square kilometers (Table
3.2). Elevations in this unit range from 1200 to 2170 meters above

Table 3.2


L'Acul River Basin Topographic Units
Name Percentage Area (km 2)

Igneous Highlands 1 3
Platons 6 16
Slopes 68 156
Flat Lowlands 25 55

100 230










sea level. Local relief is 800 meters. It is an area of steep slopes
with no flat lands. The northern limit of this unit forms the river
divide between those streams flowing southward toward the Caribbean
and those flowing northward toward the Atlantic Ocean near Jeremie.
The Platons is an area characterized overall as a gently rolling
plateau with periodic abrupt limestone hills rising from this rolling
terrain. The plateau's surface has a regional dip from the northwest
to the southeast. This dip is manifested in the units' elevation
which ranges from 1200 meters in the northwest and systematically
decreases to 600 meters in the southeast. The underlying lithology
of the whole unit is limestone. Because of this rock's permeability
and solution weathering properties, the presence of surface water
runoff is limited. Most of the area's drainage is underground. The
surface runoff flows to the numerous depressions that pock the terrain
in short blind valleys. These depressions, known as sinkholes, serve
as local collectors of the water runoff. These sinkholes are the
major groundwater recharge areas. It appears that the groundwater
flow in Les Platons is from the northwest toward the southeast with
the greatest outflow emerging at the Tete L'Acul in the lower slope
unit. Because most of the water from precipitation in this area flows
underground and not on the surface in an integrated river network, a
common phenomena in limestone areas, the surface drainage divide on
Les Platons is relatively meaningless. The crucial hydrologic divide
in this unit is determined by the regional dip of the limestone. For
this reason, the Sousbois area in the northwestern portion of Les
Platons Unit is included in L'Acul River Basin even though it lies
just outside of the topographic divide. All indications are that the
groundwater in the vicinity of Sousbois flows toward the southeast and
enters L'Acul River System. In its transition to the slope
topographic unit, the Platons margins are bounded with steep rocky
slopes, in many places greater than 500. These margins are
dissected in many places by short but deep ravines. These margins are
either occupied by rapidly eroding farmlands, or abandoned fields.

The slope topographic unit makes up 68 percent of L'Acul River
Basin. This is the archetypical landscape of Haiti. It is a
hodge-podge of fluvially eroded valleys resulting in a complex
dissected surface. It is comprised of numerous hills having moderate
to steep slopes and narrow-valley bottoms. It is an area where very
little flat land is to be seen, and where it exists, it is normally
found on the valley bottoms which are susceptible to frequent flash
flooding. Within L'Acul River Basin the dominant underlying rocks are
either of igneous origin or within the family of rocks comprised of
calcium carbonates (OEA, 1972). Slopes range anywhere from 10 to 60
degrees and local relief is between 100 to 200 meters.

The flat lowlands, which are part of the Cayes Plain are an area
of low relief and low slopes. The regional dip is from the north to
the south. Along the slope unit-flat lowland boundary the elevation
of the plain is about 100 meters. From these margins it slopes
seaward at relatively uniform rates. The underlying material of the
lowlands is primarily alluvium. Being extremely permeable, much of










the runoff flowing from the slope unit infiltrates beneath the
lowlands surface. As such a large reservoir of untapped groundwater
likely exists throughout these lowlands. The numerous streams that
emerge at springs on the lowlands gives clear evidence of the large
groundwater reservoir existing under this unit.

3.4.3 Climate

Only one meteorological station exists within L'Acul River
Basin. This is at Dubreuil, and this station was only established in
August, 1979. Therefore, no long term rainfall records exist in in
the area. Within the whole of the Cayes Plain Basin, stations are
located only at Les Cayes, Gerard (Torbeck), Levy Farm, Chantal, and
Camp Perrin. Therefore no actual climatological data exist for the
slope, Platons, and Igneous Highlands within L'Acul River Basin. That
is, for the whole of the Cayes Plain Basin actual data only exist for
the flat lowlands. As a result all statements concerning the upland
areas are based on inference using the roles of elevation, topographic
orientation, and distance from the ocean in determining the
temperature and precipitation values of these areas. It is from these
inferred values that the crucial climatological properties for
agricultural production in the upland areas such as
evapo-transpiration rates are derived.

The minimum rainfall in L'Acul and the Cayes Plain Basin is
along the coastline. In this area the annual rainfall is
approximately 2000 mm (Les Cayes 2035 mm). Moving inland, rainfall
gradually increases on the lowlands (Chantal 2464 mm; Camp Perrin 2272
mm). By extrapolating annual precipitation from the National
Meteorological Service's average annual precipitation map, rainfall in
the upper reaches of the slope unit and Platons must range between
2400 and 2800 mm per year. Along the upper margins of the highlands
precipitation likely over 3000 mm. A humid climate is found
throughout the whole basin. The lowlands have a definite wet-dry
season regime. As you move inland, the elevation rises and the
climate becomes ever more humid until you reach the Igneous Highlands
that experience only a very short dry season. This overall humid
climate, along with the dry seasons, makes the area have very
favorable moisture conditions for agriculture, forestry and livestock
production.

With the average annual temperature at Les Cayes 25.80 C
(elev. 5 m), Chantal 26.10 (elev. 40 m), and Camp Perrin 24.90
(elev. 230 m), we can assume the mean annual temperature at Le Pretre
(180 m) is approximately 25.40 C, at the Citadelle des Platons (680
m) 22.00 C, and at Sousbois (920 m) 20.70 C (Figure 3.3). These
figures are derived assuming the average environmental lapse rate in
the area is 0.60 C per 100 meters, the average rate for the
troposphere. The highest monthly temperature for the lowlands is
about 27.50 C in July and 22.40 C at Sousbois. The lowest mean
annual temperature on the lowlands is about 24.00 C (Jan) and
18.10 C on the Platons.










From an agricultural point of view, these raw temperature and
rainfall figures need to be used to derive the evapo-transpiration
rates and the moisture balance for the Cayes Plain Basin. Given that
no areas of below freezing temperatures exists in the whole basin, it
is the moisture balance that determines the growing season for all
rainfed vegetation. It is the deficit between potential
evapo-transpiration and precipitation that determines the amount of
water needed in areas undergoing irrigation. Using the methodology
developed by Hargreaves and Samani (April, 1983), the moisture
availability index (MAI) is approximated for Le Pritre, the Citadelle,
and Sousbois. Their published MAI values are used for Les Cayes, Camp
Perrin, and Chantal (Hargreaves and Samani, 1983, pp. A-19, A-21,
A-43).

The MAI is a particularly useful agroclimatological index for
planning purposes in that it is an index of relative rainfall
adequacy. It is defined as:

MAI= P D
ETP

where PD is the 75 percent probability of precipitation (monthly) and
ETP is the monthly potential evapo-transpiration. An MAI value of
0.33 or less for one month is considered a danger signal in rainfed
agriculture. At this level, production most likely will drop below an
economical level. This is especially true if it occurs before the
plant has reached its critical growth stage. If the MAI value is less
than 0.50 for the growing season, the use of fertilizers is not
considered economical since not enough moisture exists to allow the
fertilizer to become soluble and then be utilized in plant growth.
The MAI value, since it detects moisture deficiencies is useful as a
planning guide for irrigated areas too. Conversely, a high monthly
MAI index, over 1.20, generally indicates a need for drainage as water
logging will occur unless the soils are extremely permeable. Given
the poor moisture retention of many Haitian soils because of their
degraded state, these high MAI values probably only indicate drainage
problems along valley bottom lands and other flat lowlands. In fact,
it is probably only during periods of high MAI values ( 0.75) that
most soils have enough moisture storage as to prevent moisture stress
from occurring.

Table 3.3 lists the published MAI values for Les Cayes, Camp
Perrin, and Chantal. The estimated values for Le P8tre, the
Citadelle, and Sousbois are also given. These values were derived by
estimating the monthly temperature and rainfall of these locations
using available data. The probability distribution of this rainfall
was assumed to be similar to the closest published station in the
Hargreaves and Samani report. Using their computation method the MAI
values for these three sites were then derived. A brief inspection of
Table 3.3 indicates that all of the Cayes Plain Basin, from a moisture
balance perspective, is a good agricultural region.















TABLE 3.3


MONTHLY MOISTURE AVAILABILITY INDEX FOR L'ACUL RIVER BASIN


STATIO_ i.JAI FEB F MAR _APR M.. AY JUNE. JULY AUG SEPT OCT NOV DEC ANNUAL .AIUAL P.I-L .
-. -- ------ .-------- -- ---- -----

a.-irnrrin 0.30 0.28 0.39 0.74 1.17 0.66 0.45 0.64 1.11 1.65 0.86 0.18 1.15 2272

Chantal 0.25 0.45 0.46 0.95 1.56 0.90 0.57 0.76 1.59 1.55 0.25 0.25 1.14 2.64

Les Cayes 0.36 0.45 0.33 0.82 1.36 0.76 0.63 0.90 1.08 1.57 0.74 0.18 1.20 2035

"itadell 0.37 0.51 0.57 1.03 1.71 0.92 0.71 0.9 1.72 1.66 0.87 0.36 1.41 2670

Le Prtre 0.34 0.44 0.51 1.00 1.44 0.94 0.61 0.83 1.49 1.57 0.37 0.35 1.23 2510

Sousbois 0.44 0.52 0.58 1.03 1.80 0.94 0.76 0.99 1.83 1.64 0.86 0.35 1.44 2675



= Estimated Values


Derived Using Methodology Explained in
HARGREAVES and SAMANI, 1983










At Camp Perrin December through March are relatively dry, while
at the opposite extreme, Sousbois only appears to have a moisture
problem in December. The flat lowlands and the lower elevations in
the slope unit fall within a climatic zone having a rainy season
between seven to nine months with either two or three months of
excessive rainfall. The upper slopes, Platons, and Igneous Highland
Units appear to have a ten month rainy period, with only December and
January having really dry periods. From the consideration of rainfall
inputs, the whole Cayes Plain Basin appears to be one of the most
favorable locales in all of Haiti.

The extreme apparent moisture conditions inferred from Table 3.2
need to be tempered due to local soil conditions and microclimatic
properties that are widespread throughout the basin, excepting the
flat lowlands. First, visual impressions of the vegetation throughout
the Platons seem to indicate that its soil moisture availability is
not as high as in the slope valley bottom areas such as Le Pretre.
Most likely this reflects the higher permeability rates on the Platons
due to its limestone geology (Wooding, etal, 1924). Therefore Table
3.3 most likely overestimates the available moisture in the Platons
(Citadelle and Sousbois). Second, the thin nature of the soil
throughout most of the slope unit means that despite the favorable
macro-moisture conditions, the residual soil moisture storage capacity
of the soils is low. Thus, despite no moisture stress being indicated
for most of the year, in actuality pseudo-drought conditions could
exist whenever rain events do not occur over a two-week period.
Evidence for this inference is manifested by the extreme difference in
the quality of vegetation between the east and west facing slopes
throughout the whole slope unit. In all cases the west facing slopes
had a lower quality of vegetation than the east facing slopes. This
probably reflects the microclimatic differences resulting from the
temporal pattern of exposure to sunlight and the slope's low soil
moisture retention capacity.

The east facing slopes have a more favorable micro-climatic
environment than the west facing slopes, all other factors held
constant. This is due to the presence of ground moisture (dew) being
present when the sun shines on the east facing slopes during the
morning period. The evaporation of the ground moisture and dew from
the.plant leaves prevents the temperatures, both ground and plant,
from becoming excessive. Thus the plants for a given quantity of
solar insolation do not transpire as much water. However, by the time
the sunlight strikes the west facing slopes (noon and afternoon) this
ground moisture has been evaporated. Therefore the incoming solar
insolation raises the ground and plant temperatures to a greater
degree requiring the plant to place heavier demands on the soil
moisture. Simply put, the east facing slopes are more humid than the
west facing slopes. This allows a greater plant density to exist on
the west slopes, with the result that the soil has been better
protected through the years. In fact, almost all areas having bedrock
exposed on the surface in L'Acul River Basin are on west facing
slopes. Throughout L'Acul River Basin, the east slopes have been










severely degraded. The existing thin soils cannot store enough
moisture and plants undergo moisture stress despite MAI values far in
excess of 0.33. Most of the fields on these slopes have been already
abandoned.

3.4.4 Soils

According to the DATPE classification of soil potential (1982)
the Cayes Plain Basin has some of the highest potential soils in Haiti
(Figure 3.4). Conversely, it also has areas with no agricultural
potential. In general the soils having the highest potential are
found solely on the flat low lands; the lowest potential soils are
found in the Igneous Highlands and Slope Units; and good to average
soils are found on the Platons. On the basis of the DATPE
classification, the majority of the slopes unit lands should be solely
in forest and where agriculture is practiced, major soil conservation
practices should be in place. In reality, most of the lands in the
slope unit are in cultivation and little soil conservation practices
are in place. Already, as mentioned in the climate section, the west
facing slopes in many areas are devoid of soil. This has been the
product of a large number of years of misuse. In the upper portion of
the Ravine Des Mornes, the Ravine Caiman and on the margins of the
Platons, lands in excess of 450 are being used for sorghum and sweet
potatoes. Clear physical evidence on these fields, such as large
rocks, point to rapid erosion.

The detailed soil mapping done by the USDA-SCS in the upper Acul
Basin indicates that no Class I soils exist within the upper Acul
(USDA-SCS, June 1983 p. 13). Only 9.4 percent of the upper Acul Basin
according to the LCC classification should be placed in cultivation
(Table 3.4). Yet, over 45 percent is in cropland and another 18
percent is periodically cultivated. This overutilization of marginal
soils is widespread throughout the Slope and Igneous Mountain Units.

TABLE 3.4

Soil Classes of Upper Acul


LCC Percent of Total Area

A. II 0.13
III 1.7
IV 7.6


B. V 1.9
VI 16.1
VII 68.3
VIII (Wasteland) 4.2


Modified from USDA-SCS June, 1983 P. 14















AGRICULTURAL POTENTIAL


Distribution of Soils
in Cayes Plain Basin

IIII Good to Excellent
Average

Poorly Drained, Limited to Rice Culture

W limited Potential

Modified from Datpe-Potentialitee Des Soils, 1982


pA 'C-










It implies that within L'Acul River Basin active land degradation is
occurring which is lowering the lands' potential both in the eroded
areas and on the flat lands where excessive soil is deposited.

3.5 SYNTHESIS

The Cayes Plain Basin, specifically L'Acul River Basin,
possesses many physical properties that are common throughout most of
Haiti. The utilization of the lands within the area likewise presents
a potpourri of conditions typical of the rural countryside. A limited
resource base is and has been stressed over a long period by an ever
growing population pressure resulting in a degrading environmental
situation. This ongoing process must be arrested quickly, otherwise a
large portion of the productive lands will cease to able to be
profitable.

The highest potential lands are the relatively limited flat
lands concentrated within the Cayes Plain and the Platons. Neither of
these areas are producing their potential agricultural yields. In
both cases, if more water were available for irrigation, farming
practices improved, and selected crop substitution occurred, yields
and income could be increased. To increase the hydrologic potential
of the Cayes Plain Basin, a set of actions need to be undertaken that
will alter existing land use and farming practices throughout all of
the interconnected topographic units comprising the area. The
Highlands, Platons, Slopes, and Lowlands all interact with each other
in terms of their physical properties. The co-ordinated strategy as
well as possible interventions required to improve the physical
setting of the area for rural regional basin development is found in
Chapters seven and eight.

Given the information presented in this chapter, three crucial
changes that this strategy must accomplish are:

1. Arrest the pervasive soil erosion occurring in the slope and
highland units;

2. Improve the quantity and availability of water in the Platons
and Lowland units; and

3. Alter the existing farming practices to introduce different land
use and conservation practices to increase the profitability of
the small farmers.










CHAPTER 4


MARKET STRUCTURE


4.1 INTRODUCTION

Marketing is a process which coordinates the exchange of
resources, goods, and services over time and space. This process
represents the direct interaction of supply and demand and is the sine
qua non of any but the most rudimentary economic system. The unit
value of the resource, good or service exchanged should reflect its
marginal cost of supply to the seller and its marginal value to the
buyer. If this mechanism is inefficient or costly, scarce resources
will tend to be misallocated and the marketing process becomes a
constraint to economic growth. Conversely, the efficient operation of
this mechanism will ensure a satisfactory (if not optimal) allocation
of resources among society and will create the potential for improved
economic performance.

The purpose of this chapter is to describe and to analyze the
market structure of L'Acul River Basin 1: to identify the location
of the markets in time and space; to delineate both the functional
hierarchy of this market system and the nature of the commodity flows
between markets; to examine spatial and temporal price variations
between markets; and, finally, to examine the constraints to, and
opportunities for, development.associated with this market system.
Before undertaking this detailed analysis of marketing in L'Acul River
Basin, section 4.2 considers some general issues and approaches
relevant to the internal marketing system of Haiti. Note that the
focus of this chapter is the internal (i.e. intraregional or
interregional) market for food stuffs and household articles. Export
commodities such as coffee, sisal, and vetiver are marketed through
independent systems which are quite different from the former in both
form and function; these systems are beyond the scope of the present
inquiry.

4.2 THE HAITIAN INTERNAL MARKETING SYSTEM: ISSUES AND APPROACHES

Over the past two decades a fairly sizeable literature on Haiti's
internal marketing system has developed. This literature covers a
spectrum of issues and approaches. The purpose of this section is to
explore the nature and range of topics examined before moving on to a
substantive analysis of L'Acul River Basin.


1Although this study focuses upon L'Acul River Basin, the
marketing system of the basin is broadly defined to include
functionally related markets within the broader Cayes Plain Basin.














LaGra, Fanfan, and Charleston (1975) have produced a fairly
comprehensive enumeration of 519 public markets throughout Haiti. For
each market they identify its location, principal day(s) of
functioning, type of construction, approximate size, principal modes
of transportation, origins of motorized transport, and the state of
the roads leading to the market. In addition, they develop and apply
a three-level typology of markets: semi-rural markets, which serve
local producers and consumers, as well as some Madame Sarahs
(traveling intermediaries that assemble and break bulk and transport
goods between regions); regional markets, which are assembly points
characterized by a variety and abundance of products, and which serve
as principal points of exchange between producers and Madame Sarahs;
and urban markets, large commercial centers in which exchange occurs
through several levels of intermediaries. Note that a regional market
may function as a semi-rural market (i.e., with a lower range and
quantity of goods, with a smaller number of buyers and sellers, and
exclusively for a local market) on certain days of the week. LaGra et
al argue that the prices in both semi-rural and regional markets
reflect prices paid at the producer-level; urban markets are
characterized by higher prices than the other two types, due to
transportation costs and the number of intermediaries involved.

A number of other authors have developed similar typologies.
These are summarized in Table 4.1. The most utilized of these
typologies is that of Mintz (1960b) who identifies the following four
market types: 1) strategic marketplaces which play a central role
with respect to the entire market system, serving as bulking and
break-bulk points for interregional trades; 2) "captured" town
marketplaces in which shops dominate the market and which provision
local middle-class merchants; 3) mixed marketplaces, local markets
with associated subsidiary trading activities such that its
relationship to the outside is not as unilateral in character as a
local market; and 4) local marketplaces which are outlets for consumer
goods via local exchange (and which may also be a strategic
marketplace on one of its non-principal days). The other typologies
presented are self-explanatory; perhaps the only one requiring comment
is that used by the Institut Francais d'Haiti. The type 1, 2, and 3
markets are based upon the role of Madame Sarahs from Port-au-Prince,
indicating respectively: 1) direct interaction between Port-au-Prince
Madame Sarahs and producers; 2) interaction between local revendeuses
and producers; and 3) interaction between Port-au-Prince Madame Sarahs
and revendeuses. A type 4 market is also implied but not observed in










the study area; this corresponds to the "urban market" of LaGra et al
(1975). It should also be noted that Le Bureau des Contributions
employs the simple distinction of the urban market, which takes place
in a center in which a communal magistrate resides, and the rural
market, which is located in a section rural.






TABLE 4.1



Typologies of Haitian Markets


l(hiqhest)


LaGra et'al (1975)


Mintz (1960b)

Moral (1959)

Wood (1963)


Johnson (1970)



Institute Francais
d'Haiti (1980)


Urban


Strategic

Sea Cost


Port

Port


Type 4


Regional


Captured Town


Regional


Mixed


Town


Interregional

Major inland
Assembly and
wholesale


Type 3


Type 2


4 (lowest)


Semi-rural

Local


Local


Intraregional


Local



Type 1


After Lundahl (1980)


Author









A second major issue evident in the marketing literature on
Haiti involves the extent to which the market system is characterized
by perfect competition and efficiency, as opposed to imperfect
competition, inefficiency, and exploitation of the peasant consumers.
Moral (1959) was one of the first authors to argue that Haiti's
internal market system operates under imperfect competition with the
end result that the peasants are victimized. Jaffe (1983) describes
the market system as monopolistic-monopsonistic in its process of
price determination. The lack of competition is responsible for a
dendritic market structure which abets economic stagnation. Johnson
(1970) takes a similar view with regard to both the dendritic
structure and its consequences. Opposing views are taken by a number
of authors. Johnson and LaGra (1975) found price variation
characteristic of imperfect competition between geographic areas but
not between markets within the same area; transport costs between
areas seem to account for what variations do exist. Mintz (1964),
citing a high level of competition between market intermediaries,
concludes that the system is free from exploitation. The level of
market services may be low but society pays a low cost for them. A
large number of participants is substituted for a high level of
productivity. Lundahl (1980) characterizes the market system as
dendritic ("vertical" in his terminology) but argues (1983) that it is
relatively efficient and that there is relatively little exploitation
of the peasants by middlemen; no monopsony can be detected and prices
are set by the interaction of supply and demand.

Two further related issues involve levels of price variation
between markets and the distribution of profits among market
participants. As noted above, Johnson and LaGra'(1975), using average
monthly prices for 6 commodities over 37 markets for the period
1971-1974 found significant levels of price variation between
geographic areas but did not detect significant variation by market
type within a geographic area. Lundahl (1983), using 1969-1974
average monthly price data collected for regional markets by the
Inter-American Institute for Agricultural Sciences, found some degree
of price variation beyond the expected differences caused by
transportation and processing. With regard to the distribution of
profits among market participants, Murray and Alvarez (1973) found a
25 percent mark-up between the price paid to the producer and that
paid by the final consumer; Madame Sarahs gained, on average, a 10
percent profit on their role as intermediary. Lundahl (1983)
estimates that both revendeuses and Madame Sarahs make a profit of 10
- 20 percent on their transactions, but notes that the margin is, in
fact, somewhat less since the cost of their labor is not taken into
account. L'Institut Francais d'Haiti (1980) arrives at the following
ranges in relation to the allocation of final selling price:
producers, 45-78 percent (mean = 61 percent); Madame Sarah, 18-48
percent (mean = 31 percent); transportation, 1-24 percent (mean = 7
percent); depot operators, 0.1 4.4 percent (mean = 1 percent).










A detailed analysis of the roles of various actors in the
marketing process has been made by a number of authors. The
Inter-American Institute for Agricultural Sciences (1974) presents an
overview of the various types of producers, consumers, and middlemen.
Murray and Alvarez (1973) focus upon the role of the Madame Sarah, and
Mintz (1960a; 1960b; 1964) presents a detailed account of the
functioning of both Madame Sarahs and revendeuses.

Other approaches have examined the marketing of individual
commodities. Murray and Alvarez (1973) have focused upon beans;
Sorenson and Chung (1973) upon corn, rice, and millet; and Roe (1978)
upon a variety of grains, vegetables, and fruits.

Finally, Rouzier (1981) has used the structure of the Haitian
marketing system (both internal and international) as an example in
the context of his theoretical micro-econometric discussion of
international and interregional trade flows. Rouzier's principal
purpose is the development of an abstract conceptual framework and
his discussion contains little substantive information about marketing
in Haiti.


4.3 THE MARKET STRUCTURE OF L'ACUL RIVER BASIN

In the following sections an examination of the marketing system
of the study area is undertaken in light of some of the major issues
and approaches that have been raised in the literature. By gaining an
understanding of the manner in which this system functions it becomes
possible to assess its potentialities for enhancing the development
process in L'Acul River Basin. Unless otherwise noted, the following
observations are based upon this Study Team's field work, undertaken
in L'Acul River Basin between November 15 and 29, 1983.

4.3.1 MARKET LOCATION IN TIME AND SPACE

Thirteen markets in L'Acul River Basin, as broadly defined
above, were examined. The location of these markets and the routes
connecting them are shown in Figure 4.1; their location in time is
presented in Table 4.2. Tuesday is the most significant marKet day in
L'Acul River Basin; the Study Team was told repeatedly and in various
locations that Tuesday is the market day of the "professionals",
meaning the Madame Sarahs and the revendeuses. This statement also
reflects the central role of the Ducis market in provisioning other
markets in the area. This will be discussed below.

Figure 4.2 combines the spatial and temporal dimensions of the
market system. A definite regionalization of principal market days
may be observed. Taken together, there is a temporal complementarity
among the larger markets, i.e. Ducis meets on Tuesday, Cayes on
Wednesday; Chantal on Friday. This permits a maximum flow of goods
and intermediaries between these major markets. Table 4.3 presents
additional information about each market: Type of infrastructure,










TABLE 4.2

Market Days, L'Acul River Basin


Market Principal Day(s) Secondary Day(s)


Arniquet Monday Thursday

Carrefour Valbre Monday Thursday

Ducis Tuesday Friday

Canon Tuesday Friday

Le Pretre Tuesday Friday*

Caiman Tuesday Friday*

Platons Tuesday All Days
Except Sunday

Cayes Wednesday Saturday

Chantal Friday

Camp Perrin Friday Monday

Sousbois Saturday Thursday

Carrefour Joute Saturday Wednesday

Torbeck Every Day


*Market also functions in a reduced capacity every other day of the
week except Sunday.
















MARKET LOCATIONS

L'ACUL BASIN

MARKETING SYSTEM


Sousbois,


Camp


S MARKETS

ROADS

POOR ROADS

FOURWHEEL DRIVE ROADS


CAYES PLAIN BASIN

L'ACUL RIVER BASIN

------ L'ACUL DIVIDE SUBSURFACE


FIGURE 4.1













SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL

DIMENSIONS

L'ACUL BASIN

MARKETING SYSTEM


Sousbois.e


Camp Perrin o


MARKET
M T w PRINCIPLE MARKET DAYS
F S E (E Everyday)


CAYES PLAIN BASIN

L'ACUL RIVER BASIN

-------- L'ACUL DIVIDE SUBSURFACE


Torbeck
0


A- 6S.















Infrastructure


Table 4.3
Market Characteristics


No. of Modes of
vendors transportation


Index of
road conditions*


Arniquet 120 permanent 150 Foot, animal truck 25
tin & straw
tonnelles

Carrefour 38 permanent 50 Foot, animal truck 25
Valere tin & straw
tonnelles

Ducis 200 permanent tin 300 Foot, animal truck 25
& straw tonnelles

Canon 15 Foot, animal 8.5

Le Pretre 8 permanent 30 Foot, animal 7.5
straw
tonnelles

Caiman 4 permanent 20 Foot, animal 3.5
tonnelles

Platons 15 Foot, animal 3.5

Cayes Permanent 300 Foot, car, truck 40
semi covered
building

Chantal 200 permanent tin 300 Foot, animal, truck 25
& straw tonnelles

Camp Perrin 100 permanent tin 120 Foot, animal, truck 30
& straw tonnelles

Sousbois 35 permanent straw 50 Foot, animal 3.0**
tonnelles

Carrefour 8 permanent tin 100 Foot, animal, truck 25
Joute & straw tonnelles

Torbeck 13 permanent tin 20 Foot, animal, truck 30
& straw tonnelles

*Defined as a "safe" speed in a four wheel drive vehicle, miles per hour.

**Represents walking speed; inaccessible to vehicles.


Market









approximate number of vendors, principal modes of transportation, and
an index of road condition for access roads.

4.3.2 MARKET HIERARCHY

Marketing systems consist of interrelated individual elements
which may be distinguished from one another on the basis of the
function that each provides in the context of the entire system.
These functions are expressed in terms of level in the hierarchical
system of markets. Such systems are conventionally analyzed within
the framework of central place theory. In the present study the
central place approach is employed as a frame of reference; as will be
seen subsequently, the divergence of L'Acul River Basin system from
central place theory is more striking than any similarity. Central
place theory is based upon six propositions:

1. There exists a hierarchical set of markets which are distinguished
from one another on the basis of the range of goods and services that
each provides. Higher level centers (markets) exhibit all of the
goods and services available at lower level centers, plus a set of
goods and services that the lower level centers do not provide.

2. Higher order goods and services require a higher population
concentration to support them than do lower order goods and services.
This is referred to as the threshold of a good.

3. In order to achieve the higher threshold required, higher order
centers are characterized by a larger range than are lower order
centers. That is to say, higher order centers have more extensive
market areas associated with them than do lower order centers.

4. Consumer movements to lower order centers tend to be frequent and
to cover shorter distances (a smaller range), while movements to
higher order centers tend to be less frequent and cover larger
distances.

5. In most instances goods tend to move vertically, up and down the
hierarchy from one level to an adjacent level rather than horizontally.

6. Market areas are arranged in a nested fashion such that the market
area for a higher order center will contain several market areas for
each of one or more centers tend to be spaced farther apart than are
lower order centers.

In contrast to the market hierarchies summarized in Table 4.1
which are, in general, based upon the nature of the settlement in
which the market is located (e.g., rural, town, urban), and to a
lesser extent, upon the area that the market serves (e.g., local,
interregional), the present study defines the hierarchical market
system on the basis of the types and quantities of goods available at
individual markets. Having examined the range of goods provided at
each of the 13 markets in the study area, a hierarchy was established
on the following basis:










Level 5. Basic items: foodstuffs, soap, thread,
(lowest) matches, notebooks, pens, small amount of cloth, small
amount of meat.

Level 4. Basic items plus sundries: charcoal, batteries, plastic
ware, small amount and limited variety of clothing.

Level 3. Basic items and sundries plus houseware/clothing: metal
cookware, cups, glasses, hardware, shoes, large amount and
variety of clothing.

Level 2. Basic items, sundries, and houseware/clothing plus
specialty items: briefcases, handbags, straw products and
hats, furniture, livestock in large quantities (alive and
butchered) tools, rubber boots.

Level 1. Basic items, sundries, houseware, clothing, and
(highest) specialty items in greater quantities and variety than in
Level 4.

Table 4.4 and Figure 4.3 illustrate the nature and location of
the hierarchy observed in L'Acul River Basin marketing system. The
large urban market at Cayes is distinguished from the next highest
level (Ducis and Chantal) principally in terms of the amounts and
variety of goods available; the Cayes market does not represent a
discrete step up in terms of the order of goods provided. Referring
to Table 4.3, one can also note that the size of a market, in terms of
the number of vendors, does not necessarily accurately reflect its
level in the hierarchy. For example, Arniquet with 150 vendors and
Caiman with 20 are placed at Level 3; similarly, Platons and Canon
with 15 vendors each and Carrefour Joute with 100 are placed at
Level 5. In both instances the seemingly disparate markets are
functionally analogous to one another. The wide spreads in the number
of vendors may be explained by the population densities supporting the
markets. Arniquet and Carrefour Joute have much higher population
densities than do Caiman, Platons, or Canon, and can thus support a
greater number of vendors.

It is interesting to note that no clear central place spacing is
evident from Figure 4.3, although Level 3 and 4 markets do tend to be
rather evenly distributed. The two Level 2 markets, Ducis and
Chantal, are much closer together than would be expected on the basis
of central place theory. However, one must consider the time
dimension; the two markets are not in direct competition, but rather,
are complementary.

4.3.3 COMMODITY FLOWS

The flow of commodities between markets is shown in Table 4.5.
This summarizes both origin and destination of goods. To facilitate
the interpretation of this table, Figures 4.4A 4.4M depict the
origins of goods flowing to each market. Several observations may be












TABLE 4.4



L'Acul River Basin Marketing System Hierarchy


Level Characteristics* Market



1 Basic items, sundries, houseware/clothing Cayes
specialty items in larger variety and
quantity



2 Basic items, sundries, houseware/clothing Ducis,
specialty items Chantal



3 Basic items, sundries, houseware/clothing Arniquet
Caiman
Sousoois



4 Basic items, sundries Camp Perrin
Carrefour Valere
Torbeck, Le Pretre



5 Basic items Platons, Canon,
Carrefour Joute


*Defined in text
















MARKET HIERARCHY

L'ACUL BASIN

MARKETING SYSTEM


Sousbois*3


Camp Perrin,4


(Highest) i
2 LEVEL IN
3 HIERARCHY
(Lowest) 5


CAYES PLAIN BASIN

L'ACUL RIVER BASIN

---- L'ACUL DIVIDE SUBSURFACE


Torbeck


A 6y


FIGURE 4.3





















FIGURE 4.4 A-M

ORIGINS OF GOODS FLOWING TO
L'ACUL RIVER BASIN MARKETS











































C O M M O DITY L O S 1 0 CO M MO D ITY FLO W S TOLAS




DU.. ...,.t
C s J .. ..C A E P AI S S


L'A~tRIER AO. -. j IVN AS



L-*C.JI DIVIDE SUSUAFCt ---- CUL DIVIDE SUBSURFACE














D















COM MODITY FLOWS TC O












t-ACOS RIVER NSAIS VACUL LIVERS 5*541
LACUL. DIVIE $ DEIE EACUE U JE...... ...
SlU.5 A1t V AC UI I IVI I SU.SUf At
L'AC~t D-U






























F I II


:'AC 1 1112 BASI




CAVESI". ASIN "Yt PLAIN BASIN.












COMMODITY FLlOWS 10 \\~ \ \I COMMODITY FLOWS TOICC~


CAUOUR AUE f i


,.,.. I I C....


I'A~tRIIABASN ....'* 'AU I' I'l"AI..,

.............. I )AC
I'C~ IVV SDURAI .. F ....--- 'CL IIO SB-FC ........





































COMMODITY FLOWS T10 COMMODITY FLOWS TO \

TORECK c o c.* PL ATONS cl..




o!.. .".;"..,I .


CAVYS PIAI N ASUI CAS P-AIN BASIN Jt*.

L'ACUtL IV *ASIN .....- CUL RIVER AS .

*--- ACUl DIVIDE SUBSUACE I-------- It'ACUL DIVIDE SUlSUFEACE





























*. ...
COMMOoITY flOWS TO S U. Ss E COMMODITY FLOWS TO S UtS

CANON c...* CARREFOUR OU'







CAVES RiAI BASIN .-- CAES P""EAN BASN

-- ACU ASI L'ACUL RIVER ASIN A....e ,

'. ACUL UIVIDU SU.SU.IAOCl ...-------- LACUL DIVIDL IUBSUIRFACIE









made concerning Table 4.5. First, it is clear that the classical
central place-type flow of goods is not found in L'Acul River Basin
marketing system. That is to say, although goods move vertically up
and down the hierarchy they tend not to pass through markets at
adjacent levels of the hierarchy. Contrary to the suggestions made by
Johnson (1970) and Jaffe (1983), the marketing system is not dendritic
but, rather, may be described as primate. This term is generally used
to describe the non-hierarchical direct connections between the
largest (primate) city and all other cities in developing countries.
Its use here indicates that direct connections exist between the
higher order markets (e.g. Cayes, Ducis, Chantal, Sousbois) and the
majority of other markets, irrespective of their levels in the
hierarchy. Note that there are several instances of direct links to
Port-au-Prince. These findings help to reinforce the delineation of
the market hierarchy specified above.

Second, with few exceptions, markets at the same or similar
level of the hierarchy tend to have similar linkage patterns, for
example Cayes, Ducis, Chantal; Arniquet, Caiman; Platons, Canon. The
major exceptions to this generalization are: Sousbois, which has a
more extensive linkage pattern than other level 3 markets due to its
strategic role as an interface between L'Acul Basin marketing system
and markets in the mountains and on the northern coast of the
peninsula; and Carrefour Valere and Carrefour Joute which serve
principally as markets for local produce.

Finally, one should note the role of the population in and
around Platons in maintaining linkages between, on one hand, Sousbois
and the markets toward the north; and, on the other hand, those in the
study area. It is common for the residents of Platons to make the 4
hour round trip to Sousbois on a Thursday or Saturday and the 5-6 hour
round trip to Ducis or Chantal on Tuesday or Friday. In this manner
the flow of goods between the uplands and lowlands is facilitated.
This is not to imply, however that other linkages between the uplands
and lowlands do not exist; it is not uncommon for a 10-12 hour (or
longer) round trip to be made between the uplands and lowlands in one
day. It is possible for the market women from the uplands to catch a
truck to Ducis at Le Pretre, if the river is sufficiently low (cost 6
G per person round trip), or, if not, at Dubreuil (cost: 4 G per
person round trip). From Ducis transport can be obtained to Cayes at
cost of 2 G per person and an additional 2 G per sack each way.
Direct connections by truck may be made between Ducis and Port au
Prince every Tuesday for a cost of 15 G per person each way.

4.3.4 MARKET PRICE VARIATION

Over the two-week period in which the marketing system was
studied, (the major portion of markets being visited in the first
week) no significant difference in the individual prices of a common











TABLE 4.5

Origin-Destination Matrix:

Commodity Flows


Destination/ 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Origin CY D CH A CA S CP CV LP T P CN CJ PaP 0


1 Cayes / + + + + + + + + + + + + +

2 Ducis + / + + + + + + +

3 Chantal + + + + + + + +

4 Arniquet + + / --

5 Caiman / -

6 Sousbois + / -- + +

7 Camp Perrin- + /

8 Carrefour
Valere /

9 Le Pretre -- -/ +

10 TorPeck / -

11 Platons /

12 Canon /

13 Carrefour
Joute-- /

14 Port au
Prince + + + + +

15 Other + + /


+ Major Flows
- Minor Flows









list of products was found between markets. 1 This finding is
somewhat surprising given the functioning of all other marketing
systems with which the authors are familiar. The lack of variation
can, however, be explained by two factors. First, time has no
intrinsic monetary value in the "accounting system" of the Haitian
individual or household. Therefore consumers are willing to spend
several extra hours travelling to a market where they can oDtain the
lowest price on a specific item. This high degree of consumer
mobility creates strong competition between markets and enforces a
high degree of price uniformity. Second, as noted above, L'Acul River
Basin marketing system is primate rather than dendritic in nature.
The direct vertical connections imply a reduced level of intermediary
activity (i.e. intermediate linkages between adjacent levels in the
hierarchy) and thus a minimal level of mark-ups as the commodities
reach their final destination. Both Johnson (1970) and Jaffe (1983)
argue that a dendritic system, characterized by lack of horizontal
competition, leads to price discrimination and exploitation of the
consumers by intermediaries. This may be so but the present evidence
indicates that a primate structure can compensate for lack of
horizontal competition. In summary, then, there is every indication
that L'Acul River Basin marketing system possesses a price structure
that responds directly to the stimulus of supply and demand and that
the system is both relatively efficient and non-discriminatory.

Table 4.6 summarizes typical system-wide prices for a list of
directly comparable and commonly purchased commodities. It must be
stressed that these prices and the general lack of price variation
between markets are associated with a specific time period; without
further study the results cannot be generalized for longer time
periods or for other markets. Figures 4.5 (A through E) illustrates
the temporal variations (in terms of average monthly prices) for some
specific commodities at three markets in the study area. These data
suggest varying degrees of price variation, at least between Cayes
Camp Perrin, and Ducis/Chantal. The latter pair are treated as one
since there is no variation in the price of commodities between them.

Figure 4.6 shows temporal price variations for four commodities
at the Cayes market. Both sets of data are presented for illustrative
purposes and no attempt is made to interpret them due to their unknown
level of reliability. Variations in the supply of certain commodities
are, however, evident in the data. For example, the relative supplies
of sorghum and corn, as reflected in the market prices, are exactly
out of phase; the peak in the corn supply corresponds to the lowest
availability of sorghum and vice-versa.


1 Market prices for commodities were collected by two
Caucasians, one fluent in Creole. It was made clear to the vendors
that the information was required for a study; there was no intention
of purchase. In this way the true market price rather than the "prix
blanc" was obtained. For verification, 3-5 vendors were asked the
price of an individual commodity.












TABLE 4.6

Market Prices:
L'Acul River Basin Marketing System

November 15 29, 1983


Price per Unit


Congo Beans

Black Beans

Red Beans

Country Rice

Milled Corn

Unmilled Corn

Wheat

Brown Sugar

Milled Sorghum**

Salt

Okra

Matches

Farine France

Garlic

Tobacco

Soap

Peanuts

Cigarettes


20 Kob/verre*

1 Gourd/verre

90 Kob/verre

1 Gourd/verre

50 Kob/verre

35 Kob/verre

50 Koo/verre

20 Kob/small roll

60 Kob/verre

15 Kob/verre

20 Kob/low

2.5 Gourd/package

60 Kob/verre

20 Kob/head

1 Gourd/4 leaves

1.10 Gourd/bar

25 Kob/petit verre

3.25 Gourd/package


* There are 11.5 verre in a marmite.
** In short supply; not available everywhere.


Item
























Figure 4.5 A thru E

TEMPORAL VARIATIONS IN
MONTHLY PRICES FOR
SELECTED COMMODITIES


C
WHITE RICE
Gourds/Pound












FIGURE 4.6

20 LES CAYES MARKET PRICE

19 AVERAGES/MONTH, 4/80 9/82

SOURCE: IDAI; compiled by M. Yeats
18
17

16

15

14

13 RICE
12 (MDM GOUGOUSSE)
11

10

9
8 RED BEANS

7


6

5

4 SORGHUM

3

2 IZE KERNEL


1


Apr. M J J A S J F MAM J JA S O N D f
1980 1981 1982









A final consideration relating to market prices is the amount of
profit accruing to the various participants in the marketing process.
Table 4.7 illustrates typical profit margins for vendors selling
directly to consumers (i.e., retailers rather than intermediaries) for
a variety of commodities. Due to time and manpower constraints it was
not possible to measure the profit margin realized by other
participants. In general, there tends to be a lower mark up on
commonly utilized foodstuffs and a higher one on tools, housewares,
and imported foodstuffs, e.g. garlic. Where appropriate, the profit
margin has been adjusted to include the cost of motorized
transportation. Although there is a relatively wide range in level of
profit, values clustering around 10% are the most commonly
encountered. It should be noted that one way in which the vendor may
increase her profit margin is to process raw or semi-finished
products, thus enhancing the final selling price. This increase in
value added frequently occurs in the case of milling corn en grain and
coffee en paille, drying green rice, and baking bread.

4.3.5 IMPLICATIONS FOR DEVELOPMENT

L'Acul River Basin marketing system has been described and
analyzed. The general impression left by this examination is that the
system is a fairly uniform and relatively closed functional unit with
few lateral external linkages. The system is a competitive one which
is non-exploitative and which is relatively efficient (from a
viewpoint which does not place a monetary value on the expenditure of
time). It remains to discuss the implications for development that
are raised by this analysis of the system. These implications are
relevant not only to the marketing system per se but also to the
broader economic system to which it is intimately related. It should
be stressed that at this stage of the study (i.e., before passing the
results through our two social-institutional filters) the following
observations are only that; they are not yet specific recommendations
for development

Export Development. Certain agricultural products that are
grown or that could be grown in the Cayes Plain Basin have the
potential for serving export markets at both the interregional (i.e.,
Haitian) and international levels. Among the existing crops the
expansion of coffee production is the most fruitful possibility, given
the introduction of better management practices. In addition, coffee
has the added benefit of enhancing soil conservation. It is difficult
to identify other crops with the potential for international export
given the large, complex, organized, and independent marketing
infrastructures required. Existing crops with the potential for
interregional export include bananas (which have had in the past an
international significance) and the various citrus tree crops. Both
bananas and citrus crops are conducive to soil conservation.













TABLE 4.7



Retailer Profits
November 15 29, 1983




Commodity Profit (%)


Unmilled Corn 5

Soap, Cloth 6

Sorghum, Coffee, Straw Hats
Country Rice 7

Peanuts, Wheat 8

Milled Corn, Black Beans 9

Bread, Brown Sugar, Matches 10

Fish 15

Flour, Rice Jean-Claude 15

Rubber Boots 18

Cigarettes, Plastic Bowls, Machetes
Coconut pieces 20

Garlic, Plantain 25

Carbonated Beverages 29

Batteries (flashlight type) 38

Charcoal 40

Salt 43

Glassware 50









Onions, radishes, and possibly garlic and potatoes are among the
potential crops with significance for interregional export. With time
and good management, wood may become a source of export income. The
difficulty here is that because of the time lag between the initial
planting and the first "harvest", the small farmers must find
alternative short-term sources of income. The practice of
continuously planting and selectively harvesting trees is, of course,
one of the better soil conservation practices. Finally, there is the
possibility that some of the lowlands within the Cayes Plain Basin may
be suitable for the introduction of cacao, a crop with international
export potential.

Import Substitution. A related consideration is the production
for local consumption of commodities imported into the region from
interregional or international origin points. Again, onions and
potatoes (presently from Kenscoff) and garlic (presently from Spain)
are obvious possibilities. In addition, many imported small
manufactured items that require neither large capital investments nor
state-of-the-art technologies could be substituted for by locally
produced goods. Among these are various tools and implements,
houseware and hardware items, and clothing.

Creation of Value Added. A further consideration that is
directly linked to both export development and import substitution
involves the processing of raw materials, especially of agricultural
products; i.e., turning perishable produce into more durable
commodities with a higher market value.' It should be noted that one
of the few existing processing operations in the Cayes Plain Basin, a
tomato paste plant, has recently been shut down because of competition
from lower priced imports from the Dominican Republic. Although the
situation is highly complex, it is rumored that the imported product
has been able to attain a lower price because the Haitian government
has released one large importer from the obligation of paying import
duties. It is evident that, if this is in fact true, this type of
practice should be curtailed and indigenous industries encouraged
rather than discouraged. Sugar refining is another possibility for
the creation of value added. Therefore, it is essential that the
linkage between the cane and its processing site be improved through
more efficient collection and transportation. With each hour that
elapses between the cutting of the cane and its processing the cane's
sucrose content diminishes. In order to compete on the world market,
however, the existing underutilized Centrale Dessalines will need to
achieve an economies-of-scale threshold. Related to the production of
cane is the distillation of rum. It appears, however, that a major
world-wide marketing campaign would be necessary to increase the
demand for Haitian rum. Further, in the long-term the possibility
exists for the processing of wood products and lumber.

Transport and Storage Infrastructure. In order to enhance the
economic viability of the region certain improvements in its
transportation infrastructure would be desirable. The roads above









Dubreuil linking it with Canon, Caiman, Le Pritre, and Platons need to
be upgraded for improved vehicular access. The three river crossings
between Dubreuil and Le Pretre, in particular, present serious
problems during the rainy season. The road from Le Pretre to Platons,
which is barely passable in a four wheel drive vehicle (which can
attain a speed equivalent only to foot traffic) will need to be
upgraded if the Platons area is to realize its full potential. The
peasants in the Platons area have aspirations of growing certain
crops, such as tomatoes, which would likely suffer considerable damage
in transit over the present road. Also, other farming changes such as
the introduction of livestock would likely be facilitated, as would
access to the area for agronomes and other technical workers. In
addition, foot paths in the slopes area that link the Ravine des
Mornes and the Ravine Duclerc hinterlands to the principal L'Acul road
network are presently dangerous during the rainy season even to tne
Haitian peasant who is accustomed to navigating them. In general,
however, "desenclavement" is not a problem as it is in the Central
Plateau. Critical issues relating to domestic and international
transportation linkages with Cayes also need to be addressed. These
will be considered in the following section. Clearly, improvements
are required in both areas in order to promote the development of the
Cayes Plain Basin. Facilities for the storage of agricultural produce
is a second required infrastructural component. As shown in Figures
4.5 and 4.6, there are seasonal fluctuations in the market prices of
agricultural commodities due to the seasonal variations in the supply
of these commodities. In many instances the peasant producers sell
their produce for low prices when the supply is abundant and buy it
back at higher prices later in the year when it is scarce. Improved
rural storage facilities would assist' in the interseasonal
stabilization of market supply and permit the farmer to retain the
surplus value that his efforts have created. Beans, sorghum, corn
and, to a somewhat lesser extent, rice are among the commodities for
which the need for storage facilities are most acute.

The Role of Cayes as a Central Place Growth Center. The Cayes
Plain Basin is linked to the rest of Haiti and to the rest of the
world through Cayes, the nation's third largest city, and thence
through Port-au-Prince. As shown above in section 4.3.3, there are
direct connections between Ducis, and also some of the lower order
markets, and Port-au-Prince, but Cayes generally functions as the
region's interface with the exterior. Thus Cayes has the potential
for serving a very crucial function in a regional development
context. There are several aspects to this strategic function.
First, Cayes may serve as a regional growth center from which
investments, technology, and the impetus to economic growth will
"spread" or "trickle down" to the areas with which it has contact.

At present Cayes, as all other Haitian cities outside of
Port-au-Prince, is not being utilized to its full economic potential.
The surrounding rural areas would benefit not only from the
development of an urban-industrial base in Cayes but also from the
innovations, information and social services that a vital urban center









generates. Second, the development of a more developed industrial
structure would provide employment opportunities which might help to
reduce some of the pressure of the farm population upon agricultural
land (particularly on the slopes), the productive capability of which
is diminishing visibly with each passing year. Third, Cayes has the
potential for the re-establishment of its historical function as an
active port with linkages to the rest of Haiti and to the rest of the
world. Not only would this facilitate interregional and international
exports, but it would also raise the possibility of developing a
quasi-freeport assembly function similar to that of Port-au-Prince.
The lower land prices in Cayes might make this a very economically
attractive alternative. Note, however, that all of the above
alternatives relating to Cayes' potential as a growth center would
require a major reorientation on the part of the Government of Haiti,
whose explicit and implicit economic development policies tend to
centralize all activities and direct all economic flows to
Port-au-Prince. For example, the recently completed paved road
between Port-au-Prince and Cayes has actually worked to the detriment
of local merchants in Cayes; many of their former customers now do at
least a portion of their shopping in Port-au-Prince.

Other Issues.

A number of other issues that may have implications for regionaL
development are worthy of exploration. First, the markets are an
effective medium of communication with the Haitian population. With a
high degree of frequency some member of every household visits one of
the lower level markets and, with somewhat lower frequency, one of the
higher level ones. The implication of this is that information,
seeds, and various social services can be distributed using the market
system. Second, levels of agricultural production may be enhanced by
crop type substitution and by selective crop variety substitution.

The former refers to the substitution of soil-conserving
perennials, such as coffee, for annuals, as well as to the
introduction of new types such as onion and garlic. The latter refers
to the substitution of crop varieties that have a different date of
maturation than those presently utilized. The effect of this is to
even out the peaks and valleys in.the supply of a crop. The
substitution must be accomplished selectively, for if the new variety
is adopted by all farmers the peaks and valleys in the supply of the
crop will simply be shifted in time. A final economic consideration
is the availability of credit to the farmers. Credit is important for
the purchase of land, fertilizer, and seeds. It was generally
observed in the course of this study that there is a wide variation in
the access to, and utilization of, credit; the lowland farmers tend to
avail themselves of available credit to a much greater extent than do
farmers on the slopes or uplands. The problem of credit is discussed
in more detail in Chapter Six.










CHAPTER 5


AGRICULTURE: THE PHYSICAL-ECONOMIC INTERFACE


5.1 INTRODUCTION

From the perspective of developing a rational co-ordinated rural
regional development strategy for the Cayes Plain Basin in general and
L'Acul River Basin in particular, it is necessary to consider the
plain first from a regional perspective, and only then examine its
site specific attributes. The optimal approach to initiate the
crucial changes in rural Haiti for improving the environmental
situation is simultaneously combining and developing all physical and
human resources while never taxing the resource capabilities above
their ecologic capabilities. Improvements in the physical environment
will increase the long-term economic situation by developing a
resource base able to support improvements in per capital income.
Equally, existing limitations of the human resource need to be
countered since without concurrent improvements in the socio-economic
situation the physical improvements would likely be only exceedingly
short-term.

Only in a regional river basin approach can all resources be
controlled in a rational manner from the basin divides to the lowest
lands without external forces preventing the re-establishment of the
ecologic balance. This balance is essential for improved agriculture,
grazing, and silvacultural production and social progress in a
primarily land resource oriented economy.


5.2 ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL CROPS IN L'ACUL

Table 5.1 lists the major agricultural crops, forestry, and
animal production activities potentially viable for the climatic
moisture conditions found within the Cayes Plain Basin. Because the
soils throughout the uplands generally are either thin or drain
rapidly, in spite of the area being classified as climatically humid
(0.80), in terms of soil moisture available for plant growth most of
the lands within the upper Acul act as subhumid (0.65 0.80) zones.
The west facing slopes, due to the already discussed microclimatic
attributes of these areas, act as a semi-humid to sub-humid moisture
zone. In addition to moisture, temperature affects the range of
possible crops. In L'Acul River Basin the variation in temperature
from one portion to another is largely a result of elevation. The
lowlands are generally below 100 meters, the slopes between 100 and
800 meters, the Platons between 600 and 1200 meters, and the Igneous
Highlands above 1200 meters. Given that mean annual temperature
decreases at an average value of 0.60 C/100 meters, a temperature
range of over 70 C exists between a lowland location such as Chantal







Potential Rainfed Crops for Cayes Plain Basin


___Major potential growing zones (optimal)


Sub-optimal moisture conditions


R = Average Annual Rainfall

EO = Annual Potential Evapotranspiration


EO(mm ) = 2422-0.358h(meters)


h = elevation


Modified for Haiti based on H.M.H. Braun Agroclimatic Zone Map of Kenya, Nairobi, 1982


Table 5.1


R/EO Moisture Range Suitable for Animal Jrest Species
UNIT (%) Various Crops without Irrigation Production


Platonl I I I
L1.euus U >.80 I I I I I
Highlands, I I I
Slopes I



I o I I
4-1
Cal 4 041 0 :3l
Lowlands .65-.80 01a o 0 3 0 i> 4 in
4-i i o o a < )4J 0 -0 a -4 o > -, -4 -i
C al C d WUi Cal4-l .) 04J C U ai Cd *H B PU t 4- 1 C "

00)) 4-1 0 W a) 0c !
_,______ _____8 CL -


--__---_-----









and a Platons site such as Formond (Sousbois). With the increasing
elevation and cooler temperatures you would expect to find a
differentiation in crop types between the four major units in L'Acul
River Basin. Table 5.2 presents the crops according to land unit and
tenure system as they were observed by the Study Team during November
and December, 1983 throughout the whole Acul River Basin. Very little
differentiation is evident in terms of land units. Many crops are
found in all of the units. Among these widespread crops are: sweet
potatoes, cocoyam, beans, sorghum, mango, corn, and banana. Only a
few crops such as sugarcane, citrus, rice, and Irish potatoes are
grown in only a portion of the river basin. It appears that little
crop specialization has evolved within L'Acul due to ecological
differences. This can be partially explained by the relatively
similar moisture available for plant growth in the uplands and
lowlands given the soil moisture retention properties of the upland
soils. However, this lack of ecological crop specialization might
reflect two other critical factors determining crop choice. First,
the absence of a wide selection of seed or nursery stock limits the
selection process. Many farmers, especially in the Platons indicated
this was an important factor that limits their crop selection.
Second, there is not a large demand in L'Acul River Basin marketing
system for other crops. However, this second possibility is likely
invalid since foodstuffs from as far away as Kenscoff-Furcy reach all
markets within the system.

A greater differentiation in crop selection appears to result
from land tenure. On table 5.2, in the sharecropped and rented
categories, no tree crops are evident. All of the crops grown are
annuals. Clearly investment in perennial crops on these types of
lands is not considered by the individuals working the lands.

Finally, from an environmental perspective it is important to
note that on the lands within the slope unit, very few of the crops
grown minimize soil erosion. In spite of active field abandonment
resulting from severe land degradation, farmers continue to crop their
land until it is impossible. Fields over 550 are continuously being
planted in sorghum, a particular crop that exacerbates erosion.


5.3 LINKS BETWEEN RURAL LAND USE AND ENVIRONMENT

5.3.1 Introduction

Many of the environmental problems existing within the Cayes
Plain Basin including low land productivity, water shortages, and
flooding result from the improper use of the land. Because both soil
and water are transported within the river system, all of the land
units are interconnected regarding these two resources. Within the
Cayes Plain Basin the best lands from an agriculture perspective are
the rolling to flat uplands on Les Platons and the low flat lands on









TABLE 5.2

Crops Observed: November December 1983,
L'Acul River Basin


TENURE


CROPS


Inherited Land






Purchased Land


Sharecropped Land


Rented Land


Sweet Potato
Manioc
Sorghum
Cocoyam
Coffee
Citrus

Coffee
Mahaut
Sweet Potato
Sorghum
Citrus

Peas
Sweet Potato

Manioc
Sweet Potato


Irish Potato
Peas
Beans
Taro
Banana
Mango

Yam
Peas
Beans
Corn (maize)
Mango


Beans
Manioc


Irish Potato
Sorghum


Owned Land (Include inherited and purchased)
Congo Peas Sweet Potato
Cocoyam Avocado
Sorghum Coffee
Orange (sour and sweet)
Manioc Banana
Mango Peanut
Karayib Sugar Cane


Rented Land


Yam
Karayib (?)
Sweet Potato


Sharecropped


Yam
Karayib
Sorghum


Sweet Potato
Beans
Corn


Non Irrigated


Irrigated


Sorghum
Corn
Sweet Potato
Banana
Beans
Sugar Cane


Rice
Tobacco


(?) English Name could not be determined but like a cocoyam


UNIT


Platons


Lowlands


Manioc
Banana
Sorghum


Karayib
Cocoyam
Peanuts
Tobacco
Mango


Beans


Slopes










the Cayes Plain. It is the uplands--The Igneous Mountains, Les
Platons, and Slope Units-- which are the major watersheds of the
rivers flowing across the Cayes Plain. In addition many of the
characteristics of these uplands, their infiltration rates, slope
steepness, and interception characteristics--determine the ratio of
the precipitation that flows as direct runoff contrasted to ground
water flows to the river channels. As this ratio increases, river
discharges for low frequency flows become larger, while at high
frequency flows they become smaller. For example if because of a
decrease in the vegetation cover, a smaller proportion of
precipitation infiltrates into the groundwater, the river will flood
more often (low frequency event) and have lower baseflow (high
frequency). Since the occupation of the Cayes Plain Basin by the
French and continuing unabated to the present, all land use practices
in operation have resulted in increases in this ratio. This signifies
that land use practices have been and are diametrically opposed to the
rational use of the water resource. In the following sections of this
chapter, the term, agriculture is used in its broadest sense. That is
it includes not only foodcrops but also livestock production and
forestry.

5.3.2 L'Acul River Basin Agriculture and Environmental Impacts

During the field portions of this S.I.P. it became obvious to
the Study Team that within the river basin the complex mixed forest
that was indigenous to the whole area has .been completely cleared.
Only in a small portion of the Igneous Highlands does there exist a
semblance of forest cover, and here it is in a degraded state with few
tree species and large areas having no protecting underbrush and few
saplings, the latter being continuously cleared for firewood.
Therefore the natural regeneration of the forest, even in its one
small remaining area, is threatened by existing practices.

A brief inspection of Table 5.2 clearly indicates that the
overwhelming proportion of land in cultivation is in annual crops.
Only sugar cane, scattered fruit trees and other scattered types of
trees, "wild" coffee bushes, banana and vetiver are perennial. From
an environmental perspective perennial crops are soil conserving
compared to annuals. Thus, the current mix of crops is not favorable
for a conservation strategy. This latter statement attains even
greater credibility when the spatial distribution of these crops is
examined. No systematic pattern of the perennial crops exists
relative to the environmental setting with the exception of rice which
is only grown on the plain. Sugar cane is grown on both steep and
gentle slopes, trees are found scattered throughout the lands without
any development of complete areal coverage. Thus little continuous
tree cover exists throughout the basin. Individual trees scattered
throughout the landscape provide only minimal erosional control since
runoff generated in other areas flows freely past the individual
trees, often exposing some of the tree roots. Vetiver actually
encourages soil erosion throughout L'Acul River Basin since, when it
is harvested, it is pulled out of the ground resulting in a loose base









soil. As the harvest often occurs just prior to the advent of the
rainy season, the potential for soil erosion is extremely high.
Coffee, as it is only grown in the immediate area of the kay, whicn is
often situated on a level parcel of land, likewise is not being
utilized as a soil conserving crop. Similarly, annual crops are grown
under widely disparate conditions independent of any apparent
environmental concern. Sorghum, congo peas, beans, corn, and manioc
are planted over the whole spectrum of slope conditions existing in
the river basin. While congo peas are considered a soil enriching
crop due to their ability to fix nitrogen, because of their poor leaf
cover the soil is continuously washed down slope when they are grown
on moderate to steep slopes. Thus the benefits of increasing soil
fertility are more than countered by the low degree of erosional
protection.

Similar to cropping practices, livestock grazing as it occurs in
L'Acul River Basin is not conducive to environmental maintenance.
Generally, animals are tethered and left to graze in a limited area
each day. This results in a process of discontinuous overgrazing. In
addition, as livestock are moved on a daily basis along footpaths in
their search for pasture, there develop zones of overgrazed land.
These overgrazed zones act as catalysts for the initiation of
excessive rill and, at times, gully erosion in many locales. In
summary, given the distribution of agricultural activities throughout
the whole basin, it is evident that either little concern exists for
the soil resources or the constraints placed upon the farmers do not
allow the peasants to consider the options necessary for soil
conservation.

5.3.3 Existing Farming Practices and Environmental Impacts

Throughout L'Acul River Basin, little obvious conservation
practices are evident. From the preparation of the fields for
planting through the harvest, little evidence exists that indicates
soil conservation enters into the minds of the small farmers. For
example, in the process of preparing the soil for seed planting, the
farmers almost universally 'hoe' the soils downslope, thereby
contributing to the downslope movement of the soil. Even in the
relatively well managed slope areas of Furcy-Kenscoff (Port au Prince)
this practice is utilized. Clearly the ease of using this hoeing
technique results in its ubiquitous use.

The piling-up of soil in mounds might appear to be a soil
conserving device. Yet the evidence indicates that it is the need to
increase the depth of the soil to a sufficient depth to permit plant
growth that is the major motivation for this practice. That is, in
many places the thinness of the soil profile requires this practice.
The lack of a specific orientation bias in the plane view of the
mounds results in these features having a minimal impact on decreasing
the movement of the overland flow of the water. In fact, the
placement of mounds on the steep slopes might even increase the
likelihood of erosion.









The clearing of rocks from the fields gives further evidence of
the minimal consideration of soil erosion control in the daily
activities of the farmer. Throughout the Slope and Platons units many
fields are 'pocked' with cairn-like mounds. Nowhere were these cairns
oriented parallel to the slope contour to act as barriers to the
downslope movement of materials even though this practice would not
have resulted in more work for the individuals. Minimal contouring
and mulching are practiced throughout L'Acul. When contouring is
evident, it is often on steep slopes ( 100) that minimize its impact.

Two bits of contradictory evidence exist to this apparent lack
of erosion control consciousness on the part of the small farmer.
First on Les Platons, relics of stonewalls are evident in the vicinity
of the Citadelle. These were built for soil erosion control. However
today they are gradually going into disrepair. This reversal in the
erosion control process began when the agronome who mobilized the
farmers was transferred and no government replacement was sent to the
area. Likewise, terrace building near Canoe initiated under the PDAI
program is evident. But these, as the stonewalls, appear to be relics
on the landscape.

In summary, current farming practices clearly place a low
priority on soil conservation. In fact some of the practices appear
to accelerate the erosional processes. Evidence exists that the small
farmers are willing to become involved in soil erosion control. But
for this activity to be successful, methods must be found to make it a
part of their daily routine; otherwise, when the outside force that
initiated the erosional activities leaves the area, the practices will
cease.

5.3.4 Existing Irrigation Practices and Environment

Irrigation in L'Acul River Basin for all practical purposes is
synonymous with the Dubreuil Project. The evaluation of this project
is reported in great detail (Stutler, et al. 1983). For the purposes
of this report only two aspects of the water management in this
project need to be mentioned. Neither of these aspects are stressed
in the Stutler report. First, it appears that minimal monitoring of
the quantities of water delivered to individual fields occurs. Visual
observations by the Study Team appear to indicate that most of the
fields are being over irrigated. Worldwide, many irrigation projects
have failed due to problems associated with water logging. Care needs
to be practiced to insure that the lands being irrigated remain
viable. Second, this wasteful use of the water minimizes the areal
coverage of the Cayes Plain that is potentially available for
irrigation. One other aspect of the irrigation project that was noted
appears to be the lack of ongoing maintenance in the canals. Some
damage was observed but no repair crews were ever observed. If this
low maintenance policy continues, when the system is under stress major
damage could occur.









Another environmental component that could limit the Dubreuil
Project occurs in the vicinity of the diversion dam. The reservoir
behind the barrage is already completely silted-up. If a major flood
occurs on L'Acul, in spite of the engineering precautions, the
diversion channel could become blocked by the massive quantities of
bedload materials available for transport upstream of the dam.
Whether or not this event occurs will be decided by the agricultural
activities occurring not on the Cayes Plain lowlands, but by the
farming practices on the Slopes, Platons, and Highland units.


5.4 Land Tenure

It is widely recognized that the specific characteristics of a
region's (or a nation's) land tenure system exert a strong influence
upon agricultural practices and productivity. A number of authors
have focused upon this issue in the Haitian context (Murray 1977,
1978a, 1978b, 1978c; Smucker 1982; Zuvekas 1978). The purpose of the
present section is to examine patterns of land tenure in L'Acul River
Basin and to explore their implications for agricultural activity.

5.4.1 Land Tenure Patterns

In his discussion of land tenure, Murray (1977: 177) suggests
the existence of "genuine subcultural differences between lowland
Haiti and highland Haiti, differences that appear to be related more
to ecology than to simple regional variation." Most previous research
in the Cayes Plain Basin has been in the lowlands. This is in
contrast to Murray's opinion that the literature on Haiti has "leaned
somewhat heavily toward the study of highland life", (Murray 1977:
77). As a result, the Study Team felt it was necessary to obtain land
tenure information in both the uplands and lowlands in spite of the
limited field period.

The present examination utilizes three of the four sub-regional
units defined in Chapter 3: Les Platons, the Slopes, and the
Lowlands. A fourth unit, the Igneous Highlands, has been omitted due
to time and accessibility constraints. As is shown, the tenure
situation in Les Platons and slope areas of L'Acul River Basin doesn't
differ significantly from what has been written about other
mountainous regions of Haiti (Zuvekas 1978).

In order to compare Les Platons, Slope and Lowlands units, a
formal land tenure questionnaire was applied to 12 household heads on
a random sample basis in each of the three subzones. For the
Lowlands, a distinction was made between irrigated and non-irrigated
land: 6 farm units were sampled in each of the two lowland areas.
Besides questions dealing with tenure, the questionnaire examined the
areas of credit, wage labor, and informal forms of cooperative labor
such as eskwad.










Most farmers were interviewed in their homes, and the majority
were men. However, when a woman considered herself to be a household
head, she was interviewed. The interviews were conducted in Creole.
After informal conversation of 10 to 15 minutes, the formal
questionnaire was introduced. The survey was done within a two week
time frame (Nov. 18 Dec. 1, 1983), and covered a total of 129 plots
worked by 36 farmers for a total of approximately 53 karo.

While the results from Les Platons and the Slopes likely are
representative of the land situation in these areas, the sample of 12
farmers in the plain certainly does not represent the lowland land
tenure situation in totality. In this study the large landowners,
which are important in the lowlands, were not interviewed. Therefore
it is better to consider this sample a "sondage" which can be compared
with caution to the Slopes and Les Platons.

To facilitate the interpretation of this survey, the
introduction of Serge Larose's (undated) diagram of possible tenure
status in Haiti is introduced (Table 5.3):


Table 5.3
MODES OF TENURE

PROPERTY RENTED LAND SHARECROPPED
I _L-- LAND

TITLED TE MINE POTEK FEM DEMWATYE
LAND --

PUR- INHER- DIVIDED NON-
CHASED ITED DIVIDED

Potek refers to land which has been rented and paid for, for two or
more years. Fem is land rented on an annual basis.


Because of important developments over the last two or three
decades, in particular the phenomenon of buying inheritable land, the
Larose breakdown of land tenure needs to be modified. Many
respondents, explaining about plots they purchased, bought lands that
were part of the family lands. Thus, the term "inherited" becomes
ambivalent because up to now "inherited land" referred by definition
to non-purchased land. It thus seems better to divide the section
"titled land" into three categories: (1) purchased non-inherited, (2)
purchased inherited, and (3) inherited non-purchased land. An
explanation of this recent development is presented below. The term
"inherited", as used in our tabulations, refers to non-purchased
inherited land, usually divided and rarely titled. In Larose's scheme
it would fit the "divided t6 mine" category. The inherited land is
worked by the farmer for his personal benefit.









Location and Tenure Type. Figures 5.1 to 5.3 indicate the
relationship between sub-region and type of ownership. With a same
number of respondents in each level of the basin (Platons, Slope,
Lowlands), there are a significantly smaller number of plots owned in
the Lowlands (Figure 5.3). Out of a total of 129 plots surveyed, 83
were owned (i.e inherited or purchased). All those who bought plots
have a clear legal title to their land. For those who own divided
inherited plots, the legal title grann pyes) is in the hands of one of
the family members. The average number of parcels owned (purchased or
inherited) for the 36 farmers is 2.5 plots. As illustrated in Figure
5.4, there are no significant differences between Platons, Slope and
Lowland units in total average number of plots per farmers: 3.16 in
the Platon, 3.58 in the Slope, and 3.91 in the Lowlands.

The literature reports a great variety in the average number of
plots held per farmer. Smucker (1982) found 5.2 plots per "economic
unit" in the northern Haitian hills. Zuvekas (1978) cites Kulakow et
al.'s findings in the Cayes Plain as 2.6 plots per farmer; White's
report in the same area found 1.7 The 1971 census showed an average
of 1.8 plots. Murray's (1977) average in the Cul-de-Sac Plain was
much higher: 5.8 plots per "holding".

In our survey, three farmers out of 36 did not own any land; one
in each of the three land units. The Platons farmer is a future land
owner. Today he works with other family members on a 21.3 karo family
holding (anpil 6ritiy6). The slope farmer sharecropped 5 karo from
his cousin, a coffee speculator who stole the land from his uncle by
bribing the notary. Otherwise this land would have become the
inheritance of the actual sharecropper. The non-owner on the lowland
rents one plot and sharecrops two non-irrigated plots. His mother is
still alive and owns 2.5 sezem (or 2.5 sixteenth of a karo), often
called ventsenk (25) in Creole. The farmer works his mother's land
but not for his own benefit. In the future he will inherit at least
part of this plot.

The reason these three exceptions are emphasized relates to the
issue of landlessness. The only person who will not own any land
through future inheritance is the speculator's cousin. Zuvekas'
percentages of people who own at least part of the land they work
range from 65 to 100 percent. L'Acul Basin findings of 33 out of 36
farmers owning land is 91.6 percent. It increases to 97.2 percent if
we consider the future ownership of two of the three other farmers.
Smucker found 17 percent of landless farmers (Smucker, 1982: 265);
Plotkin's survey in the North revealed only 2 percent of landless
household heads (Plotkin, undated:2). From the evidence gathered in
this study and reported in most other studies, landlessness appears to
be a non-issue in most areas when only the current farmers are
considered. However, from this, one should not infer that enough land
exists for the rural population. Perhaps one reason why landlessness
is not an issue is that most rural people without land migrate out of
the countryside.

















FIGURE 5.1

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF PURCHASED PLOTS BY LOCATION


TOTAL: 35 plots


34.(2)
(N-12)


40%


25.7%

(N-9)



~I


PLATOON SLOPE PLAIN


FIGURE 5.2

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF INHERITED PLOTS BY LOCATION

41.6%

(N-20)
33.3%


25%

(N-12)


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN


TOTAL: 48 plots


FIGURE 5.3

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF OWNED PLOTS (INHERIT or BOUGHT) BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 83 plots


38.5%

*(N-32)


36.1%

(N-30)


25.3%

(N-21)


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN














FIGURE 5.4

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF NUMBER OF PLOTS

(PER FARMER) BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 36 FARMERS
129 PLOTS

AVERAGE: 3.58 plots
5 per farmer
0 4 3.58 plots 3.91 plots
s. 3.16 plots
3
2
1


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN






FIGURE 5.5

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF RENTED PLOTS BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 28 plots



18 60.7%
16 (N-17)
14
12
10

4 8 21.4%
S6 17.8%

4 (N-5) (N-6)
2


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN






FIGURE 5.6

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF SHARECROPPED PLOTS BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 18 plots






S10 50%
8 38%
B 3)N-9)

' 6 (N-7)
S4
2 11.1%


PLATON SLOPE


PLAIN









Figures 5.5 and 5.6 refer to rented and sharecropped plots.
They show that in the Lowland many more plots are sharecropped and
rented than in the Slope and Platons areas. In the Platons, two
respondents indicated that they would like to sharecrop, but that no
land was avalaible. The same two farmers were also owners (of less
than 1 karo); one of them also rents a plot. Thus, it appears that
farmers' land demands are not met by the current availability of land.

Of the total 129 plots surveyed, 18 are sharecropped. This is
13.9 percent, which is close to the 14.4 percent found in the 1970
national survey. (Zuvekas, 1978: 16).

Figures 5.7 5.10 illustrate the meaning of the word "owner".
They indicate that "ownership" doesn't mean that the farmer
necessarily can make a sufficient living from his land. In the same
way that inherited and purchased land is governed by a regime of
microproperty (81.8 percent own less than 1/2 a karo), so are rented
and sharecropped plots extremely small in size. Of the rented plots,
92.8 percent are less than 1/2 karo; 94.3 percent of the sharecropped
plots are also less than 1/2 a karo. In our survey in the Cayes Plain
Basin, 62 percent of the plots measure less than 1/4 of a karo, and
23.2 percent are between 1/4 and 1/2 a karo.

Signs of increasing pressure on the land are revealed in many of
the respondents' reactions to the question on what they do to prevent
erosion. They can no longer afford to fallow their plots for one or
more seasons. In Smucker.'s research area, less than a decade ago,.
over 75 percent of the household units still maintained some land in
fallow (Smucker 1982: 259). In L'Acul Basin no such freedom remains.
In Le Pretre (Slope), family members have conflicts even over which
part of the non-divided family land will be worked by whom. This
"first-come, first-take" method of acquiring family plots was observed
by Murray (1978) in the same area. The Study Team was told that this
was not a general practice, but that only mechan yo (mean people) had
this bad habit. Both phenomena, the disappearance of the fallowing
custom and the "grabbing" of family lands, illustrate increased
pressure on the land. The farmer's most obvious reason for
maintaining land in fallow is ref6 te-a (rebuild the land fertility).
They all considered it a good, and traditionally probably the only,
erosional control method.

Farm Size and Price. Figure 5.11 illustrates average farm sizes
in each sub-region. The 36 farmers work a total of 52.1 karo, an
average of 1.44 karo. The plots in the Lowlands are only about half
as large as the Slope and Platon's plots. One explanation may be the
higher land prices in the irrigated plain and the lack of cash
availability for buying larger plots. Zuvekas' (1978) statement that
Haitian farmers "often deliberately seek to have fragmented
landholdings, particularly in different ecological zones, because this












FIGURE 5.7

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF RENTED PLOTS BY SIZE


TOTAL: 28 plots


71.4%


21.4%
7.1%
________--i-----


0.25 & less


0.26-0.50 0.51 1


FIGURE 5.8

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF OWNED PLOTS BY SIZE


TOTAL: 83 plots


61.4%


1 PURCHASED


E INHERITED





a 4.8%


20.4%


karo karo karo


30

25
S20
o. 15
o 10
z 5


50
45
40
E 35
30
o 25
II
a 20
15
10

5


karo


karo


















FIGURE 5.9

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF SHARECROPPED PLOTS BY SIZE

TOTAL: 18 plots



55.5%
o 10
a 38.8%

S 6
z 4

2 1 5.5%
20%

0.25 &less 0.26-0.5 (0.51.4) 5 karo






FIGURE 5.10

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

TOTAL NUMBER OF PLOTS BY SIZE

TOTAL: 129 plots

90
62.7%
80
70
60

50
40
S40 23.2%
30

20
8.5%.
10


0.25 & 0.26-0.5 0.51-1 1-2.01 2 4 5
less
(karo)





FIGURE 5.11

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF FARM SIZE

AVERAGE BY LOCATION

36 FARMS


2.00
2.00 *1.845 karo
1.75
175 1.609 karo
1.50 (N-12)
(N-12)
1.25
1.00 0.888 karo

0.75 (N-12)
0.50
0.25


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN









provides some security against crop failure in any area" seems
suspect. This might be a post facto explanation for not finding land
close to their (farmers') houses. In the study area, each farmer's
lands were in the same ecological zone even when fragmented.

Compared to other published estimates of Haitian holdings, the
average 1.44 karo is high. Murray (1977) found 1.3 karo the average
in the Cul-de-Sac. In Comhaire-Sylvain, the average size is 5 acres
(1.8 karo), and in Simpson, the size is 3 to 6 acres (1.08 to 2.17
karo). It should be noted that in Murray's report (1977 pp. 208-209)
he incorrectly converts his land holding at the rate of 1 karo equals
1.43 ha instead of 1.29 ha.

Within the Lowlands, rent for irrigated plots is almost twice
the price of dry plots. Also, in the Lowlands more 'plots are rented
than elsewhere. Out of 129 plots surveyed, 28 were rented, 17 in the
Lowlands and 14 in irrigated areas. Irrigation is the only
significant factor differentiating land sale prices. Irrigated land
is 7 to 8 times more expensive than dry land, and jumped to an average
of US$ 2,120 per karo in the 1980s (Figure 5.14). Palmer (1976: 147)
found that in Belladere "renting is increasingly common as more and
more farmers inherit impracticably small plots. At the same time,
however, as land becomes scarce and more valuable, large landowners
are more hesitant to put their properties up for rent." This can
neither be confirmed nor denied for L'Acul based on results from our
sample. The fact that in L'Acul River Basin the average size of all
rented plots (0.24 karo) is smaller than the average size of all
inherited plots (0.35- aro) would make the first part of Palmer's
statement seem invalid for the area.

Land Security. Out of 129 plots, 35 (or 27.1%) were purchased.
Not many authors mention comparable figures. Purchasing land implies
to some form of relative wealth at one or another moment in life.
Fifteen out of 36 farmers have purchased land: 5 in the Platons, 4 in
the slope area, and 6 in the plain. Thus, there is no significant
difference between sub-regions. It is interesting to note that land
prices are higher in the Lowlands, especially for irrigated lands
(Figure 5.12-5.14)

As mentioned earlier, many farmers purchase land from family
members (inheritable land). One interpretation is that land is sold
intergenerationnally (Murray 1977), and that the rituals, which are
often performed for the dead, function as an intergenerational land
circulating mechanism. Findings in Les Platons might confirm these
findings. Farmers in Les Platons have the custom (at least ideally)
of performing at least once in a lifetime an expensive ritual for the
ancestors called devwa, literally "obligation". It consists of a
Catholic mass by thelocal priest, a ritual by the local oungan
(voodoo-priest), and a big meal, for which animals are killed. The
price of such a ritual might run between $100 and $500. Often, in






















$ 2,000
1,800
1,600
1,400
1,200
1,000
800
600
400
$ 200


FIGURE 5.12

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF PURCHASED

LAND PRICES (PER KARO) BY LOCATION
$ 2120.












$407
$375
(N-12) (N- 4)
NON-IRRIG. IRRIG.


PLATON SLOPE


L.PLAIN


FIGURE 5.13

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF RENTED

LAND PRICES (per karo) (per year) BY LOCATION


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN


FIGURE 5.14

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF LAND PRICES (PURCHASED)

(BY DECADES) BY LOCATION ($ U.S.) (PER KARO)


Irrig. Non-irr.
Overall average 407.- 37.5 2,120. 305.6
per Karo

Before 1960 100.- 122.- 96.7

1960-1969 408 367.-


1970-1979 264 338 617.7


'980+ 563 2,640.-


Location


Platon Slope


Plain









order to pay for this feast, people have to sell land. None of the
respondents had yet performed their devwa. People tend to postpone
this obligation until late in life. The devwa custom does not exist
anymore in the Lowlands. People referred to-it as vye koutim (old
custom); vye has also a morally negative connotation ("only backward
people do this"). Some people said they were Protestants and would
not participate in this custom, but to the question if Protestantism
was the cause of the custom's disappearance, it appears that it was
not the only reason: "depi Janklod moun yo pi eklere" (Since
Jean-Claude, people are more educated). On the slopes, devwa was also
considered not to be fashionable but some people still perform it.
One must make special mention of the custom of building tombs in
gardens, a custom common in the South. It might just be a "folkloric
custom," with no rational for it. But all tombs are built on family
land, never on purchased or rented land. Thus, one can assume that
the dead, symbolised by tombs, are perhaps at the core of the land
tenure issue in L'Acul River Basin.

It does not appear that peasants feel very insecure about their
land. The main complaints were that it is hard to buy or rent land.
The land tenure security theme runs through most of the land tenure
literature in Haiti; the threat of losing land seems to be a slowly
increasing pressure growing from generation to generation. The
presence of tombs (kavo) on inherited land could carry two opposite
symbolic meanings in relation to land security: (1) "This land
belongs to my (extended) family, and should never go into hands of
non-family buyers"; or (2) "There is a constant danger that this land
will be lost for the family, so, this stone (kavo) and my eternal
presence here will make it impossible for you, my progeny, to sell
this land." Both seem to mean the same but the first way of
formulating it, refers to true tenure security, while the second
formulation expresses the fragility of ownership, and the lifelong
fight of the ancestor for this piece of property.

Tenure and Location.. Figures 5.15 5.18 deal with the size of
the total amount of land differentiated by type of tenure and location
in the study area. Since there were less owned plots in the Lowlands,
the highest total acreage of rented and sharecropped land is found
there. The acreage of inherited land is almost the same as the
acreage of the purchased plots (Figure 5.15). Much more land is
owned, than is either rented and sharecropped (Figure 5.14); 35.75
karo are owned while 16.38 karo are rented or sharecropped.

Common to Haiti and existing in L'Acul Basin, mixed tenure is
the dominant method of land holding; 15 farmers out of 36 did not work
any land besides they owned (non-mixed tenure pattern of 44.4
percent), 7 in Les Platons, 4 in the Slopes, and 4 in the Lowlands.
For the 19 other farmers, besides working their own inherited or
purchased plots, 7 farmers also rent land (Platon 4, Slope 2, Lowlands
1), and 7 farmers both rent and sharecrop some land (Platon 1, Slope
3, Lowlands 3).





















FIGURE 5.15

FREQUENTED & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

OWNED (INHERITED or PURCHASED) LAND Bf LOCATION


TOTAL: 35.75 karos 100%
18 17.951 Karo

16 9.56K. INHERITED
(N-12) HE D
14 12) 12.808 Karo
12
(5.52 )/A
S 10 (N-5) PURCHASED

6 6
4.919 Kato
4 /2.81K
2 8.39K 7.28K
N-i5/ (N16 2A.1K (HN-l

PLATOON SLOPE PLAIN
50.2% 35.8% 13.7%


FIGURE 5.16

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION

RENTED LAND BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 6.77 karo a 100%


3.403 karo
3.5

3. 2.687karo (N17)
2.5 (N-6)
a 2.
2
1.5 0.686karo
1.

0.5 (N-5)


PLATON SLOPE PLAIN
10.1% 39.6% 50.2%




FIGURE 5.17

FREQUENCY 4 PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION

OF SHARECROPPED LAND BY LOCATION

TOTAL: 4.612 karo 100%
(N.B. one case of 5 karo
was left out)on slope

3
2.5 2.342 karo
2.
S 2. 1.545 karo (N-9)
1.5
(N-6(+l)
1. 0.625 karo
0.5 (N-2)

PLATON SLOPE PLAIN
13.5% 39.9% 50.7%







FIGURE 5.18

FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF AVERAGE

PLOT SIZES BY LOCATION


1.

0.9

0.8

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1


PLATONS SLOPE PLAIN


FIGURE 5.19

FREQUENCY & PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF

NUMBER OF FARMERS BY TYPE OF TENURE


TOTAL: 36 farmers


20
rent + sh.l

own
sh. 7
rent


own
sh.


own
rent
rent


mixed
tenure
55.5%


16
sharecr.


own 15


I I


non-mixed
tenure
44.4%


PURCHASED
SHARECROPPED
RENTED
INHERITED


20




15 4










Of the 36 farmers, only 3 farmers did not own any land; two
farmers both rented and sharecropped some plots, the other
sharecropped only his cousin's 5 karo (Figure 5.19).

Thus, 20 farmers out of 36 (55.5 percent) work their land under
mixed tenure conditions. In Smucker's northern research village "the
modes of tenure ... is thoroughly mixed" (Smucker, 1982: 278). "The
1950 census does not provide any information on mixed tenure patterns"
(Zuvekas 1978: 9). Only one farmer out of 36 had a tenant working
on his land; he was ebenis, so besides his farm activity, he had also
other cash income. Thus, one does not observe Murray's Cul-de-Sac
pattern of sharecroppers, who give land out to others (38 percent),
and of landlords, who have tenants working on their land, working as
tenants on the land of others (60 percent); this illustrates the
ambivalence of terms like "sharecropper, "owner" or "renter" (Murray
1977: 393) in other areas of Haiti. For L'Acul area, there is no
such confusion in the surveyed sample.

In concluding the land tenure analysis of L'Acul River Basin, it
is possible to make the following generalizations: (1) the regime of
microproperty is the dominant pattern, and the majority of farmers are
not capable of making a living on their own lands; (2) most farmers
work under mixed tenure conditions; and (3) with an average farm size
of 1.44 Karo, along with the risks of drought and crop failure, and
the low productivity per plot, fundamental changes must be introduced
in this area. These three generalizations apply only for the fields
in Les Platons and Slope areas. Further studies are needed for the
Lowlands area. Also the impact of large land holdings and ownership
in the Lowlands ought to be studied.

5.4.2 Constraints On Agriculture

The following three aspects of land tenure need to be addressed
in terms of their impact on the potential options for rural
development. First, how do the size of land holdings affect the
potential of co-ordinating rural development while improving the river
basin's soil and hydrologic resource bases? Second, to what degree
are the farm units fragmented? And third, what strategies are viable
given the range of ownership/tenant categories?

Size of Land Holdings and Fragmentation of Farm Fields. Figure
5.11 illustrates the average farm size for Les Platons, Slope, and
Lowland units. In a general manner the relative size of the farming
units reflect the-quality of the land. The lowlands, possessing the
highest quality of land have the smallest ownership units. However
this figure (0.89 karo) is biased toward underestimating the farm
size, as no large landowners were part of our sample. Nevertheless,
it is fair to state, that on the lowlands farm size is, on the










average smaller than in any of the other units. One explanation for
the smaller plot size on the lowlands is that the higher productive
lands command higher land prices. The lack of capital liquidity among
the small farmers has resulted in the plot size being relatively small
on the plain. On the Slopes and Platons, the lower productivity of
these lands clearly requires a greater area to meet the demands of the
farming unit. Yet given the relative quality of the lands, the size
of farms on Les Platons indicate that the average Platons farmer has a
greater agricultural potential than the Slope farmers.

From the perspective of farm size affecting rural development,
in all cases the small nature of the land holdings in all of these
units compounds the problems in developing an agricultural strategy.
On the lowlands where irrigation is involved, the allocation of waters
during periods of water shortage presents major policy decisions if
equity is a consideration. Given the extremely small size of
holdings, if water is withheld from any farmer, major financial losses
will entail. Co-ordination and maintenance of the system is further
complicated by the fragmentation of the land holdings. On the
average, each lowland farm unit is comprized of 3 3/8 fields (average
field size approximately 0.27 karo), none of which are necessarily
contiguous to each other.

These same general properties exist on the Slope and Platons
farms. On the slopes, the average size of a plot is 0.37 karo; and
each farming unit on the Slopes is made-up of 5 fields. Les Platons
unit appears to have the largest blocks of land. Here the average
field size is 0.43 karo, with each farming unit on the average made of
3 7/10 fields. As on the lowlands, the fields of an individual farmer
are not usually contiguous to each other.

Both the small size of the farming units as well as the
dispersal of the fields compounds the problem of developing a strategy
that will increase the agricultural returns from the fields while
improving the quality of the resource. Unfortunately nature does not
recognize the sovereignty of field boundaries. Thus to minimize
erosional and runoff problems, it is necessary to co-ordinate all
farming practices existing on the hillslope system. The actions of a
farmer practicing good farming techniques could be completely negated
by a farmer on the same hillslope system that ignores conservation.
It is further complicated in Haiti due to the fragmentation of fields
which results in such small parcels and in a multitude of owners
farming parcels of lands juxtaposed to each other operating under
numerous categories of tenure. This interrelation of farming units
located in the same erosional depositional system (stream basin) has
been legally recognized in the State of Iowa. A farmer in that State
has the right to sue for damages occurring on his farmlands because of
improper land use on another farmer's land.










Ownership/Tenancy Arrangements. As in other regions of the
world, in the study area a strong relationship between the nature of
land tenure and the degree of investment on the land may be observed
(Table 5.2). As is expected intuitively, the ownership of land
implies a relatively long-term time horizon; the land is a resource
which, if maintained properly, will provide both food and income over
a lifetime. The rental of land implies a medium-term time horizon.
In the Cayes Plain Basin where land is generally rented in five year
periods, often renewed, there is an incentive to preserve the land's
productive capacity. Finally, sharecropping (deux-moiti6) is
associated with a relatively unstable form of land tenure. There is a
definite disincentive to the expenditure of time and capital on the
preservation of land that maybe utilized for a short-term.

Table 5.4 presents a summary of the ownership/tenancy
arrangements for three of the four topographic units found in L'Acul
River Basin. From the table it is clear that Les Platons unit has the
most favorable land tenancy conditions in terms of incentives for the
preservation of the land resource. Here 92 percent of the farmers
cultivate lands of which they own at least some of their cropped
lands. Fifty-four percent of Les Platons' farmers only cultivate
lands that they own. Given this property along with the slightly
larger land units found in this area, previously discussed, it appears
the residents of Les Platons would be amenable to interventions that
would improve the land and water resources of the area.






TABLE 5.4

Ownership/Tenancy Arrangement by Topographic Unit
(November December 1983)



Land Farmed Platons Slopes Lowlands

Owned Land Only 54% 36% 36%
Owned and Rented Land 30% 18% 36%
Owned and Sharecropped 8% 18% 8%
Rented and/or Share-
cropped Land 8% 28% 28%









Conversely, the land unit that requires immediate interventions
to arrest its rapidly deteriorating environmental situation, The Slope
Unit, has apparently the least favorable land tenancy conditions.
While ownership percentages of the land are identical for the Lowlands
and Slopes (72%), the Slopes have the largest percentage of lands
under sharecropping arrangements. Nevertheless, for L'Acul River
Basin as a whole, it presents generally favorable land tenancy
conditions for interventions. The overwhelming percentage of land in
the basin is owner occupied, the group that should be most open to
long term investment.


5.5 EXTRAPOLATING OF PRESENT AGRICULTURAL SITUATION

The proceeding portions of this chapter examined the
interrelations between the physical and socio-economic domains in the
Cayes Plain Basin. Within the Haitian context, it is the agricultural
activities that most clearly manifest these interrelations.
Throughout the life of a rural Haitian the direct links of the
physical environment have life and death implications almost on a
daily basis. As little slack exists in both the physical and
socio-economic areas, whenever any component becomes stressed, the
small farmers' low level of well being is placed in jeopardy. In the
following two sections the likely outcomes of non-intervention in the
existing rural framework are explored.

5.5.1 Land Resources

In each of the four topographic units within L'Acul River Basin,
if the current situation is allowed to continue, the environmental
situation will deteriorate in each unit. This will place ever
increasing demands on the land resources. Because the topographic
units are linked together via the river system network, the negative
impacts occurring upstream will have a multiplier-like effect as they
move downstream. Therefore the best lands from an agricultural
perspective, the lowland Unit being located at the end of the system
will experience most of the negative impacts of the deleterious events
occurring upstream.

By extrapolating the existing trends into the future, unless
interventions are introduced and become successful the following
conditions in terms of the natural resources will likely occur:

1. The Igneous Highlands will become completely deforested. Runoff
will increase; infiltration decrease. Soil erosion will remain
a problem, and will likely become exacerbated.

2. Les Platons will experience local erosional deterioration. A
gradual decline in land productivity and resulting lower yields
will occur.










3. The Slopes will become non-productive except for the valley
bottoms. The valley bottoms will become more susceptible to
flooding making the area both less productive and more hazardous.

4. The non-irrigated lowlands will remain non-irrigated as less
water will be available for irrigation. The currently irrigated
lands will both decrease in areal extent as well as experience
higher costs because:

a. water supply will become more extreme. L'Acul's flow regime
will fluctuate between torrents and trickles. Moderate flows
will decrease in frequency and less waters will therefore be
available for irrigation;

b. Siltation will increase due to deterioration of upstream
areas. This will result in high maintenance costs; and

c. Actual destruction of irrigation works could occur as
extreme hydrologic events (i.e. a discharge that today
represents the 100 year flow) will become more common.

5. In all topographic units, the carrying capacity of the land for
livestock will decrease as a need will exist to bring even more
marginal land under cultivation. Thus only the extreme marginal
lands will be available for grazing.

As it is easier to improve a degrading environment than to
completely rehabilitate a degraded area, from the physical
perspective, there is every reason to immediately begin the actions
required to arrest the ongoing processes throughout the Cayes Plain
Basin. The need for such immediate action is further strengthened
when the socio-economic impacts of the current degrading system are
examined.

5.5.2 Social Economic Implications

The physical degradation of land resources described in the
previous section will have significant impacts upon the social and
economic structure of the study area. These include:

1. A deteriorating level of food supply, both crops and livestock
will occur. This will induce a decline in nutrition and
health. Ultimately this will lower the productivity of the
human resources in the area. In addition, a decreased food
supply will create the necessity for the import of food, thereby
creating "leakages" from the regional economy and diminishing
its ability to retain the surplus value that has been generated.

2. The level of cash income from the marketing of products will be
reduced. This will lead to a reduction in the range and
quantity of goods and services that can be purchased, resulting
in a lower quality of life. The impact of this income reduction
will be amplified due to continuing inflationary trends in the
world economy.









CHAPTER 6


THE INSTITUTIONAL CONTEXT



6.1 INTRODUCTION

Regional rural development programs necessarily depend, in
practice, on the organizations and people through which such programs
can be implemented and the institutional context within which the
program activities operate.

This chapter will inventory and generally describe principal
institutions that directly or indirectly affect rural development in
the Cayes Plain Basin. For the purposes of this report, these
institutions are classified as popular, governmental, or
non-governmental. The term "institution" is used broadly to encompass
agencies, organizations, officials, and a variety of permanent,
semi-permanent or ad hoc groups. Limited time for field work did not
permit a full inventory of the organizations and their activities, or
an evaluation of their effectiveness. Discussion here focuses on the
range of activities the groups or institutions are involved in, and
their strengths and weaknesses insofar as regional agricultural
development activities are concerned. As many institutions work on
similar or common activities, discussion of different institutions will
occasionally overlap. This chapter concludes with a brief discussion
of the effects of land tenure on development options.

For purposes of discussion in this chapter, institutions will be
referenced as follows:


6.2 Popular Institutions

6.2.1 Lakou
6.2.2 Coumbites and Escouads
6.2.3 Groupments
6.2.4 Irrigation Groups
6.2.5 Cooperatives
6.2.6 Community Action Councils

6.3 Government

6.3.1 Government Agencies
6.3.1.1 Agriculture
6.3.3.2 Plan
6.3.1.3 Public Works









6.3.1.4 National Education
6.3.1.5 Public Health and Population
6.3.1.6 Finance
6.3.1.7 Justice
6.3.1.8 Interior
6.3.1.9 IDAI
6.3.1.10 BCA
6.3.1.11 ONAAC
6.3.1.12 SNEM
6.3.1.13 SNEP
6.3.1.14 CORCOPLAN

6.3.2 Subnational government entities
6.3.2.1 Prefect
6.3.2.2 Mayor's Office

6.3.3 Other government or quasi-government
6.3.3.1 VSN
6.3.3.2 CONAJEC

6.4 Private organizations

6.4.1 Religious Organizations
6.4.1.1 Catholic organizations
6.4.1.2 Protestant organizations
6.4.2 Non-religious organizations
6.4.2.1 Pan American Development Foundation
6.4.2.2 Ateliers Agricoles et Ecoles de Camp Perrin
6.4.2.3 Interntl. Maize and Wheat Improvement Center
6.4.2.4 ASDEC nursery
6.4.3 Private sector
6.4.3.1 Comme II Faut
6.4.3.2 FACOLEV
6.4.3.4 Other agroindustries
6.4.3.4 Credit institutions
6.4.3.5 Other citizens groups in Les Cayes

6.5 Land Tenure


6.2 POPULAR INSTITUTIONS

6.2.1 Lakous

The lakou, or extended family compound characterized by several
houses and a yard, has long been considered the fundamental institution
of rural Haitian society. In addition to being the central focus of
family life, it serves a variety of other functions related directly or
indirectly to agricultural development. It enables family members to
recruit unpaid labor to assist them in assuring their common or
separate subsistence. It provides an orderly system for access to
land and its transfer between generations. Typically, it is the first




University of Florida Home Page
© 2004 - 2010 University of Florida George A. Smathers Libraries.
All rights reserved.

Acceptable Use, Copyright, and Disclaimer Statement
Last updated October 10, 2010 - - mvs